Gaps in U.S. rural and urban economic growth widened in the post-Great Recession economy, with implications amid the coronavirus recession

Downtown Prattville, Ala. during a period of shelter-in-place orders, mid-April 2020.

Overview

Prior to the current coronavirus recession, most U.S. economic metrics pointed to a slow but steady nationwide recovery amid an 11-year post-Great Recession run of economic growth. But prosperity was not spread equally across the breadth of the nation. In addition to widening income and wealth gaps, new data show that rural communities did not reap widespread benefits compared to urban regions of the country. The reasons for this gap between urban and rural economic growth bear serious policy consideration as the coronavirus pandemic sweeps across the nation.

During the 11-year recovery following the Great Recession of 2007–2009, Gross Domestic Product growth in rural America lagged behind urban GDP growth, according to the recently released Local Area GDP measure, which provides annual GDP growth data by county and industry. Rural areas in the aggregate experienced post-recession growth of 14.8 percent while urban areas registered 19.2 percent growth. When the data are broken down regionally, we see that the largest urban-rural divide is in the West, which consists of California, Oregon, Washington state, Alaska, and Hawaii. (See Figure 1.)

Figure 1

Regional Gross Domestic Product growth divided by urban and rural counties, 2010–2018

Demographic and industry breakdowns

This divide in urban and rural outcomes was driven by changes in demographic and industry composition. Rural and nonmetropolitan areas have a higher share of older people over 65 years of age, 17.5 percent, meaning labor force participation rates will drop as rural communities age. In addition to age, educational attainment contributes to declining labor participation and outcomes because half of prime-age adults (ages 25 to 54) held no more than a high school diploma in rural communities. Decreasing educational attainment brought about an ever-widening labor force participation gap between rural and urban areas.

Looking at the regional breakdown of urban and rural growth, it is evident that rural communities rely on specific industries for economic growth and sustainability. Rural counties in some states such as Texas and Oklahoma depended on the mining and fracking industries for long-term growth after the Great Recession. (See Figure 2.)

Figure 2

County-level mining and fracking output, 2010–2018

Indeed, Louisiana’s rural counties witnessed a 30 percent decline in post-recession output, yet the entire Southern region’s rural growth was able to counteract this decline partially through mining and fracking output in Texas. As a result, the South, as well as the Northeast, experienced large shares of growth coming out of the mining and fracking sector. (See Figure 3.)

Figure 3

Share of mining and fracking compared to all growth by U.S. region, 2010–2018

Beyond farming, mining, and fracking, the rural economy relied heavily on the service industry as a form of sustainable employment. In 2016, data from the U.S. Census Bureau’s American Community Survey showed that 22 percent of people living in completely rural counties (counties in which 100 percent of the population live in a rural area) were employed by the educational, healthcare, and social assistance service sector. Another 7.3 percent worked in the arts, food, and accommodations service sector. Yet even though many rural workers depended on services over fracking, mining, and agriculture, the service industry output fell short for these communities during the post-Great Recession run of economic growth.

What’s more, growth in the rural service sector lagged behind similar industries in urban communities. In the South and the West, there was a 14 percentage point and 16 percentage point gap, respectively, in the growth of service output between urban and rural communities. The gaps were smaller in the Midwest and especially in the Northeast. (See Figure 4.)

Figure 4

Growth in the service sector by urban and rural counties, 2010–2018

Rural and urban and regional economic growth gaps in healthcare

Then, there’s the healthcare sector. There are widespread regional and rural-urban divides in economic output in healthcare since the Great Recession. Rural counties in the West and Rocky Mountain states experienced growth in healthcare while rural counties in the South, Midwest, and Northeast registered more contraction in this industry since the previous recession. (See Figure 5.)

Figure 5

Percentage change in healthcare and social assistance output by county, 2010–2018

One explanation for such geographic divides is the growing trend of healthcare professionals moving away from rural counties toward urban counties, where hospitals are growing rather than closing or consolidating. Since 2010, 130 hospitals in rural communities have closed their doors, predominantly in the South. A study from the Chartis Center for Rural Health estimates that another 453 hospitals out of the remaining 1,800 are vulnerable to closure based on their performance and funding support between 2019 and 2020.

In addition to funding struggles and closures, rural hospitals are often vulnerable to mergers and acquisitions. Between 2007 and 2012, approximately 8 percent of rural hospitals, or 121, were involved in a merger. These hospitals had fewer profit margins, a lower percent of outpatient revenue coming from Medicare, a smaller ratio of full-time-equivalent, or FTE, employees to hospital beds, and higher amounts of debt compared to hospitals not involved in a merger. Researchers found that after the mergers, salaries went down by more than $1,220 per FTE employee, or almost $645,000. Other studies show that rural hospitals that merged with larger hospital systems experienced a decline in services provided, such as diagnostic imaging and outpatient care.

Despite the reduction in services, these rural hospitals showed significantly increased operating margins, which indicates that they aren’t performing at any greater efficiency than before the mergers took place.  

The preservation and improvement of rural hospitals is crucial to the growth of the rural economy, particularly amid the current pandemic. Without accessible and good-quality healthcare, rural workers won’t be able to effectively work and promote growth within their local economies. Lack of accessible healthcare in rural counties means people risk losing their jobs in order to travel further distances to seek medical care that they can’t afford, thus exacerbating the social disparities in rural and urban public health outcomes.

Protecting healthcare accessibility doesn’t mean preserving poorly operating hospitals. In order to close the growth gap between rural and urban communities, policymakers should look at ways to strengthen healthcare accessibilities, such as providing public funding for nonprofit rural healthcare or expanding Medicaid in states with higher rural populations.

Reasons for the growth gap between rural and urban economies

Research by Charles S. Gascon and Brian Reinbold of the St. Louis Federal Reserve credits the urban-rural growth gap to agglomeration effects, which are seen when urban cities experience stronger growth because of firms’ access to resources that increase productivity, such as airports, efficient public transportation, and large pools of consumers. Some urban firms do provide services that spill over into rural communities, such as an urban hospital providing telemedicine to rural patients. But this is still output generated by and for urban areas, and so improvements in rural accessibility to resources primarily boosts urban output and growth. Nonetheless, these spillover effects and increased accessibility to cities’ resources improve rural prime-age adults’ employment prospects and optimism.

On the urban side, much of the gap is attributed to a technology boom concentrated in major metropolitan areas such as San Francisco, Boston, Austin, and New York. The rise of the tech industry worked in tandem with the phenomenon known as the rural brain drain. Young and talented individuals raised in rural communities are migrating to metropolitan areas in waves, searching for jobs in new industries and a higher quality of life.

In a study conducted by demographers Ken Johnson at the University of New Hampshire and Richelle Winkler at Michigan Technological University, the data show that large metropolitan areas experienced net population gains while nonmetropolitan areas experienced net population losses of people ages 20 to 34 years old. As a result of the decreased supply of workers, tech industries are failing to establish themselves in rural areas, despite the relatively low cost of living in such areas.

Policy implications

It is imperative that policymakers consider rural communities when discussing economic policy initiatives. Programs that promote urban growth, for example, may have negative effects on the rural economic expansion. Through the use of data, such as the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis’s Local Area GDP measure, academics and policymakers alike can track rural industry trends and create policies that promote a stable and resilient rural economy.

Twenty-one policy resources to combat the coronavirus recession

Policymakers learned late last week that the U.S. economy registered a stunning 9.4 percent contraction in the second quarter of this year, a drop not experienced since the Great Depression more than eight decades ago. And that extraordinarily bad news came in late July—following weeks of the novel coronavirus becoming “extraordinarily widespread” across most of the country, leading a number of states and municipalities to restrict or re-restrict economic activity to stem the pandemic and rising number of deaths due to COVID-19, the disease caused by the coronavirus. U.S. economists are mildly to extraordinarily concerned that our economy is moving toward further contraction and a possible return to the record unemployment numbers posted this past spring.

In the early days of the coronavirus pandemic in the United States, the Washington Center for Equitable Growth launched a new web page dedicated to policy resources for the coronavirus recession. Nearly every day since, we’ve posted new analysis and policy recommendations backed by evidence-based research on the ways the federal government can help our economy recover and ensure that recovery is broad-based and equitable. Much of this policy work is based on our Vision 2020 project, a resource designed to provide policymakers in Congress and the federal government with detailed policy recommendations on a wide array of issues.

Together, these two resource pages on our website point to workable solutions to the multitude of interconnected economic travails besetting the country. Some of these ideas are immediately relevant to economic growth for the remainder of the year, particularly the need to deal with the spread of the coronavirus itself as the first order of business. Other ideas on these resource pages point to ways policymakers can ensure the recovery from this recession is different from past ones. Here is a list of some of these most relevant posts.

Jobs and Unemployment Insurance

Factsheet: Unemployment Insurance and why the effect of work disincentives is greatly overstated amid the coronavirus recession

Fool Me Once: Investing in Unemployment Insurance systems to avoid the mistakes of the Great Recession during COVID-19

Coronavirus recession layoffs require reforms to the Unemployment Insurance program now to fully protect all U.S. workers

Child care

Child care is essential for working parents, but is the industry ready and safe to reopen?

The coronavirus pandemic requires a wartime commitment for essential workers’ access to child care

How the coronavirus pandemic is harming family well-being for U.S. low-wage workers

Paid leave

New analysis shows state paid leave programs cushioned the blow of COVID-19, sparking important new questions

The economic imperative of enacting paid family leave across the United States

Small businesses

Did the Paycheck Protection Program work for small businesses across the United States?

More resilient small U.S. restaurants and their workers can exit the coronavirus recession and sustain an equitable economic recovery

Rescuing small businesses to fight the coronavirus recession and prevent further economic inequality in the United States

The coronavirus and structural racism

A feminist economic policy agenda in response to the COVID-19 pandemic and the quest for racial justice

The coronavirus recession is an opportunity to cancel all U.S. student loan debt

New congressional reports underscore structural inequalities driving U.S. racial disparities in coronavirus infections and COVID-19 deaths

The coronavirus and the environment

Americans want green spending in federal coronavirus recession relief packages

Green stimulus, not dirty bailouts, is the smart investment strategy during the coronavirus recession

The coronavirus and data collection

The coronavirus pandemic highlights the importance of disaggregating U.S. data by race and ethnicity

Data will provide accountability to ensure the U.S. economic recovery is shared broadly

Social insurance

Broken plumbing: How systems for delivering economic relief in response to the coronavirus recession failed the U.S. economy

New research finds enhanced U.S. social insurance will be necessary until the coronavirus recession recedes

The coronavirus recession highlights the importance of automatic stabilizers

Testimony by Heather Boushey before the Joint Economic Committee on the Coronavirus Recession

Heather Boushey
Washington Center for Equitable Growth
Testimony before the Joint Economic Committee,
Hearing on “Reducing Uncertainty and Restoring Confidence During the Coronavirus Recession”

July 30, 2020

Thank you, Vice Chair Beyer and Chairman Lee, for inviting me to speak today. It’s an honor to be here.

My name is Heather Boushey, and I am president and CEO of the Washington Center for Equitable Growth. We launched in November 2013 with the goal of advancing evidence-backed ideas and policies in pursuit of strong, stable, and broad-based economic growth. We do this through a unique institutional strategy: We fund academics to investigate whether and how economic inequality—in all its forms—affects economic growth and stability. We have an open and competitive academic grants program that now, in our seventh cycle, has given away about $6.5 million to more than 250 scholars nationwide.

What the research now shows is that there are many ways that inequality hurts both families and the long-term trajectory of our economy. These long-term trends are inimically tied up in the current coronavirus pandemic and resulting recession.

The most important economic uncertainty facing your constituents and our nation is: When will the administration and Congress address the public health crisis caused by the coronavirus pandemic?

Addressing the administration’s failure to contain the coronavirus and COVID-19, the disease caused by the virus, is the only way to fully restore confidence and put us on the path to economic recovery. The United States is experiencing the most uncontrolled and deadly outbreak of any high-income country in the world. Compared to the European Union, we now record 10 times as many daily coronavirus cases and COVID-19 deaths.

Until the virus is contained, however, there are key actions that can bolster economic confidence and rein in uncertainty. Specifically:

  • Immediately renew the $600 Pandemic Unemployment Compensation payments
  • Set economic assistance programs, such as Unemployment Insurance, to continue automatically until objective economic conditions improve
  • Pass generous aid for states and localities, which have already shed 1.5 million jobs and are bearing the brunt of responding to the pandemic, on the order of the $900 billion in the HEROES Act
  • Resist enacting corporate liability immunity and instead release workplace health standards that protect workers’ lives and give employers evidence-based guidance
  • Enact other policies to stabilize demand and help those most affected by the crisis, including:
    • Food assistance
    • Rental assistance and the extension of the eviction moratorium
    • Direct payments to a broad swathe of low- and moderate-income Americans
    • Investments in communities of color hit so hard by the coronavirus
    • Funding to ensure safe and secure elections in November
    • Help for small businesses
    • Premium pay to our essential workers
    • Fixes to the long-term fragilities detailed below that have made us so susceptible to this shock
  • Build the data tools to know how this crisis and recovery are affecting families up and down the income ladder by enacting GDP 2.0 measures

The HEROES Act, which was passed by the House more than 2 months ago, contains many of these priorities. The Senate should immediately consider passing this bill or a similar bill that includes a recently introduced bill from Sens. Schumer and Wyden to peg expanded unemployment benefits to the economic conditions in each state. This would allow aid to automatically adjust based on objective criteria. Vice Chair Beyer has authored a similar proposal.

The coronavirus pandemic abruptly ended of the longest economic recovery in U.S. history. But before we get to the current situation, we need to acknowledge that even in those good years, the gains from that economic growth weren’t shared. This created systemic fragilities that left us less economically resilient and set us up for the multiple failures we are now experiencing.

The Roots of this Failure

This immediate failure is the result of a series of decisions made by this administration. But it also is the result of decisions made over the past 50 years that have created underlying fragilities in our economy and society. These decisions have made our economy less effective in good times and less resilient to shocks.

Even as the topline economic markers signaled to policymakers that our economy was growing last year—indicators such as a historically low unemployment rate and annual Gross Domestic Product growth of around 2 percent—wages were not growing commensurate with a tight labor market or at a pace to close our country’s unconscionable longstanding racial income and wealth divides.

The fruits of our economic growth, in terms of both income and wealth, were diverging sharply.

The Federal Reserve Board’s new Distributional Financial Accounts and the latest research by University of California, Berkeley economists Emmanuel Saez and Gabriel Zucman document that income inequality remained historically high, and wealth inequality was outpacing it.

Inequality hurts economic growth and mobility. Growth has slowed since 1980, and average people no longer share in the growth we do have. The bottom 50 percent of the population has the same inflation-adjusted pretax income that they did in 1980, and lower absolute mobility means that people born in 1980 now have only a 50 percent chance of surpassing their parents’ income.

As I summarize in Unbound: How Inequality Constricts our Economy and What We Can Do About It, at Equitable Growth, in our now 7 years of looking at the best economic research, we see that inequality constricts growth by:

  • Obstructing the supply of people and ideas into our economy and limiting opportunity for those not already at the top, which slows productivity growth over time
  • Subverting the institutions that manage the market, making our political system ineffective and our labor markets dysfunctional
  • Distorting demand through its effects on consumption and investment, which both drags down and destabilizes short- and long-term growth in economic output

As a country, we have put ideology over evidence. We have chosen tax cuts and deregulation over investments such as paid family leave, robust social insurance programs, and public institutions. We have put our faith in the idea that markets can do the work of governing.

Instead, we should put our economy—and society—on a path where growth is strong, stable, and broadly shared. To do that, we need to enact policies that constrain inequality at the top, not allowing it to spiral out of control, and giving the beneficiaries of that inequality the power to subvert our markets, politics, or economy. And we need to provide counterweights to concentrated economic power. As we consider the economy we had at the onset of the pandemic, we can see clearly how failures to ensure workers and families, especially Black, Latinx, and Native American workers and families, have access to the tools to be healthy and safe—policies such as paid sick time, access to affordable healthcare, and well-enforced workplace safety standards—made our nation less resilient to this shock.

There are six key factors that made the United States and the U.S. economy particularly susceptible to the coronavirus pandemic and COVID-19. Each of them have contributed to the current crisis. And if they are not corrected, the United States is likely to experience a slow and inequitable economic recovery.

  1. Too many people lack the basic protections that would have slowed the spread of the coronavirus

The gaps in our social insurance systems exacerbated the spread of the coronavirus. The United States is behind its peer nations in labor market regulations to protect workers and families, including on paid leave, stable schedules, and access to child care. Compounding the problem is the lack of health insurance and fear of high medical bills, both of which kept—and are still keeping—those who feel sick from seeing a doctor, placing a serious burden on these individuals as well as raising rates of transmission.

Research is already showing the significant economic and psychological toll this pandemic is taking on workers. These stresses are heightened for people of color and immigrants, who face institutional discrimination and are often forced by their already precarious economic straits to succumb to workplace abuses at the hands of their employers.

  1. Workers lack the power to share in the gains of the economic expansion that would have given them protections and security

Civic institutions—especially labor unions, which once served as voices for many wage-earning workers (though never representing all workers)—have suffered a long decline. Now, only 1 out of every 16 private-sector workers belongs to a union. On top of this, labor laws and policies have failed to reflect the growing role of the fissured workplace in our modern-day economy, where firms subcontract pieces of their work so they can avoid responsibility for workers and working conditions.

These two debilitating trends in our labor market mean that corporations that are ultimately in charge of labor practices and that make the largest profits are not liable for maintaining 21st century workplace standards. The coronavirus pandemic exposed the failure of these labor market inequalities and the need for workers to manage health crises and family care, as well as protect workers against layoffs and the loss of these key health and family benefits.

  1. Decades of stagnant wages and meager workplace benefits leave many families without enough savings to weather the coronavirus recession

At the onset of the coronavirus pandemic in the United States, millions of people across the country were one paycheck away from financial catastrophe, even after a decade of economic expansion and historically low unemployment. Case in point: Four in 10 adults in the United States said that if they had a $400 emergency expense, they would have to borrow, sell something, or would not be able to pay it.

As the coronavirus recession continues, more and more workers and their families are robbed of buying power, which will undermine one of the key drivers of economic growth—the stable incomes that drive consumer spending.

  1. Policymakers starve public goods of investments that would have enabled better protections from the coronavirus pandemic and ensuing recession

Decades of tax cuts, culminating in the sharply regressive Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017, have fueled a long-term decline in federal revenue that has starved resources that can be used to fund critical public investments and basic governmental functions, including in public health. High concentrations of income and wealth hamstring our political system because the wealthy dictate the legislative agenda and shape news headlines.

Yet these same wealthy elites don’t prioritize investments in public health infrastructure or other public goods. Early in this crisis, our neglected Unemployment Insurance system was unable to handle millions of Americans losing their jobs. Millions have waited weeks or months as decades-old computer systems struggled to process their claims. This dearth of investment is a systemic problem in the United States. (See Figure 1.)

Figure 1

U.S. gross government investment, federal and state, as a share of GDP, 1947–2018
  1. States and localities don’t have the resources to deal with a pandemic or a recession

State and local governments are experiencing sharp drops in their capacity to provide the services needed to cope with the coronavirus recession. Already, state and local governments have shed 1.5 million jobs. A continuing recession will induce further cuts to health and education and exacerbate the ongoing weaknesses. Austerity in state governments likewise disproportionately harms people of color, as public-sector jobs form the basis of a strong middle class for Black and Latinx workers.

  1. Business concentration across markets increases consumer and small business vulnerabilities just when those threats are most dire

Wealthy and powerful corporations use their status to maintain dominance in the marketplace. Large businesses and monopolies muscle competitors out of business, suppress wages, and hobble innovation. These companies are also precisely the ones that will thrive after the coronavirus pandemic passes. Strong cash reserves combined with political influence allow entrenched businesses to swoop in when asset prices are low and reshape rules of entire markets in the aftermath. The collapse of small businesses will disproportionately hurt people of color for whom business ownership is an especially important route to wealth creation and to closing the racial wealth gap.

The failure to prevent coronavirus infections and deaths and the ensuing recession

President Donald Trump’s focus is and always has been on the stock market rather than conceiving of and effectively implementing a comprehensive and fully thought-out federal plan to address the coronavirus pandemic and its economic effects. Case in point: Though the administration knew about the threat of the coronavirus in early January and took an early effort to limit the transmission into the United States by halting travel from China, where the coronavirus first emerged, it did not use that time to prepare sufficient stockpiles of medical and protective supplies.

Despite the months that have passed, the administration also has not set up a nationwide system to contact trace confirmed COVID-19 cases or given states the resources to do it themselves. And tests for the general population still can take a week or more to process and access too often varies by race.

Addressing the Immediate Economic Uncertainty

Unemployment Insurance

The largest economic uncertainty facing the United States is whether the Senate will renew the $600 increase in weekly unemployment benefits, known as Pandemic Unemployment Compensation, or PUC. The Senate majority has refused for months to act to renew this critical lifeline despite dire circumstances in the labor market.

In June, more than 11 percent of the workforce was unemployed, while the unemployment rate for Black workers was higher than 15 percent and more than 14 percent for Latinx workers. And conditions appear to have worsened in July as COVID-19 cases have resurged and states have been forced to re-enter various stages of lockdown. Unemployment claims numbers are rising once more, and a new survey from the U.S. Census Bureau shows that a staggering 6.7 million jobs have been lost since June.

There is a racial component to the Senate’s refusal to renew the $600 PUC benefit. States with a higher share of Black workers tend to have less generous jobless benefits. For Black workers, an estimate shows, the average maximum weekly benefit is $40 short of that received by White workers. (See Figure 2.)

Figure 2

Regular Unemployment Insurance wage-replacement rate by state, January–March 2020

We risk a cascade of economic damage that could be uncontainable if Congress does not act immediately to extend the $600 unemployment benefit boost. Families need this benefit to sustain them. Their landlords need them to pay their rent, and their local small business owners desperately need them to keep ordering take-out and popping by for socially distanced shopping.

Like a virus out of control, high unemployment spreads economic pain throughout the entire community.

Unemployment benefits accounted for 14.6 percent of all wage and salary income in May. Failure to extend the $600 boost alone would contract GDP by a rate of 2.5 percent in the second half of this year, per an analysis by Harvard University’s Jason Furman. As a percentage, that is more than the economy grew in 2019.

Allowing the $600 boost to remain expired would devastate local economies.

Our communities rely on the temporarily unemployed being able to continue spending. States where unemployment benefits replace a greater percent of workers’ wages experienced the smallest drop in work hours in March—and, as of early June, had the strongest recovery.

There have been unfounded concerns that the $600 boost might be a meaningful disincentive to work during this crisis, perversely causing the very economic ailment is it meant to alleviate. This is not the case. The ongoing failure to be able to get back to business-as-usual due to the out-of-control pandemic, the absence of safe working conditions, a sharp drop in consumer spending, and lack of support for parents and caregivers are preventing millions from working, not Unemployment Insurance payments.  

People are eager to get back to work when they have the opportunity, but there are not enough jobs in our labor market. The Job Openings and Labor Turnover survey shows that there were four unemployed people for every job opening in May. Lack of opportunities to work, not a lack of eagerness to work, are keeping unemployment elevated.

We can also see this in the population of people who returned to work in May and June after being laid off in April. Nearly 70 percent of those who returned to work in May and June did so despite the fact that they were making more from Unemployment Insurance than at their job, according to analysis by Ernie Tedeschi, an economist at Evercore ISI and former Treasury economist. (See Figure 3.)

Figure 3

In short, Americans want to work, and they know that a permanent job is more valuable than a temporary Unemployment Insurance check. This is one reason why employers are filling their scarce open positions faster than at any point since February 2012, as shown in the U.S. job vacancy yield.

Automatic Stabilizers

Nobody knows for sure how long the coronavirus recession will last or exactly how severe it will be. The uncertainty that would exist when confronting any recession is compounded by the uncertainty about the nature and consequences of the coronavirus itself, including the number of people who will die from COVID-19 now and in the future, the short- and long-term health impacts of the virus on those who recover, the pace at which treatments and vaccines will be developed, and the quality of the public health response.

Enhanced unemployment benefits should end when objective conditions show they are no longer needed. An unemployment-rate-based “trigger” that only turns off when a stable recovery is underway would allow this program to wind down automatically.

Sens. Schumer and Wyden have introduced a bill that would extend the $600 increase in weekly UI benefits beyond July 31, 2020 until a state’s 3-month average total unemployment rate falls below 11 percent. The benefit amount then reduces by $100 for every percentage point decrease in the state’s unemployment rate, until the rate falls below 6 percent. Vice Chair Beyer has sponsored a similar bill in the House. These bills follow the best evidence in research-driven policy design, inspired by research on automatic stabilizers from Equitable Growth and the Hamilton Project’s book Recession Ready

State and Local Government Aid

The next priority, if Congress wants to create economic certainty, is to pass fiscal relief for states and localities with around $900 billion in aid in the HEROES Act.

States and localities are bearing the brunt of responding to this virus in light of federal inaction. They are losing tax revenue and, as a result, have shed 1.5 million jobs so far—even as their services are more necessary than ever. These job losses make up a significant portion of the overall 12 million jobs permanently lost since February.

With state and local general fund revenues in freefall due to needed increases in spending on healthcare and related spending amid plummeting tax revenue, these governments’ budgets are on the precipice. State budget shortfalls could total more than $550 billion over the next 3 years, nearly double what it was estimated states missed out on in the entire decade following the Great Recession more than a decade ago. Fiscal requirements that states balance their budgets are already forcing governors to propose cuts in spending that will harm already struggling communities. Local governments are, if anything, in an even more challenging economic situation.

During the previous recession, these budget cuts proved seriously harmful to the economy. Shrinking state and local government budgets during the Great Recession reduced Gross Domestic Product by more than three times the size of the cuts themselves, according to estimates.

Other Crucial Policies

Other policy priorities include food assistance, rental assistance and extension of the eviction moratorium, investments in communities of color hit hard by the virus, funding to ensure safe and secure elections in November, help for small businesses, and premium pay to our essential workers. And I urge you not to support enhanced liability protections for big corporations facing lawsuits if they put their workers at risk. Federal policymakers need to provide evidence-based guidance so firms open safely, not shift risks onto workers.

Finally, Congress should also implement new data tools to measure how the recession and recovery will affect people differently up and down the income and wealth ladders. The GDP 2.0 measure Equitable Growth has proposed, and which I have previously discussed before this Committee, will tell us whether families are recovering from the crisis and which need more help. We can lay the groundwork now to make sure we understand who benefits from a future recovery and what other action is needed.

We can see clearly that markets cannot perform the work of government. Americans need public institutions that can protect them from threats to their lives and livelihoods, and provide leadership in times of crisis. Our economy and society have a long way to go to get back to full health. We have even further to go to implement fixes for our long-running systemic fragilities. I thank you for the chance to submit this testimony on how you can do just that.

Congress must act to help U.S. families facing an income crisis

We now have 4.3 million confirmed cases of the novel coronavirus in the United States. The virus moves fast, and policymakers in Washington move slow. Families across the country face a wide array of individual income crises and need federal fiscal support, yet policies to address public health and economic hardship are backsliding. Families, unemployed workers, small business owners, and communities need more money, and only Congress has the means to help.

Congress must deliver a multitrillion-dollar package. One-fifth of families have lost a breadwinner and twice as many have lost income, according to surveys by the University of Michigan and Google. Black, Hispanic, and Asian families, as well as young adults and less educated workers, are being hit much harder than others. This is a clear income crisis, larger than any since the Great Depression.

Early on, when the pandemic first crashed the U.S. economy, policymakers had to act with limited information. Key indicators on public health and the economy were not keeping up with quickly changing conditions. Recessions normally build over months or even quarters. This crisis arrived in days and weeks. In addition, huge disagreements among professional forecasters, including me, and massive uncertainty about the path the coronavirus would take hindered the federal response.

None of those excuses prevail today. Official statistics, administrative data, and new research all have caught up. There is no rapid bounce back in our economy. And there will be no solid economic ground until the coronavirus is under control.

Congress, in those first few months, designed the first relief packages for a crisis they hoped would be over by the summer. They were wrong. It is not over, which means they must do more—even more than in March. Coronavirus cases spiked this month, and the U.S. economy worsened. Deaths from COVID-19, the disease caused by the virus, are consequently on the rise. Policymakers must face this harsh reality. They must go bigger and better. They must move faster.

Workplaces must make it safe enough for workers to return to their jobs. Congress must invest aggressively in public health, testing, contact tracing, and personal protective equipment. They must get money out to make up for lost paychecks and reverse cuts in hours and wages of the employed. Families must have paid health insurance, sick leave, and child care. Renters and homeowners behind on their monthly obligations must get help. As many small businesses as possible must avoid bankruptcy. And Congress must get grants to state and local governments to avoid laying off more teachers and essential workers. Congress must get more money out now. 

Do what worked again, and keep it simple

Better jobless benefits are the big success story of the relief provided by Congress so far. In March, Congress made more workers eligible for unemployment benefits, including independent contractors and gig workers, and added an extra $600 per week to those benefits while extending the number of weeks someone could receive benefits. By April, the unemployment rate hit its highest level since the Great Depression, and those enhanced unemployment benefits prevented that joblessness from translating into mass human suffering and a macroeconomic collapse. Currently, around 30 million people are receiving jobless benefits, including those who suffered big cuts in hours or wages. Helping the unemployed is crucial to getting us through this income crisis.

New research by the JP Morgan Chase Institute shows that the better jobless benefits worked. Using bank account data, the researchers find these benefits allowed these families not to pull back on their spending. In fact, their spending in July was somewhat higher than before the start of the coronavirus recession. Keep in mind, lower-income families have been twice as likely as the national average to lose jobs in this crisis. Even before losing their jobs, many could not buy what they needed. One-quarter of families, for example, went without medical care because they could not afford it in 2019. Avoiding medical care now is disastrous.

The extra $600 per week in Pandemic Unemployment Compensation will expire on Friday. The last $600 extra went out last weekend. A lapse in this benefit will mean a delay in payments of weeks. Congress must renew the extra $600 per week now and taper it down only when it is safe to go out and the unemployment rate falls.

Another way to fight the income crisis is one-time payments to all families—referred to as recovery rebates. The first round worked well: Most U.S. families got $1,200 per adult and $500 per child. It came within weeks. Nearly all $300 billion arrived by the end of May. In my forthcoming research with University of Michigan economists Matthew Shapiro and Joel Slemrod, one-fifth of families told us they would mostly spend their rebates, mainly within weeks or a few months. We know from a prior study that families said they will mostly save or pay off debt and will spend some too—the cumulative result of which is for every dollar of rebates, 50 cents was spent quickly.

That’s $150 billion—or 4 percent of all consumer spending in the second quarter. These rebates softened the freefall some. And other researchers confirm the sharp upturn in spending when those rebates arrived. The rebates worked. Do it again.

Congress also must extend the enhanced jobless benefits. Again, my forthcoming research shows that half of the unemployed workers in our nation had not yet received any of these benefits by June. Relief packages are pointless if they do not get into the hands of those who need it.

One last piece of the income crisis is employee wage cuts—a hardship not seen since the Great Depression. This income loss comes on top of the layoffs, the lost overtime, and the fewer hours. Many of these workers are employed by small businesses. Congress must get money to small businesses to keep paying employees. Another round of rebates will help, but it cannot make up for less money in every paycheck.

Fix what did not work, and make it simple

Congress left state and local governments to fend for themselves. It is a disaster. States face rising public health costs from the pandemic at the same time that their revenues have plummeted. As a result, state and local governments had laid off or furloughed 1.5 million workers by June, disproportionately harming women and Black workers. Congress increased its share of Medicaid expenses, but not enough to make up for massive budget shortfalls. State governors are calling on Congress repeatedly to send help. We know from the Great Recession more than a decade ago that our communities need support, or the recovery will be slow and painful. Congress must generously support these fiscally embattled state and local governments.

In the private sector, some businesses have rehired some workers, but that uptick in re-employment is unsustainable amid an unabated public health crisis. Most importantly, Congress must find a better way to get money to small businesses—they are the bedrock of U.S. employment. The Paycheck Protection Program was well-intended but failed to get relief to the hardest hit of these firms. Banks gave loans to their most well-connected customers and those faring relatively well, such as construction businesses that continued operating in the shutdown. But the administration of the loans was confusing and too risky for many businesses. Business owners had to use the funding largely for payroll, but many businesses have other big expenses to overcome to stay afloat.

Then, the rules kept changing. As a sign of the mess, even after Congress put more money into the program, businesses did not borrow. Amanda Fischer, my colleague at Washington Center for Equitable Growth, argues that Congress must do better at targeting smaller businesses. They must expand eligible uses for funding and improve incentives for short-term wage compensation, or work-sharing arrangements. Congress must get relief to business owners of color who are serving low-income neighborhoods and hire workers in those communities who need jobs to come back to and earn living wages. 

Finally, Congress cannot rely on the Federal Reserve to prop up Main Street. The Fed stabilized Wall Street this spring, and bond and equity markets soared. But the indirect effects are not enough to help small businesses and Main Street communities. Loans from the Fed, to date, are not widespread enough to save enough businesses and keep municipalities from laying off more teachers and other frontline public servants. Congress must instruct the Federal Reserve to fully use its Main Street and Municipal Lending Facilities, even if it means making some loans that may not be repaid. The Fed has made only a handful of loans so far, even as tremendous need exists for more financial support.  

Next relief package from Congress

Congress must do what works and commit to doing whatever it takes to support an economic recovery that is strong, stable, and broadly shared. Congress should spend $6 trillion in its next coronavirus relief package. Specifically:

  • $2 trillion to continue enhanced jobless benefits until people are safely back to work
  • $1 trillion for grants to state and local governments
  • $1 trillion in payments to the hardest-hit small businesses
  • $500 billion for public health efforts to contain the pandemic and keep essential workers safe
  • $500 billion for another direct payment to all families now and again at the end of the year
  • $1 trillion for other efforts to support families in need, such as paid child care and sick leave; and rent and mortgage forgiveness

The cost of doing too little now will be enormous in the coming years. No matter what Congress does next, so many families will never get their loved ones back and will never get the chance to say goodbye. But if Congress acts now and commits to stay the course, our workers will get the dignity of work back, our small business owners will succeed, our essential workers will be kept safe, and our children will have teachers. Congress must fight for our future.

Broken plumbing: How systems for delivering economic relief in response to the coronavirus recession failed the U.S. economy

Overview

Sudden economic contractions are dangerous. Individuals experience income shocks that leave them hungry, sick, and frightened. And if left unchecked, these shocks spread. When people lose income, they stop spending, businesses lose customers, layoffs begin, more people lose income, and more people stop spending. This cycle sends hardships rippling through the population.

Well-crafted economic delivery systems to absorb these shocks are crucial to stopping this cycle, but some policymakers in the United States construct them poorly on purpose. They design systems well that transfer cash to the powerful but use faulty delivery systems as a backdoor way to tamp down aid and assistance to everyday people.

To understand how economic delivery systems can stop the cycle of economic contraction, it’s instructive to look back over the past two decades. Economists drew a clear lesson from the Great Recession a decade ago—delivering money to the hardest-hit individuals and families is one of the best tools to break the cycle of economic contraction. When people have money to buy essential goods and services, businesses maintain their customer base and don’t need to lay off staff. And, as Harvard University economist and Equitable Growth Steering Committee member Karen Dynan and her co-authors’ research found, delivering money to working- and middle-class Americans is the best way to create a virtuous cycle to stabilize the U.S. economy amid an economic downturn.

In the early days of the coronavirus recession, Congress realized this and acted, appropriating more than $2.3 trillion to halt the sharp economic downturn. But earmarking money for individuals and families is not enough. Money needs to actually reach consumers for them to spend it and stabilize the economy.

What are the steps between policymakers acting and families having money to spend to meet their needs? A metaphor can be instructive here. Think of the appropriated resources as water, stored in an aquifer. When resources are delivered effectively, a consumer will turn on the tap at her bathroom sink, and the water will flow. To get from the aquifer to the tap, the water flows through a plumbing system. When there are problems with the plumbing, consumers find their taps empty.

Well-functioning delivery systems, like plumbing systems, are essential to stopping the cycle of economic contraction. At the onset of the coronavirus recession, Congress decided to deliver money to consumers using a variety of programs. Each program has its own set of plumbing systems, beset with its own challenges. As economist Esther Duflo at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology notes, economists have a responsibility to not just create theoretical models but also engage in the messy, complicated work of ensuring that our economic “plumbing” is effective.

It is tempting to look at our broken plumbing and feel resigned that it has to be this way. Fixing delivery systems is a relatively boring and decidedly challenging task. But that perspective misses an important fact: For some people and businesses, delivery systems do work well. In fact, they tend to be incredibly effective for the most powerful members of our society. It’s not that good plumbing is too hard to build or that it naturally breaks down over time. Rather, our policymakers intentionally underresource the systems that deliver aid to everyday people, while quietly maintaining systems that efficiently funnel resources to the powerful.

Using faulty plumbing is a discreet way to cut off aid from those with great need but little political power. It can also be a way to deliver aid through channels that provide profit-making opportunities to private plumbing systems that pop up to fill gaps left open by absent or rusty public plumbing. In good times, the burdens of this system are borne primarily by the very vulnerable. In bad times, economic shocks spread more widely, and the plumbing problems affect more people.

Below, we detail four delivery systems tasked with providing relief during the coronavirus recession— relief targeted to small and large businesses, Unemployment Insurance, direct payments to consumers, and paid leave programs—each of them emblematic of a different plumbing problem. Looking at business rescue programs, we see pipes well-designed to flow easily to people with power, while the taps of the less powerful remain dry. Looking at Unemployment Insurance, we see the failure to invest in pipes, preventing these benefits from flowing smoothly to people who need them the most. Looking at direct payments, we see who profits when the plumbing is routed through costly private systems that twist and turn, enabling the powerful to siphon off of the plumbing. And looking at paid leave, we see what happens when policymakers build no pipes at all and suddenly need to turn on a spigot when the economy hits a drought.

To summarize this research brief’s conclusions, policymakers must invest in our economic infrastructure if our economy is to emerge from the COVID crisis more resilient. This includes:

  • Re-engineering plumbing to deliver aid to those who need it most in a manner just as quick as our most sophisticated plumbing for the well-connected and well-resourced. This problem comes into stark relief with regard to business rescue programs.
  • Fixing broken plumbing that has been degraded by years of deliberate neglect. An example of this rusty plumbing is embodied with the degradation of our Unemployment Insurance systems.
  • Re-routing plumbing to deliver aid directly to the most vulnerable and eliminate costly detours that happen along the way. This brief discusses how a public payment system has been supplanted by private delivery channels that are both slower and costlier to our most vulnerable individuals and families.
  • Building new plumbing for new programs that invest in an equitable economy. The absence of a paid leave delivery infrastructure has hobbled our ability to quickly and efficiently set that up in the midst of the coronavirus pandemic.

Business rescue programs—unequal plumbing

Challenges in small business rescue systems

Previous writing from the Washington Center for Equitable Growth discusses how mechanisms to aid small businesses are ad hoc, unfamiliar, and difficult to scale up to reach all impacted firms, while mechanisms to aid medium- to large-sized businesses are efficient, well-practiced, and can be deployed at scale. In other words, the economic plumbing to help our small businesses is rusty and degraded, while the plumbing that serves medium- to large-sized businesses is sturdy and resilient.

How is this playing out during the coronavirus recession? News articles declare that “the small business die-off is here,” notwithstanding the $670 billion approved by Congress to save small businesses via the Paycheck Protection Program. Reporting shows that small business owners did not feel confident that they could meet PPP requirements in time for loans to convert to grants, and that even for those who did receive small business loans, the support may not be enough to cover expenses during periods of mandatory lockdown or partial business closures. A survey of research on the Paycheck Protection Program shows that the loans were not properly targeted to the geographic areas hit hardest by the pandemic or its economic effects, and were not designed in a way to prevent avoidable layoffs. Because the assistance provided by the PPP was relatively shallow in comparison to the shock faced by most small businesses, the program ended up serving as a liquidity backstop for small businesses that needed a temporary boost, rather than a lifeline for the most devastated businesses.

The funding also likely arrived too late for many businesses. Recent research from Opportunity Insights, led by former Equitable Growth Steering Committee member Raj Chetty, finds that small businesses providing services that require face-to-face contact in certain ZIP codes saw an 80 percent drop-off in revenue largely before government rescue money was even available. Moreover, early survey research is showing that small businesses owned by Black and Latinx entrepreneurs are suffering particularly acutely.

The story is different for medium- to large-sized businesses, whose aid came largely via lender-of-last resort interventions by the Federal Reserve rather than through appropriations by Congress. The Federal Reserve’s stated commitments to support the economy across a number of interventions had the effect of bolstering these businesses’ ability to raise capital, even before most policy actions were undertaken. So, it doesn’t even much matter when the Fed starts to lend to companies or buy their bonds because the mere reassurance that the Fed will step in is enough to soothe the markets that serve medium- to large-sized businesses. Investment-grade, or the most creditworthy, U.S. companies issued record-breaking amounts of debt during the first few months of the coronavirus recession and have continued to do so. Junk bonds, or those that are backed by less creditworthy but still medium- to large-sized companies, are strongly rebounding too.

The gap between the efficient business rescue programs for medium- to large-sized businesses and laggard small business rescue programs was known to policymakers well before the coronavirus pandemic caused the latest recession. After the global financial crisis of a decade ago, the stock market and bank profits rebounded quickly, while small businesses recovered much more slowly. While the Federal Reserve at that time was able to calm markets with monetary policy interventions and bail out large financial firms over the course of mere days, small business rescue programs never received a needed revamp.

Fast forward to today. Markets rightly believe Fed Chair Jerome Powell when he says that the Federal Reserve is “not going to run out of ammunition,” largely because the Fed took extraordinary actions a decade ago when faced with the previous crisis.

Small businesses do not hear the same reassurances and would have no reason to believe such statements even if they were declared. In fact, multiple government oversight reports and pieces of journalism document how small business aid was slow to arrive for eligible firms after natural disasters over the course of the past decade. This pattern was replicated on a larger scale during the current crisis, when the U.S. Small Business Administration was tasked with deploying funding provided via the Paycheck Protection Program to ailing small firms.

There certainly are success stories for small businesses due to the Paycheck Protection Program, yet the small business aid also was beset by administrative chaos at its inception. The Small Business Administration website crashed on its first day of launching and many times thereafter, and many small businesses remain in grave danger. One survey of small business owners shows that more than half of them expect to be out of business in the 6 months after the survey was taken in April 2020.

Profit-seeking in private rescue systems

In the case of both programs—both the insufficient small business rescue efforts and the efficient medium- to large-sized business rescue efforts—it should be noted that the government lacked the infrastructure to administer programs directly. In fact, each was administered by agents in the financial sector, rather than through the direct public provision of assistance.

This means that certain private firms, usually the most advantaged and well-connected, profit from the taxpayer-directed deployment of rescue aid. That profit represents funds that reinforce existing political power and that could otherwise be channeled back into helping those suffering.

In the case of small business rescue programs, the Small Business Administration, lacking staff or technical capacity to loan hundreds of billions of dollars using in-house capacity, relied on financial institutions to intermediate the delivery of financial aid from taxpayers to eligible small firms. In exchange for these services, lenders received more than $18 billion in fee income from processing Paycheck Protection Program loans—money that was deducted from the pool of funding available for small businesses.

By intermediating aid through the banking sector, the program also reinforced existing inequities in small business credit, at least according to anecdotal reports. The New York Times reported that a large small business lender established a “concierge service” for VIP business clients, allowing them to bypass call center wait times and avoid online portal snafus. As stated earlier, other stories documented the troubles faced by Black- and Latinx-owned small businesses in accessing funds, repeating longstanding discrimination in small business funding from the banking sector.

Again, this policy choice is not inevitable. Congress could have found ways to directly compensate businesses using systems similar to best practices from abroad. Denmark’s business rescue program, for example, had businesses apply directly to the Danish Business Authority for rescue aid. Denmark is now on track for a much less dramatic collapse in GDP this year, compared to peer countries, due both to the success of public health measures and economic rescue programs in the country. An efficient and already well-developed U.S. Small Business Administration, with pre-existing relationships with the IRS or payroll processing companies, could have worked to release aid in a more efficient and equitable manner.

One natural experiment in the United States is the state of North Dakota, which led the nation in small business rescue funding received per small business worker in the state. Observers credit the Bank of North Dakota, a public bank, for the state leading in the deployment of small business funds. In the words of Robert Hockett, a Cornell University law professor and alumnus of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, in a comment to The Washington Post, “there was no leakage—the sort of ridiculous fee-charging that tends to happen when you do it through larger banking entities.”

He added that the North Dakota model “isn’t really designed to maximize revenue lines by finding as many places to assess fees or brokerage charges as possible.” Though the bank offers few retail services or direct loans, it did serve as a clearinghouse to community banks, educating them about the new program, coordinating across the state, and buying slices of loans from local lenders where needed. The amount and type of help available in North Dakota was clearly well-practiced and scaled to the extent of the crisis in the state.

In the case of large business rescue programs, profit-seeking firms also sit at the center of aid programs. The Federal Reserve is being supported by asset management firms BlackRock, Inc. in the purchase of corporate bonds and Pimco Company in the purchase of commercial paper. Both are programs designed to boost large businesses’ financial health. All told, BlackRock and Pimco are under contract to purchase hundreds of billions of dollars’ worth of financial investments on behalf of the Fed, with BlackRock, for example, slated to earn around $40 million in profit from the services it’s providing.

This raises significant conflict of interest concerns, as each company is also a large shareholder or bondholder in many of the companies whose financial investments they may buy on behalf of taxpayers. In the case of BlackRock, the company was also tasked with purchasing exchange-traded funds, and early reports show that BlackRock ETFs were the primary beneficiaries of BlackRock purchases as an agent of the Federal Reserve. Other observers point to relatively lax conflict of interest standards in place within Federal Reserve financial agent contracts, allowing potentially unfair access to market-moving information. And while these contracts will come up for a bid by the summer, they were initially granted by the Fed on a no-bid, temporary basis in response to the coronavirus recession emergency.

The use of these firms to administer rescue programs on behalf of the Federal Reserve is not a new phenomenon. The same approach was used in response to the 2008 financial crisis, underscoring that the Fed and policymakers have had time to consider alternative approaches to responding to a financial emergency and chose not to build public plumbing, but instead to rely merely on private plumbing. This represents a missed opportunity, as the Federal Reserve System employs almost 23,000 individuals, including sophisticated lawyers, economists, and market experts, and its budget authority is unlimited and set outside the congressional appropriations process. Given that this is the second major rescue program in more than 12 years, it stands to reason that it may be in the public’s best interest to develop this expertise in-house.

Alternatively, scholars such as Saule Omarova and Robert Hockett, both from the Cornell School of Law, suggest that Congress create a National Investment Authority that could serve as an institutional bailout manager, with democratic governance, to manage taxpayer investments in private enterprises with a fiduciary duty to the public. Similar proposals have been floated in major news outlets, harkening back to the Great Depression’s Reconstruction Finance Corporation, and in a piece by Todd Tucker, the director of governance studies at the Roosevelt Institute.

The plumbing that serves our least well-resourced constituencies—small businesses—is rusty, compared to the plumbing that serves medium- to large-sized businesses. Compounding that imbalance is the fact that the very firms that benefit from the efficient plumbing also manage to profit from the laggard plumbing available to others, reinforcing inequities in a feedback loop that accelerates during times of crisis.

Unemployment Insurance—rusty plumbing

At a moment when nearly 1 in 4 U.S. workers is not receiving a paycheck due to a pandemic that is clearly beyond their control and taking place in a country with no paid leave social insurance program, Unemployment Insurance is an obvious choice for delivering income to those who lose work due to the pandemic and its economic fall-out. Indeed, Congress recognized this when they gave states the ability to modify rules affecting the receipt of Unemployment Insurance to suit the conditions of the pandemic, and again when they established three pandemic-specific Unemployment Insurance add-ons: one increasing the benefit amount, another lengthening the benefit duration, and a third expanding the group of people eligible for benefits to include independent contractors, those with low earnings, and independent contractors.

Yet when people went to access the benefits they were entitled to under the law, many were greeted by crashed websites, jammed phone lines, and even instructions to line up in person to receive paper applications. The $600 weekly increase took weeks to implement, and in some states, the program expanding benefits to new groups of claimants took months. While some policymakers try to pass off this state of affairs as an unexpected tragedy—a sad coincidence that the system was out of shape just when benefits were needed most—the difficulties with benefit delivery are the result of decades of conscious choice by policymakers to starve the system of the resources it needed most. With computing systems that are hard to navigate for claimants and challenging to update for administrators, and without adequate resources for staffing and system updates, the plumbing for delivering Unemployment Insurance benefits is broken from years of neglect. 

Unemployment Insurance program administration is funded through federal taxes based on employee payroll—referred to as FUTA taxes after the Federal Unemployment Tax Act. Taxes are collected at a rate of 0.6 percent (the FUTA tax rate is 6 percent, but a 5.4 percent credit is applied for state taxes paid) and are levied on the first $7,000 of earnings for each worker on an employer’s payroll. For a full-time, year-round employee, the FUTA tax is $42 per worker per year.

These taxes are technically charged to employers, but research finds that employers pass the cost on to workers by paying them less. This revenue is tasked with not only maintaining more than 50 administrative systems but also funding half the cost of the extended benefits that workers receive in times of economic contraction. In 1939, the taxable wage base was $3,000, equivalent to $55,000 in 2020 dollars. Because this amount can only be raised by law (and has only increased three times over the past 80 years), its value has eroded by nearly 800 percent. In contrast, the taxable wage base for Social Security benefits was indexed to inflation in 1977. The chart below shows their divergent histories. (See Figure 1.)

Figure 1

U.S. Unemployment Insurance and Social Security taxable wage bases, 2019 dollars, 1937–2019

This trend has been labeled fiscal constriction by Columbia University scholar Alexander Hertel-Fernandez, and it means that by starving the Unemployment Insurance program of resources, policymakers effectively bind their own hands and purposefully prevent themselves from establishing a modern and efficient system for disbursing benefits. During the Great Recession, we saw the consequences of fiscal constriction clearly. Yet federal policymakers left the taxable wage base at the same level it has been stuck at since 1983, unmoved by the hardship of millions of members of the U.S. labor force and unwilling to risk even a small amount of political capital by modestly nudging tax levels upward.

Bringing the Unemployment Insurance taxable wage base back to the same level as the Social Security taxable wage base and then indexing it to inflation would provide states with the resources they need to deliver unemployment benefits efficiently and effectively.

Looking to 2017 as an example and conducting a simple back-of-the-envelope calculation that keeps the FUTA tax rate at 6 percent and applies a 5.4 percent state credit reduction to the $7 trillion of taxable earnings under the Social Security wage base indicates that using this tax base would generate $41 billion. This is a $33 billion increase over the $8 billion in FUTA taxes that were actually collected in 2017. Similar to other social insurance programs, Unemployment Insurance has an elegant design—small taxes in good times ensure smooth delivery of benefits in hard times. By allowing the pay-for to erode over time, policymakers shirk their fiscal responsibility, and workers and families pay the price. Following the Social Security model and indexing the wage base is a small investment that will yield large dividends.

In fact, this additional revenue would provide sufficient funds for Unemployment Insurance system modernization efforts (past grants to states have ranged from $50 million to $200 million), ongoing maintenance, and appropriate staffing. These funds also could be used to provide grants to states to partner with community-based organizations serving vulnerable workers to raise awareness of Unemployment Insurance benefits and provide assistance in the application process. Additional revenue would cover the increased use of the Extended Benefits program and could be used to provide grants to states as they standardize the amount and length of benefits, as detailed below. Any change to the taxable wage base could be scheduled—for example, occurring when unemployment rates return to pre-pandemic levels with revenue advanced prior to that time.

Without this type of policy change, policymakers won’t have the resources that are so badly needed to repair our broken plumbing and efficiently deliver benefits to people who are entitled to them under law. The case of Unemployment Insurance shows that it’s not enough to build a system to disburse benefits—that money needs to be spent over the long haul to maintain that system. This type of continued investment is necessary to deliver the benefits that provide relief to individuals and stabilize our economy when crisis hits.

Direct payments to households—plumbing that twists and turns to allow siphoning off along the way

Most Americans live on razor-thin budgets, even in good times. One study from the Federal Reserve has found that only 40 percent of Americans could cover a $400 emergency expense.

So, when Congress authorized emergency direct payments to households as part of the Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security, or CARES, Act, the efficiency of the plumbing was nearly as important as the amount of water unleashed from the aquifer. The degradation of our public plumbing systems—namely, the IRS as an agency tasked with locating all U.S. taxpayers and building a channel to allow payments between individuals and the government—was laid bare.

While around 6 in 10 people who file taxes received a direct deposit refund from the IRS in 2018 or 2019—the filing years the IRS used to track bank account information for these payments—4 in 10 filers, representing almost 64 million filers, did not (the vast majority of those 64 million filers was eligible for CARES Act payments, which phase out for higher-income earners). These individuals and families had to wait weeks for paper checks to be mailed, with one estimate suggesting that certain filers may have to keep waiting until September, about 20 weeks after the direct payments were authorized by Congress. While the IRS rightly prioritized mailing checks out sooner for those with the lowest adjusted gross income, mailing paper checks still took weeks longer than for those with direct deposit numbers on file.

Those who don’t file tax returns with the IRS faced an even more complex situation. Social Security recipients who didn’t, in the recent past, file tax returns received unclear information about whether they had to file a supplementary tax form to get a direct payment check and had to meet a deadline if they wanted to claim dependents. While the IRS set up an online portal for nonfilers to report direct deposit information and avoid the check-mailing process, the deadline for such submissions was May 13, and many less-tech-savvy individuals probably didn’t know where to enter that information or were unable to do so.

While the IRS worked as quickly as possible to deploy money in a timely manner, there are consequences to this lack of preparedness. Those who receive paper checks may have needed, or may still need, to get expensive payday loans to tide them over until checks arrive. Others still may overdraft on their bank accounts, leading to fees. Others who don’t need an advance on their checks may need to go to expensive check cashers to convert checks into money once they arrive. And because policymakers allowed creditors to “eat first” once checks arrived, stories surfaced showing that banks garnished the checks deposited into peoples’ accounts, both to repay bank debts and on behalf of debt collectors.

All told, direct coronavirus-payment challenges replicate our existing understanding of the high cost of being poor, with low- to moderate-income households spending far more than other households on fees as a percentage of their income, averaging a whopping 10 percent of income, using data from before the coronavirus.

These expenses reflect a lack of public economic infrastructure. And while they represent burdensome budget items for some, they represent profit to others. Banks made an estimated $11.68 billion in overdraft fees in 2019, with an average fee of around $35 per overdraft. These fees fall particularly hard on the working class, with only 9 percent of account holders (typically those with low account balances) representing 84 percent of the total fees charged. Check cashers and payday lenders made a similar amount in fees, totaling around $11.4 billion in 2019.

Further, the tax preparation company TurboTax, owned by Intuit Inc., created a proprietary website where individuals could go to enter direct deposit information, calculate anticipated check amounts, and check on the status of their payments. While the website services are offered at no charge, TurboTax has, in the past, used the promise of free services to steer filers into more expensive proprietary and add-on products, even when they qualified for free filing. TurboTax made $1.6 billion in income in the most recent filing year.

Solutions for quicker direct payments

All of these frictions were avoidable had other public policy choices been made. Just as fiscal constriction has hobbled state Unemployment Insurance systems, federal policy has deliberately underinvested in technical capacity and potential delivery systems for the IRS. While the IRS staff had an unenviable task of accomplishing the massive technical and logistical challenge of deploying millions of direct payments in a matter of weeks during a global pandemic, the snafus experienced by the agency were undoubtably made worse by sustained budget cuts over the past decade. As the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities documents, the IRS has lost nearly 15 percent of its staff and 21 percent of its budget since 2009. A more well-resourced IRS would have been better prepared for this moment.

Policymakers also missed an opportunity to build out the IRS’s technology infrastructure by not considering legislation to direct and support the IRS in establishing a free file online portal system for annual tax returns. Though envisioned as a tool for routine annual filings before the pandemic, such a system run by a well-resourced IRS could have been quickly repurposed to meet direct payment needs and could have supplanted TurboTax.

Moreover, policymakers could have advanced other actions to strengthen payment delivery mechanisms to individuals and households. The United States has one of the slowest payment systems in the world, compared to peer countries. This means that it can take days after funds are deposited in private bank accounts for those funds to actually be available to spend. Again, in the case of the coronavirus recession, this adds yet more frictions to the delivery of aid. But this slow system is not inevitable.

In the United States, the Federal Reserve both regulates the private payment system and operates its own system. The private payment system, which is the dominant system, is operated by The Clearing House, a consortium of 24 large banks. The Fed has long had the goal of modernizing its own payment system, which hasn’t been updated in decades, releasing a proposal to bolster payment infrastructure in 2013 and then committing in 2019 to finalize an upgraded payment infrastructure by 2024.

Such moves to modernize our public payment infrastructure have been opposed by The Clearing House. The bank association argues that large banks have already invested substantial time in building their own system, that the Fed cannot act as both a regulator and a competitor, and that further investments would be needed to ensure interoperability with the new Fed system. Below the surface are the obvious concerns that this public system would undercut The Clearing House’s market dominance, would reduce profits on payment transactions, and would dampen the use of overdrafts, thereby further reducing bank fees.

In the case of the deployment of coronavirus rescue funds, a public, faster payment system would have clear benefits. One estimate from Aaron Klein, policy director for the Center on Regulation and Markets at The Brookings Institution, finds that implementing the Fed’s real-time payment system could save low-income families $7 billion a year simply by helping money to arrive faster and allowing families to thereby avoid intermediaries such as check-cashing services and payday lending companies to access their money.

Further, a public payment system also would help small businesses to manage incoming and outgoing payments, as these businesses are now operating on thinner margins during the recession. Lastly, a faster digital payment system is essential during a highly transmissible pandemic. While the use of cash to make payments has been declining for years, public health concerns and social distancing have increased the need to more quickly mediate money electronically.

In addition to building a quicker public payment system to deliver funds to private bank accounts, policymakers also could build accounts that are themselves public. Legislation based on the work of Washington Center for Equitable Growth Board member Mehrsa Baradaran has, for years, been introduced to allow the U.S. Postal Service to provide basic banking services to customers—bank accounts that could be available in every community across the country and could allow for a functioning economic system that equitably serves all individuals and families.

In this way, policymakers could eliminate or reduce costly fees and stop garnishments through this public system. And it wouldn’t be a new or untested approach. The U.S. Postal Service has done this in the past, providing banking services for 50 years starting in 1911. This would have the benefit of both expanding access, reducing costs to consumers, and shoring-up the finances of the postal system, which stands in a precarious position due to both the pandemic and congressional legislation that has required the service to pre-pay 75 years’ worth of healthcare and retirement benefits for workers. The Postal Service could offer these accounts either through a congressional authorization or via administrative action, with its Board of Governors authorizing the measure.

Paid leave—when plumbing does not exist

If ever there were a moment that called for paid leave, the coronavirus crisis is it. The term “paid family and medical leave” refers to social insurance programs in which a small payroll tax is collected while people work and then—when the need arises to care for a new child, seriously ill loved one, or one’s own serious medical need—workers can take weeks or months away from work with partial wage replacement. In some thoughtfully designed paid leave programs, workers are guaranteed to be able to return to their job when their leave is complete.

Most paid leave programs were not designed with a pandemic in mind, but they are built to deliver paid time away from work for health reasons while maintaining attachment to one’s employer. If you are scratching your head and wondering why policymakers chose not to deliver payments through a small modification to the eligibility criteria associated with our federal paid leave system, the answer is simple: We do not have a federal paid leave system. Legislation has been introduced for many years that proposes the adoption of a federal paid leave program. Yet political obstacles have prevented us from establishing a federal system, despite the research that suggests doing so would strengthen the economy and benefit the finances and health of paid leave claimants and those who receive care from them. A lack of a federal system leaves us scrambling to provide paid leave solutions when workers need them most.

Congress eventually passed legislation in response to the employment crisis caused by the COVID pandemic. But the “paid leave” program it enacted bears little resemblance to a strong social insurance system that provides adequate time away from work to care for oneself or a loved one. This is a temporary stop-gap, not an investment in permanent plumbing. This stop-gap system provides a fraction of the workforce with 80 hours of leave at full pay for those with symptoms or the need to quarantine due to one’s own COVID-19, the disease caused by the coronavirus, 80 hours at two-thirds pay for to care for someone subject to quarantine or a child subject to COVID-19-related school or childcare closure, and another 10 weeks of leave at two-thirds pay to provide childcare for one’s own children who are subject to COVID-19-related school or childcare closure. These benefits don’t provide the support that social insurance programs offer and that people whose families are affected by COVID-19 need: weeks, not days, of leave to attend to one’s illness or the illness of loved ones.

While the benefit is not generous enough, the real problem is program administration. The first problem is the glaring issue of the program coverage. Despite the largest firms having the greatest financial and staffing flexibility to allow for leave, no person who works at a firm with 500 or more employees is eligible for leave. Employers with fewer than 50 employees, too, can easily opt out, as can firms that employ healthcare workers or emergency responders.

What’s more, the interpretation of the healthcare carve-out is broad—anyone who works at a healthcare facility, from janitors to accountants, can be carved out. Sarah Jane Glynn at the Center for American Progress finds that as few as 1 in 5 private-sector workers may end up eligible for paid leave.

Then, being eligible for a benefit does not mean that a person can access it. Many factors influence what social scientists call the “take up” of benefits. Key factors include program knowledge, the ease or difficulty of applying for or being granted access to a program, and—in many cases—employer behavior that encourages or impedes claims. When it comes to the newly implemented federal paid leave program, there is a perfect storm of factors that create leaky plumbing. Money that Congress intended to channel to men and women who need time off from work due to COVID-19 is not reaching them in part, it appears, because of the lack of a robust public awareness campaign. Given that most people in the United States do not have access to state-provided paid time off and thus are unfamiliar with the concept, raising awareness of the new program is extremely important—and extremely difficult in the context of the pandemic.

To extend the plumbing metaphor: If people don’t realize that new taps have been installed, they can’t access the water that flows from them. It’s best to install the taps at times when people’s attention is not divided, so that they are aware of them well in advance of when they need to access them.

There is another major reason that we hypothesize depressed paid leave take-up rates: the confusing process of benefit reimbursement. Employers are required to cover the cost of the leave upfront and then are reimbursed quarterly for these costs. This complex way of paying for benefits means that employers who do not want to deal with paperwork or who cannot afford to front the cost of paid leave have an incentive to discourage employees from accessing their right to paid leave and may confuse employees who would otherwise hope to access the benefit.

When workers come to states with questions about their right to access paid leave, state labor departments are hamstrung: They don’t enforce the law, even though state residents come to them with issues. Good state-federal coordination is difficult to develop quickly, but it is crucial to ensure that workers can access the benefits they need. In the absence of a pre-existing plumbing system, workers were left with a temporary and unsatisfactory fix.

State paid leave systems provide a clear illustration of what a federal paid leave system could have provided, had it been established. When the coronavirus pandemic hit U.S. shores, residents of five states had access to state paid leave programs. In Rhode Island, shortly following Gov. Gina Raimondo’s (D) declaration of a public health emergency, the governor worked with the state’s Department of Labor and Training to ensure that people affected by the pandemic could access paid leave. The result: Paid leave claim rates in Rhode Island shot up in the early days of March. (See Figure 2.)

Figure 2

Weekly paid family and medical leave claims, March–May 2020

Because an existing social insurance program was already in place, Rhode Islanders were able to access paid time off when they needed it most. The plumbing was in place to deliver the needed assistance. In contrast, residents of the 45 states that lack paid leave programs waited as Congress debated how to best deliver aid, ultimately receiving a program that missed the mark for effectively delivering paid leave to those who needed it most.

If the federal government had had a strong benefit delivery system in place before the coronavirus pandemic hit, then the benefits that are needed would be flowing much more easily and efficiently. In the wake of this catastrophe, some policymakers are calling for a permanent fix—a federal social insurance program—so that our nation is not caught off-guard the next time a crisis hits.

Conclusion

To break the current cycle of economic contraction and prepare to do so again in the future, policymakers need to deliver benefits to workers and families so that they can pay their rent, fill their prescriptions, and keep food on the table—setting into motion the virtuous cycle of economic stabilization. This moment requires an unprecedented scale of investments in people and businesses in the United States in order to mitigate the pain caused by this economic recession.

But our programs are only as effective as the plumbing we use to distribute those resources in a timely and equitable manner. Systematic disinvestment in our economic infrastructure impaired the well-being of the people in the United States, particularly those who are most vulnerable even in normal economic times. Policymakers’ decisions to allow, or even hasten, the degradation of economic infrastructure is a choice, not a coincidence. Our faulty plumbing has been purposefully neglected, poorly constructed, and designed in the service of short-term profits for some and as a backdoor way to deny aid to the most disadvantaged members of society.

To stabilize our economy in times of macroeconomic contraction, we need to redesign our invisible economic infrastructure to more quickly help individuals and families, not just the most well-resourced, eliminate costly toll collection from financial intermediaries, and reinvest in durable plumbing to prepare us for the next drought.

Sleepwalking into depression: The economic response to COVID-19 in the United States

Almost five months into our country’s response to the coronavirus pandemic and ensuing recession, policymakers seem to have lost the urgency that characterized the initial days of dramatic, bipartisan action. In March, four pieces of coronavirus legislation were passed and signed into law. But over the following 2 months, very little in the way of meaningful new policy action occurred. What’s worse, some congressional leaders, squinting at recent data through rose-colored glasses, are ready to declare “mission accomplished,” letting the previous legislation expire and taking no further action.

Are they right? Well, the stock market is now about even for the year. Unemployment declined by 1.4 percentage points in May, and 2.2 percentage points in June. Retail sales increased by 17.7 percent in May, the largest increase ever. And deaths per day from COVID-19, the disease spread by the novel coronavirus, have fallen by half. With the vast majority of stimulus checks delivered and cashed, and with the extra payments for the unemployed set to expire at the end of July, might the U.S. economy be able to muddle along without further support?

The short answer is no—not by a long shot. The few green shoots of improved economic data belie the fact that the health and economic crises are far from over. In fact, we are in danger of sleepwalking into economic depression.

What real-time data are telling us

A careful review of the data reveals gaping wounds caused by the coronavirus pandemic: large declines in market incomes, consumer spending, and employment, all barely propped up by the temporary government stimulus payments. To prevent economic collapse, it is urgent that policymakers take further action. Congress must continue to support unemployed workers’ incomes, send additional stimulus payments to families to keep them financially afloat and increase spending, and give aid to local and state governments so they don’t have to lay off workers.

But, most importantly, policymakers at the state and federal levels must do more to control the spread of the coronavirus, which is now growing at the rate of 70,000 cases a day.

The April Personal Consumption and Income report from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis showed a historic collapse of consumption expenditures, with total spending down 13.6 percent. The decline came despite a record increase in personal income of 10.8 percent, due to the massive inflow of federal stimulus and Unemployment Insurance payments. Without these transfer payments, personal income would have declined 6.3 percent in April and spending would have collapsed even further. For every dollar of stimulus, households increased spending by 25 cents to 35 cents, according to recent estimates, while previous research shows that every dollar of Unemployment Insurance benefits leads to 27 cents of spending.

Thanks in large part to pandemic-related income support, spending recovered somewhat in May, rising 8.2 percent, but it is still down 9.8 percent from the same period in 2019. The most recent official data, the June Retail Sales report, shows that spending on retail goods has largely recovered to its level from last year, while spending on restaurants remain depressed, down 26 percent from its period last year.

While government data give the most accurate picture of the aggregate economic situation, alternative real-time data are crucially important in understanding the scale of the economic crisis and determining the appropriate government response. In a recent paper, I use real-time payment data from Earnest Research, a company that analyzes spending data from credit and debit cards, to study the latest on how consumer spending is responding to the pandemic.

My analysis based on these data examines measures of real-time retail and restaurant spending growth, comparing weeks in 2020 with the corresponding weeks in 2019. The higher-frequency data show that the spending drop came at the end of March and beginning of April, followed by a partial recovery at the end of April. The revival stalled somewhat in May, but continued again in June, with spending in some weeks actually above 2019 levels. In July, however, there are initial signs that with Covid-19 cases spiking again, spending is declining, with retail spending down 7 percent for the week ending July 15. (See Figure 1.)

Figure 1

Year-over-year change in spending on retail and restaurants, excluding automobiles

Restaurant spending saw a sharper decline and slower recovery: As of July 15, it was still down more than 15 percent. Aggregate service spending saw the largest decline in spending, more than 50 percent, and was still down more than 40 percent as of July 15.

The decline in consumer demand raises the specter that even if businesses are able to reopen after lockdowns end, there will not be enough demand to sustain them. A recent survey of small business owners found their biggest concern is that sales will not be high enough to justify their reopening. Layoffs—initially concentrated in sectors directly affected by the pandemic, such as restaurants and hotels—have metastasized to white-collar sectors, such as professional services, finance, and real estate.

Unemployment remains at a staggering level, with the latest jobs report showing 18 million Americans unemployed. The unemployment rate in June 2020, 11.1 percent, is the highest it’s been since the Great Depression in the 1930s, except for the previous two months. The good news in the report was that this elevated level is down 3.6 percentage points from April, driven mainly by workers who were on temporary layoffs being recalled to their jobs. The largest gains were in the leisure, hospitality, and retail trade sectors. Unemployment among Black workers declined by only 1.3 percent between April and June, about a third of the magnitude of White workers. And the data contained other worrying signs: The number of workers who have permanently lost their jobs increased to almost 3 million.

There are two additional factors that cause the headline number to understate the impact of the pandemic on employment. First, the report counts as employed an extra 2 million people who were “not at work for other reasons” and does not include the 4.6 million who have left the labor force since February. The 2 million were misclassified in error and should rightfully be counted as part of the true unemployment rate. Second, usually workers who leave the labor force are not included in totals of unemployment, but this pandemic presents a special case. Labor force participation fell substantially between February and May; a decline this large suggests that some of the people leaving the labor force may have done so temporarily due to the difficulties of looking for a job. Adjusting for these factors would increase the June unemployment rate to 13 percent.

Another worrying sign in the jobs data is government employment. State government employment declined by 247,00 between March and June, local government employment fell by a staggering 1.2 million, and federal government employment has been flat. As the coronavirus pandemic knocks a massive hole in their budgets, governments are laying off workers by the thousands. Lower consumer spending means lower tax revenue, and new coronavirus-related expenses means higher government spending. As a result, state and local governments are tightening their budgets at the worst possible moment for the economy. These government cuts have disparate impacts on Black Americans, who make up 12 percent of the labor force but 18 percent of government jobs.

The overall picture of the economy, then, is seriously troubling. Consumers are struggling, with incomes propped up by massive government stimulus and unemployment benefits. Some businesses are recalling furloughed workers but are concerned about a lack of demand. And governments are cutting employment and essential services due to unanticipated expenses and rapid declines in revenues. These fundamental issues will not resolve themselves on their own. The government acted with surprising alacrity in passing the Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security, or CARES, Act in March, but further action is needed.

Policy proposals to head off a depression

First and foremost, the extra $600 per week Unemployment Insurance payments, slated to expire on July 31, should be extended and based on automatic triggers tied to an eventual economic recovery. The benefits are not only a lifeline to the 20 million workers who have been laid off but also the thin thread by which consumer spending is hanging. The drop in income and spending from the expiration of this benefit would be catastrophic for an economy in which market income is falling and spending has collapsed. Congress must extend the benefits and not put an expiration date on them, keeping them elevated until triggered off by unemployment returning to normal.

But even this is not enough. Given the collapse in consumer spending, it is clear that more demand support is needed than additional Unemployment Insurance payments. While the $1,200 stimulus payment in the CARES Act was a good start, there is no reason for this to be a one-off benefit. Monthly payments—$1,000 would be a good start—should be made until unemployment returns to normal and/or consumer spending improves.

State and local budget deficits through 2021 might approach $1 trillion. Without additional aid, the shedding of government workers across the country will continue. This is not a short-term issue that can be solved with a one-time stimulus bill. Once again, what is needed is monthly aid to state and local governments that continues until the unemployment rate returns to normal and states’ fiscal health improves.

While each of these policies can help to deal with the symptoms of the economic collapse, the fundamental cause remains the continuing spread of the novel coronavirus and the lethality of COVID-19 uncontained. Many of the layoffs are in the restaurant, travel, and retail sector, whose customers will not come back in sufficient numbers until it is safe to do so. Even with states beginning to reopen, 78 percent of Americans say they would be uncomfortable eating at a restaurant, and 67 percent are not comfortable shopping at a retail clothing store. While the outbreak may have left the front pages of some newspapers, it continues unabated. Around 500 Americans per day are dying from COVID-19, with 70,000 new cases reported each day.

Several of the hardest-hit European countries, such as Italy and Spain, have succeeded in suppressing new cases to the low hundreds per day. They did so by following the only tried-and-true plan that has worked against the coronavirus: a comprehensive program of tracking and tracing, with massive testing and effective tracing and quarantining of those exposed to the virus. Compared with the four economic stimulus plans Congress has already passed, the cost of these public health measures is moderate. Congress has already spent more than $1 trillion on relief and recovery measures—and more will be necessary—but the cost of following the proven path these other nations have taken would run in the relatively modest tens of billions of dollars, and could save additional trillions of dollars in consequently unneeded stimulus costs down the road. 

There is much to be done. The federal government, state governments, and local governments must refocus and redouble their efforts to suppress the virus. A plan by Sens. Michael Bennet (D-CO) and Kirsten Gillibrand (D-NY) would create a national test-and-trace program that would hire hundreds of thousands of people who would help carry out testing, contact tracing, and eventually vaccinating to fight the coronavirus, at the cost of $55 billion. The Medical Supply Transparency and Delivery Act of Sens. Tammy Baldwin (D-WI) and Chris Murphy (D-CT) would finally rationalize the medical supply chain, utilizing the Defense Production Act to ensure the production of critical medical supplies.

At the state and local levels, the burgeoning test-and-trace programs that have been introduced can be scaled up and expanded with increased federal resources. The CARES act allocates some funding for contact tracing, but billions of dollars in additional funding is needed.

Recovery from the coronavirus pandemic and the coronavirus recession is neither close nor assured. This mission has not been accomplished. The federal government needs to act and spend aggressively to support families, workers, and states and localities, and restore consumer demand. Acting swiftly and certainly can mean the difference between a lengthy, weak recovery with unnecessary suffering by those who already suffer from economic and racial inequality, and a strong recovery that leads to stable, broad-based growth and a more equitable economy.

New research on the Great Recession shows extended unemployment benefits insignificantly affect U.S. unemployment rates

Unemployment rates in the United States are currently higher than they were at height of the Great Recession, standing at 11.1 percent in June after declining from a record high of 14.7 percent in April, compared 10.6 percent at the height of the previous recession in January 2010. Amid the deepening coronavirus recession, Unemployment Insurance is critical to keeping families afloat and bolstering our economy, just as the program has been throughout economic downturns since its federal inception in the Social Security Act of 1935.

Then and now, however, there is a common public narrative that purports generous and lengthy access to Unemployment Insurance is a disincentive to work, with people choosing to stay home and receive benefits rather than return to work. New cutting-edge research examining unemployment benefits and unemployment rates during and after the Great Recession demonstrates that was not the case then—with key implications today as Congress and the Trump administration negotiate whether and how to extend the Pandemic Unemployment Compensation program beyond the end of this month.

Forthcoming in the American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, the paper is titled “Unemployment Insurance Generosity and Aggregate Unemployment,” by Christopher Boone of Cornell University, Arindrajit Dube of University of Massachusetts Amherst, Lucas Goodman of the U.S. Treasury Department, and Ethan Kaplan of the University of Maryland, College Park. Their new research reveals that emergency Unemployment Insurance and extended benefits during and after the Great Recession did not increase unemployment rates between counties with longer access to those benefits, compared to those with shorter access. The four researchers find that overall bad economic conditions, such as those which occurred more than a decade ago and are evident again today, determine U.S. labor market outcomes more than generous access to unemployment benefits.

Prior to the steep downturn this year, the Great Recession was one of the biggest economic crises in a lifetime. Policymakers responded by instituting large increases in the duration of Unemployment Insurance, from 26 weeks to 99 weeks, but there were variations across states in both magnitude and timing. These changes were executed through the Emergency Unemployment Compensation program enacted by Congress on June 30, 2008 and modified seven times subsequently, as well as through the already-existing Extended Benefits program that provided 13 weeks or 20 additional weeks of Unemployment Insurance triggered by the level or pace of increase of a state’s unemployment rate.

Those triggers for Extended Benefits, however, are optional for states to take up, so many states opted out of providing more generous benefits in the Great Recession, resulting in variation between states in the duration of benefits available to unemployed workers. Both changes in policy over time through the Emergency Unemployment Compensation program and changes between states through the Extended Benefits program allow for what economists call a natural experiment to examine the impact of greater generosity in unemployment benefits on aggregate employment.

Boone, Dube, Goodman, and Kaplan implement what’s known as a cross-border-pair methodology—which examines differences in policy outcomes in similar regions of the economy and was pioneered by economists David Card and Alan Krueger—alongside an event study design, both with the Quarterly Census of Employment Dynamics, to test whether the long duration of unemployment benefits increased aggregate unemployment in states with more generous Unemployment Insurance. The four researchers find that the longer duration of benefits and the greater the increases to benefits result in a very small, positive impact on employment rates within those counties, with their results not statistically different than zero. While the overall employment-to-population ratio declined by 3 percentage points during the Great Recession, counties with more generous benefits may have offset this somewhat, or at least did not have worse employment outcomes.

Their paper directly challenges previous research that finds negative impacts on county employment rates as a result of longer Unemployment Insurance benefits, particularly work by Marcus Hagedorn of the University of Oslo, Iourii Manovskii of the University of Pennsylvania, and Kurt Mitman of Stockholm University. They followed a similar methodology. Boone, Dube, Goodman, and Kaplan rectify these discrepancies by noting that their paper makes use of superior administrative data in the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages. The four researchers also critique the methodology of the previous research for using a “quasi-forward differencing” as a dependent variable based on anticipation of policy changes rather than the actual policy changes, and for examining a shorter time horizon.

Boone, Dube, Goodman, and Kaplan also address other critiques of the cross-border-pair methodology by dropping counties where employment was correlated with state levels of employment and by including county fixed effects. Their results did not change when dropping potentially spurious counties. Boone, Dube, Goodman, and Kaplan also note that their findings align with additional research using alternative methodologies that find similar insignificant impacts of duration generosity.

This cutting-edge research from the previous economic downturn demonstrates that benefit generosity in an economic crisis does not negatively impact employment levels, prolonging the labor market downturn. As the policy debate over extending more generous unemployment benefits will surely continue throughout the current recession, this new research supports the proposals included in Equitable Growth and the Hamilton Project’s Recession Ready essay compilation that calls for increased generosity in Unemployment Insurance, as well as triggers that extend the duration of benefits based on state-level unemployment rates.

As we demonstrate in our new factsheet, “Unemployment Insurance and why the effect of work disincentives is greatly overstated amid the coronavirus recession,” the research shows that Unemployment Insurance not only does not appear to have a significant impact on increasing unemployment rates, but also that there are other positive effects such as increasing aggregate demand to help support our economy in a crisis.

Factsheet: Unemployment Insurance and why the effect of work disincentives is greatly overstated amid the coronavirus recession

The United Artists Theatres in Berkeley, CA., is one of the many venues that was forced to close at the onset of the coronavirus pandemic.

Under the Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security, or CARES, Act,the Pandemic Unemployment Compensation program added a $600 weekly boost to Unemployment Insurance payments. Despite being one of the most effective policy responses to the coronavirus recession yet, the enhanced payments are set to expire at the end of July. The idea that Unemployment Insurance creates incentives for workers to remain unemployed has emerged as the main argument against extending the additional weekly $600, with critics arguing that generous benefits are “undermining the economic recovery.”

As this factsheet points out, current labor market indicators show jobless benefits have a negligible effect on unemployment levels. But the enhancements to Unemployment Insurance have a big impact on the economy and have set in motion a virtuous cycle that helps workers weather an economic crisis while keeping demand for goods and services from plummeting. Here are the facts.

The coronavirus health crisis—not enhanced unemployment benefits—are behind the spike in unemployment

Even after strong employment gains in May and June, the U.S. economy has lost 15 million jobs since February, and new unemployment claims have stood above their Great Recession high for 15 straight weeks. The absence of safe working conditions, a sharp drop in consumer spending, and lack of support for parents and caregivers are preventing millions from working.  

More specifically:

  • Using real-time data from small businesses, a team of economists find that the states where benefits replace a greater portion of workers’ wages experienced the smallest drop in hours of work in March and, as of early June, the strongest recovery. Another analysis finds that receiving jobless benefits had no effect on workers’ likelihood of finding a job.
  • The U.S. vacancy yield, which measures the ratio of hired workers for every job opening, shows that employers are now filling open positions faster than at any point since February 2012. Lack of opportunities to work, not a disincentive to work, are keeping unemployment elevated. (See Figure 1.)
  • Data from Indeed.com—a widely used job-search website—show that there were 23 percent fewer job openings in early July 2020 than in the same moment the previous year. Data from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics show that there are now almost four unemployed workers for every job opening.

Figure 1

U.S. total nonfarm hires per total nonfarm job openings, 2000–2020

Concerns about work disincentives overstate the negative impact of jobless benefits on employment and minimize the positive impacts evident in economic research

There is no academic consensus on the effect of the duration or generosity of unemployment benefits on employment. Research shows, however, that any effect these benefits might have on overall unemployment is small and likely to be weaker in downturns than in booms. Consider:

  • Cutting-edge research on the duration of Unemployment Insurance finds that the expansion of jobless benefits during and after the Great Recession had a negligible effect on unemployment rates. When comparing similar workers facing similar labor market conditions, states where workers could get benefits for longer did not have higher rates of unemployment.
  • By providing a lifeline when jobs are scarce, Unemployment Insurance can keep workers engaged in searching for jobs even when jobs are hard to find, keeping many from dropping out of the labor force altogether.

Unemployment Insurance provides liquidity to the workers who need it the most, getting cash in the hands of those more likely to spend it. Those who have been hardest hit by the crisis—Black, Latinx, and low-income households—are less likely to have the liquid financial assets needed to maintain their consumption when their earnings suddenly go down.

Until the coronavirus pandemic and recession are under control, rolling back unemployment benefits will exacerbate the public health crisis and deepen the downturn

Under normal circumstances, Unemployment Insurance allows workers to put food on the table as they search for suitable work, supporting overall economic activity. In the context of a global pandemic and the sharp recession it sparked, providing workers with time and financial resources as they search for suitable work is even more crucial. Specifically:

  • Without adequate health and safety workplace standards, face-to-face jobs will put millions of workers at risk. Workers need time and resources to search for suitable work that will not jeopardize their health or public health.
  • In the economics literature, the concept of compensating wage differentials describes the additional earnings needed to offset the negative risks associated with some jobs. The true costs to workers of being exposed to a deadly virus in a pandemic is not reflected in the pre-pandemic wage levels used to calculate benefit amounts. Enhanced Unemployment Insurance allows workers to make decisions based on safety rather than desperation during the pandemic.
  • The Economic Policy Institute estimates that extending Pandemic Unemployment Compensation payments through mid-2021 would provide 5.1 million jobs by maintaining demand for goods and services.

The emphasis on work disincentives serves to exclude Black and low-wage workers and reflects racist biases against low-income workers of color

As with other safety net programs, opposition to a robust Unemployment Insurance system often acts to prevent workers of color from receiving their fair share of unemployment benefits. This is especially true for Black workers. Consider:

  • Despite applying for Unemployment Insurance at similar rates than unemployed White workers, unemployed Black workers—and especially unemployed Black women workers—have been much less likely to receive benefits. States with a higher share of Black workers tend to have less generous jobless benefits. For Black workers, an estimate shows, the average maximum weekly benefit is $40 short of that received by White workers. (See Figure 2)

Figure 2

Regular Unemployment Insurance wage-replacement rate by state, January–March 2020
  • Depending on the state, the withdrawal of the additional $600 would lead to a median cut in benefits of 52 percent to 72 percent. The drop would be of 71 percent in Arizona, 71 percent in Louisiana, and 72 percent in Mississippi.

Conclusion

As a number of states reinstate lockdowns due to the recent surge in coronavirus cases and COVID-19 deaths, the prospect of a quick economic recovery is becoming increasingly unlikely. Concerns about work disincentives fail to recognize that job displacements have consequences beyond the loss of wages. Most workers find inherent value in their work and care about benefits, career advancement opportunities, and their long-term economic security.

If Congress lets the Pandemic Unemployment Compensation program expire, then those who have already been hardest hit by the downturn—Black workers, Latinx workers, women workers, and low-wage workers—will be most affected, making the current crisis longer and more severe.

Child care is essential for working parents, but is the industry ready and safe to reopen?

By now, it is no secret that parents across the United States are struggling. Adapting to life during the coronavirus pandemic has been difficult for nearly everyone, but parents—particularly those with young children—are facing day-in, day-out work-life conflicts with no end in sight. Whether they are continuing to work from home, unemployed, or still working outside the house, providing for their children without the support of schools, daycare, camps, or even help from grandparents is taking an emotional and economic toll. Rarely has the role of child care in supporting our economy, by freeing up parents’ time and minds to focus on work, been more self-evident.

For weeks, experts and parents alike have been warning that child care will be essential in any economic recovery from the coronavirus recession. Without it, many parents, particularly women, will have to weigh dropping out of the labor force or reducing their work hours if their caregiving responsibilities remain incompatible with their work responsibilities. Still, plans to reopen schools and child care facilities remain scattershot, largely driven by uncertainty about how coronavirus infections spread in such environments, how children may contract or spread the virus to adult staff, and how susceptible children themselves are to COVID-19, the disease spread by the coronavirus.

How to provide child care safely is primarily a question for scientists and public health experts, but policymakers and social science researchers have their own role to play in this ongoing crisis. First, the coronavirus pandemic must be treated as the workplace safety issue that it is. This involves developing a national set of safety standards—along with the appropriate education, training, and funding to enact those standards—so that parents and staff can be confident that their care is as safe as it can be. Without such standards, each facility will have to fend for itself with limited knowledge and potentially disastrous consequences.

Also important are policies designed to make child care accessible and affordable even in the midst of a pandemic. Recent research suggests that the child care market will be unprepared to provide care in a post-pandemic environment without significant public investment. If parents are shifting their preferences as a result of the pandemic and ensuing economic crisis—either by desiring smaller providers or working more nonstandard hours—then the policy challenges of providing high-quality and affordable care will only grow.

More research on what child care services families need and what the child care industry is poised to provide will help target the policy response supporting families as they return to work and fuel the economic recovery.

Child care priorities prior to the coronavirus pandemic limit our post-pandemic options

The United States does not have a universal child care system, so many families rely on a patchwork of polices, including tax credits, licensing standards, and subsidy programs, to access high-quality child care. These policies help some families afford much-needed care, but they are largely insufficient in meeting the variety of care options that families need. What’s more, these policies underpin a child care system that lacks the flexibility necessary to meet the shifting needs of families in response to the current pandemic. 

As the coronavirus and COVID-19 continue to spread through communities, larger child care centers, where dozens of children are together in one building, may be more prone to spreading both the virus and the disease. Already, some communities are reporting alarming transmission of COVID-19 in child care centers, though some studies suggest the disease is less likely to spread among children.

While wealthy families can hire nannies or babysitters to limit exposure, middle- and lower-incomes parents may be driven to seek in-home care. This type of care, also called home-based care, typically occurs in the provider’s home, where only a handful of children are present. It may be reasonable to assume these less-crowded settings are a safer alternative for families concerned about the safety of their kids and themselves. But the number of licensed in-home providers has rapidly declined over the past two decades. (See Figure 1.)

Figure 1

The number of licensed child care providers in the United States, by type, 2005–2017

As some of these in-home providers exit the market, others may be transitioning to an “underground” market of unlicensed providers. These providers, which may be legally unlicensed depending on state statute, do not necessarily provide lower-quality care. But regulators cannot oversee the quality of care in these settings to the same extent that they can with those that are licensed. Parents who prefer in-home care over child care centers may be left with a difficult trade-off between accessibility of care and their confidence in a provider’s quality. Unfortunately, even parents who find an acceptable in-home provider could lose out on the subsidies that made their previous care arrangements affordable.

Child care can be incredibly expensive, even exceeding the cost of college in some states. Many families rely on some combination of tax credits or subsidies to help cover the cost. The Child Care Development Fund is the primary child care subsidy program for low-income families in the United States. When the program was reauthorized in 2014, it included important health and safety requirements for eligible child care providers but did not guarantee sufficient additional funds for states to enact these requirements. Experts say this has inadvertently advantaged child care centers, where states are better positioned to provide oversight and training. 

Centers care for about 40 percent of preschoolers with a regular, nonrelative child care arrangement but serve more than 70 percent to 78 percent of similarly aged children receiving Child Care Development Fund subsidies. Conversely, in-home care serves 34 percent of similar preschoolers but around 18 percent to 25 percent of those receiving subsidies. This disparity in funding has dramatically widened in the previous decade. (See Figure 2.)

Figure 2

The percentage of U.S. children receiving Child Care Development Block Grant subsidies, by provider type, 2000–2018

Reshifting subsidies toward these in-home providers is not a simple task. States will need to devote significant resources supporting in-home providers, particularly those that are exempt from licensing, to meet quality standards. Experts already worry that quality standards are too geared toward center-based providers and do not reflect the relative strengths and opportunities of in-home care. This could present an opportunity for high-level rethinking of what defines “quality” for these settings—a task for researchers as much as it is for regulators and policymakers.

Information on the spread of the coronavirus and COVID-19 and their effects on the economy changes rapidly. In the coming months, many families will be continuously reassessing their child care needs and what levels of risk are acceptable. The child care system, and the policies that help make it accessible to more families, must be flexible enough to meet parents’ needs without sacrificing quality or affordability. Unfortunately, these may be longer-term fixes in a system facing immediate shortfalls.

The supply of child care amid the pandemic is down, but parents are still searching for the care they need

These challenges in the U.S. child care market are longstanding, but they are now exacerbated by the coronavirus pandemic and COVID-19. More research is needed to understand how larger structural changes—such as additional subsidies or adjusted licensing standards—can be accomplished. In the meantime, the child care industry also faces an immediate critical shortage of providers who can care for the nation’s children once parents return to work.

Like many industries, the coronavirus pandemic and resulting public health measures were shocks to the child care market. An April poll by the Bipartisan Policy Center found 60 percent of licensed providers shut their doors amid lockdowns and stay-at-home orders. More than 330,000 jobs were lost in the child care sector in only a few short weeks. (See Figure 3.)

Figure 3

All child day care employees, in thousands, June 2019–June 2020

The U.S. child care system was already in a pre-existing financial crisis, and the fallout from the pandemic could mean millions of child care slots are permanently lost. Affordable and accessible child care will be the foundation of any economic recovery, but right now, that foundation has multiples fractures.

In addition to layoffs, the industry dramatically slowed hiring in recent months. A new working paper by Umair Ali, Chris Herbst, and Christos Makridis, economists at Arizona State University, titled “The Impact of COVID-19 on the U.S. Child Care Market: Evidence from Stay-at-Home Orders,” finds that new online postings for early child care and education jobs declined 13 percent per dayfollowing the adoption of states’ stay-at-home orders, resulting in approximately 1,000 fewer providers hired per month than if the pandemic had not occurred. Assuming that these postings were to replace providers who exited the field and not providers who may be postponing a retirement or resignation during the pandemic, 1,000 fewer providers could mean as much as 10,000 fewer child care slots each month.

Even as the industry has been rattled by the coronavirus pandemic and recession, there is evidence that families remain interested in—or at least curious about—their child care options. The same working paper by the three researchers finds no statistically significant decline in Google searches for child care-related terms following state lockdowns. Of course, parents searching for online information on child care does not mean that they currently want or need those services. Many parents—63 percent in one survey—are skeptical about sending their children to child care while the coronavirus and COVID-19 are still spreading.

But just because many parents are not sending their children to child care now doesn’t mean they will not want to—or need to—soon. Even larger child care centers could face a critical capacity issue as parents return to work. Child care operates with low child-to-caregiver ratios, which means providers may need to hire quickly in order to ensure appropriate staffing for returning children. Encouragingly, child care job postings have rebounded by 23.4 percentage points since their lowest point in May, but they remain more than 39 percent below the postings in July 2019. And these recent gains may be tenuous as states resume partial shutdowns through the summer.

Sooner or later, many parents will have to make difficult decisions on when their children are going back into child care and what type of child care is best for their family. Without significant public investment—more than $9 billion a month, according to some estimates—the industry will be unable to provide the care necessary to help families get back to work.

Conclusion

The struggle facing parents today is not one they face alone—it boasts important implications for everyone affected by the coronavirus recession. Research shows that when child care is not accessible or affordable, it can prevent parents, particularly mothers, from entering the workforce. Policymakers and economists are already seeing signs that the lack of child care is creating a drag on women’s employment during the current crisis. Fewer working parents means a smaller tax base, reduced household income, and less money spent on goods and services—all the tools needed to help the economy recover.

As states decide whether to continue to ease their coronavirus restrictions or return to earlier lockdown levels, and as families decide whether to take cautious steps toward resuming their pre-pandemic lives, the demand for child care is only going to rise, particularly as schools and summer camps remain closed and public health experts caution against grandparent care. Policymakers need to take bold action to ensure that child care is accessible and affordable, and high-quality research must help target the policy response.

Most immediately, the industry needs an injection of cash to keep the doors open and caregivers on the payrolls. Many child care advocates have requested $50 billion in flexible funding in the next congressional coronavirus relief aid package. Looking further out, policymakers and researchers will need to turn their attention to the structural challenges discussed above that could limit parents’ options as they seek safe and affordable child care for their children. Otherwise, child care could remain out of reach for many families returning to work, and the economic recovery will stall before it even begins.

Did the Paycheck Protection Program work for small businesses across the United States?

A waiter disinfects tables at an outdoor café during the coronavirus pandemic.

Overview

Across the United States over the past few weeks, we’ve all seen advertisements, received emails, or heard from friends about small businesses trying to inch back to some semblance of  pre-pandemic normal. Hair salons reopening. Gyms welcoming people back into their facilities. Restaurants shifting from take-out only to dining outside and even inside. Specialist retail shops reopening their doors for walk-in customers. Daycare centers beginning to test whether parents will re-enroll their kids.

Now, governors and mayors across the country are giving businesses large and small the green light to invite back their customers. But these openings remain fragile, at best, or are even slipping out of reach in some places as the community spread of the coronavirus hammers Michigan bars, Texas daycare centers, and Florida restaurants. Premature reopenings, without adequate public health controls, may well put the U.S. economy right back to where it was months ago.

The minutes from the Federal Reserve Board’s closed-door interest-rate-setting meeting in mid-June showed the very real possibility of a much worse recession later this year if coronavirus cases continue to spike and the death rate begins to rise. A third of small business owners don’t expect their businesses to be back to normal for more than 6 months, according to a recent survey by the U.S. Census Bureau—and that survey was completed before it became clear that the coronavirus was never truly contained.

Against that backdrop, Congress this month extended the deadline for small businesses to apply for Paycheck Protection Program loans—loans authorized by Congress under the Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security, or CARES, Act that allow firms with fewer than 500 employees to keep workers on payroll and pay for certain other expenses necessary to stay open. In total, Congress authorized $670 billion for the program—an amount larger than any other previous small business investment. Of the money provided by Congress since April, about $130 billion remains unused, with lawmakers debating changes to the program’s loan terms, eligible uses, and whether to create set-asides for the smallest of small businesses, as well as broader changes such as restructuring the program to work better alongside Unemployment Insurance.

As policymakers consider how to keep the U.S. economy stable while efforts to control the public health crisis continue, it is useful to evaluate the early research on the efficacy of the Paycheck Protection Program—most notably, whether the money went to the hardest-hit areas, encouraged firms to keep employees on payroll, and kept small businesses from going bankrupt. It is unlikely that any businesses—and particularly, small businesses—will be able to return to normal anytime soon, and the early evidence suggests that the Paycheck Protection Program is struggling to meet its intended goals. Examining what we know about the program can provide a roadmap on how to deploy aid to American small businesses moving forward. Here’s what the early research says:

  • The Paycheck Protection Program did not generally go to small businesses in the areas hit hardest by the pandemic in terms of coronavirus infection rates and COVID-19 deaths, social distancing measures imposed, or declines in employment.
  • For those businesses that received Paycheck Protection Program loans, the funding did not have a statistically significant impact on preventing avoidable layoffs among employees.
  • Financial institution composition had a large effect on how many loans an area received.
  • There exist significant gaps in our understanding of how Paycheck Protection Program funding served Black- and Latinx-owned small businesses.

In short, it appears that the Paycheck Protection Program was a successful liquidity backstop for firms that may have needed marginal help meeting payroll during the worst of the mandatory lockdowns, but it did not prevent layoffs.

This issue brief details these findings and then examines how different courses of action by Congress may have better met the intended goals of the program, including providing funding directly to businesses to cover revenue declines amid the coronavirus recession and removing the mediating role of private-sector financial institutions. The issue brief then concludes with program changes for Congress and the Small Business Adminisration to consider moving forward as the last tranche of PPP funding is deployed, including creating incentives for short-term compensation arrangements (otherwise known as work-sharing), dedicating set-asides for certain subsets of locations or borrowers, and using available data to monitor effects by race and ethnicity.

Was the Paycheck Protection Program effective?

The goal of the Paycheck Protection Program was to keep the employees of small businesses attached to their workplaces at pre-pandemic wages and to prevent firm bankruptcies during the pandemic by providing government support. Small businesses were invited to apply to lending institutions for loans, fully backed by the Small Business Administration, that would convert to grants if certain conditions were met. After some amendments were made to the original program design, the Paycheck Protection Program now requires businesses to devote at least 60 percent of any loan amounts to payroll costs in order for loans to be forgiven and converted into grants. These loans can be forgiven on a prorated basis if payroll spending amounts dip below 60 percent. If the loans are not forgiven, they carry a 1 percent interest rate and must be paid back within 5 years. The remainder of any business’s PPP funding can go toward paying the mortgage or rent, or certain other expenses.

There are a number of ways to measure whether the original goals of the program were met, among them:

  • Geographic targeting
  • Effects on employment
  • Effects of intermediation by financial institutions
  • Racial equity

Early research provides us some evidence in each of these arenas.

Geographic targeting

A primary question to ask in any research on the efficacy of PPP loans is: Did the funding go to the areas hit hardest by the pandemic, and therefore the areas most likely to experience small business closures?

Research suggests that was not the case. Researchers João Granja, Constantine Yannelis, and Eric Zwick of the University of Chicago Booth School of Business and Christos Makridis of the MIT Sloan School of Management find in their working paper titled “Did the Paycheck Protection Program Hit the Target” that firms were more likely to receive a PPP loan if they were located in areas with better employment outcomes, fewer coronavirus infections and COVID-19 deaths, and less social distancing. Specifically, their research finds that 15 percent of establishments in the regions most affected by declines in hours worked and business shutdowns received PPP funding. In contrast, 30 percent of all establishments received PPP funding in the least-affected regions.

Other research supports this finding. Analysis by Haoyang Liu and Desi Volker of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York titled “Where Have the Paycheck Protection Loans Gone So Far?” shows a negative relationship between coronavirus cases and COVID-19 deaths per capita in a state and the share of eligible small firms receiving PPP loans, meaning that the more cases in a community, the fewer the eligible firms that received aid. Less than 20 percent of small businesses in New York City, for example, received PPP loans, compared to more than half of firms in Nebraska. This disparity is stark, considering that New York City saw a death rate from COVID-19 approximately 20 times the rate of Nebraska. 1

Moreover, New York City began its lockdown of all but essential businesses on March 22 while Nebraska never issued a mandatory stay-at-home order and many nonessential businesses remained open during the pandemic. Liu and Volker’s research also finds no statistically significant relationship between economic hardship, as measured in unemployment claims in the state, and what proportion of the state’s small business workforce was employed at a firm that received a PPP loan.

Why is this the case? Both research studies point to the role of financial institutions, discussed more fully below, in mediating which firms did and did not receive aid.

Effects on employment

Now that we know where small business funding went, the next question is: Did it have the intended effect of preventing avoidable layoffs for the firms that did receive aid? Recent research published by the Opportunity Insights team, led by former Equitable Growth Steering Committee member and Harvard University economist Raj Chetty, suggests that the Paycheck Protection Program had little bearing on whether a business remained viable or kept their workers on payroll. Using the SBA definition of an eligible firm (generally 500 or fewer employees) and data from payroll firms, Chetty and his colleagues find that PPP-eligible businesses were no more likely to maintain workers on payroll than non-PPP-eligible businesses.

Why is that the case? The researchers suggest that funding went to firms that were most likely to keep their workers on payroll to begin with, mostly businesses that don’t need to meet face-to-face with customers, including small businesses in the professional, scientific, and technical services industry. The researchers point to SBA data, noting:

Firms in the Professional, Scientific, and Technical Services industry received a greater share of the PPP loans than Accommodation and Food Services. Yet Accommodation and Food Services accounted for half of the total decline in employment between February and March (prior to PPP enactment) in BLS statistics, while employment in Professional, Scientific, and Technical Services accounted for less than 5 percent of the decline.

In other words, the Paycheck Protection Program served as a liquidity backstop for firms that may have needed a marginal boost to keep workers on the payroll but did not contribute to employers’ threshold decisions in terms of whether to keep workers.2

Liu and Volker’s research corroborates this, but only in part. While their analysis finds a correlation between an industry being affected by coronavirus cases and COVID-19 deaths and that industry’s receipt of a PPP loan, they did not find that loan amounts were proportional to the industry’s employment decline. They also find instances of significant exceptions to this rule, with the construction industry, for example, receiving a large amount of loans despite the sector being deemed “essential” and staying open in many states.

Effects of intermediation by financial institutions

Paycheck Protection Program funding did not go to the geographic areas and business sectors hit hardest by the pandemic and the ensuing recession. What explains the disparities in which areas received funding? Evidence suggests that the size and types of financial institutions had a large role in determining which small businesses received aid, with firms in areas with the highest shares of big banks less likely to receive funding.

Congress directed the Small Business Administration to implement the Paycheck Protection Program by authorizing banks, credit unions, community development financial institutions, and certain financial technology firms to accept applications from small businesses, complete initial underwriting per the terms of the program, and send applications along to the agency for funding. In exchange for their participation, financial institutions received more than $18 billion in fee income, calculated on a percentage basis as a proportion of the total loan amount.3

Because the demand for PPP loans exceeded the supply and financial institutions were left with discretion on how to prioritize applications, lenders had a large role in deciding which applications were accepted, reviewed, and funded. Particularly for the first round of PPP funding, the program became fully subscribed quickly, running out in just 2 weeks, so lending institutions’ prioritization of applications had a material impact on who received funding.

The evidence in the available research suggests that big banks had less interest in the Paycheck Protection Program than their smaller counterparts, meaning areas with high concentration of smaller institutions performed better than others. Liu and Volker, in their analysis “Where Have the Paycheck Protection Loans Gone So Far?,” find a strong relationship between the market share of mid-sized and community banks in a state and the share of small businesses within a state that received a PPP loan.4 This is corroborated by analysis from the Institute for Local Self-Reliance, which also finds that states where community banks had a larger market share had a higher distribution of PPP loans per capita.5 

Granja and his co-authors, in their study “Did the Paycheck Protection Program Hit the Target?,” came to similar conclusions, noting that areas predominately served by the largest banks—JPMorgan Chase & Co., Wells Fargo & Co., Citigroup Inc., and Bank of America Corp.—underperformed in the provision of PPP loans, given those banks’ market share of typical small business lending. Indeed, while these four large banks originated 36 percent of all small business loans before the pandemic, they originated just 3 percent of PPP loans.

These conclusions intuitively make sense, considering that rural areas, which received an outsized share of PPP loans, are more likely to be served by community financial institutions and less likely to be served by big banks. That said, Granja and his co-authors did find areas served by larger mid-sized banks typically had more PPP loan penetration than areas served strictly by the smallest banks. This suggests there were some advantages in economies of scale and nimbleness in responding to new program terms, up to a point.

Neither Liu and Volker nor Granja and his co-authors offer hypotheses on why the largest banks underperformed in PPP lending. That said, some rough data and anecdotal evidence provide some potential explanations for why smaller institutions generally did a better job than the largest U.S. lending institutions in deploying small business funding. SBA data show that the average PPP loan size for banks with more than $50 billion in assets was nearly $120,000, while the average loan size for banks with less than $1 billion in assets was around $85,000, and the average loan size for community development financial institutions—some of the very smallest financial institutions—was around $51,000. This suggests that perhaps large banks prioritized making fewer, bigger loans due to the fee income structure of the program and the more complex bureaucracies at the institutions.

Additionally, past research from the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, the nation’s supervisor of most small U.S. banks, notes that community banks “are said to be relationship lenders, which rely to a significant degree on specialized knowledge gained through long-term business relationships. They are likely to be owned privately or have public shares that are not widely traded, and therefore tend to place the long-term interest of their local communities high relative to the demands of the capital markets.” In the case of the Paycheck Protection Program, the relationship lending model may have meant that community banks had better pre-existing relationships with local small businesses and a greater focus on lending rather than, say, investment banking or trading.

Finally, other reporting by Barron’s suggests that community banks saw the Paycheck Protection Program as an opportunity to build new lending relationships. This opportunity was perhaps overlooked by larger financial institutions with more customers and more lines of business.

Whatever the explanation, it is clear that the composition of lending institutions in an area had a significant impact on mediating aid to eligible businesses, providing policymakers with considerations for how to structure rules around remaining payouts and suggesting that future programs may want to consider distributing aid in more geographically neutral ways.

Racial equity

It is also crucial to understand whether the Paycheck Protection Program is reaching small businesses owned by people of color, particularly Black and Latinx small business owners who have historically faced lending discrimination and other barriers to entrepreneurship. Encouraging small business formation and survival for Black and Latinx entrepreneurs is a worthy goal for public policy. Research evidence from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis shows that for Black Americans who achieve small business ownership, Black entrepreneurs have both higher levels of wealth and higher levels of wealth mobility than Black workers.

The same study also found that Black entrepreneurs have levels of wealth mobility equal to those of White entrepreneurs, while White workers have greater wealth mobility than Black workers. History also demonstrates that Black-owned small businesses help cultivate a vibrant civil society. Black-owned businesses were crucial in financing the civil rights movement of the 1960s, for example, by providing goods and services to people otherwise locked out of White-owned businesses and supporting the autonomy of Black activists, who as employees or customers would not be punished for exercising their right to protest.

How did Black and Latinx small businesses fare under the Paycheck Protection Program? Because policymakers chose not to track PPP funds by race or ethnicity, it is hard to know how the money was distributed disaggregated by the race or ethnicity of the business owner. Lenders were not required to collect information on the demographics of borrowers at the time of the loan application or when the loan was funded. Though Congress, in the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010, required that the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau establish a framework for small business application and lending data collection by race, ethnicity, and other protected characteristics, the new agency never finalized that rulemaking.

That said, the Small Business Administration did include a field requiring that small business owners report their gender, race, ethnicity, and veteran status in paperwork required for loan forgiveness, which will be submitted by borrowers when they seek to have the loan extinguished after meeting program requirements. The agency last week committed to publicly providing those data and has released initial data on the program, though without demographic information.6

While this transparency effort is significant, it will still leave some gaps in our understanding. First, the data will not cover those businesses that do not wish to have their loan forgiven, and it also will not include information about loan applications submitted but not approved, meaning it will be impossible to see how many Black and Latinx small businesses had their funding requests rejected.

In the meantime, lacking hard data, we turn to survey evidence to determine whether the Paycheck Protection Program is adequately serving Black and Latinx small business owners. One survey by the advocacy groups Color of Change and UnidosUS, taken between April 30 and May 12, finds that just 12 percent of Black and Latinx small business owners who applied for aid from the Small Business Administration reported receiving the amount they requested, while 26 percent said they had received only a portion of what they had requested. These figures, while distressing on their own, are particularly troubling, given that small businesses owned by Black and Latinx entrepreneurs are more likely to be in industries highly impacted by the coronavirus—meaning they’re more likely to need this bridge funding than other businesses more insulated from the pandemic’s effects.

Policy recommendations

The Paycheck Protection Program, totaling $670 billion in funding, is the largest investment in our nation’s small businesses and has the power to reshape our economy. Early lessons from the rollout of the program suggest some benefits—namely, that the money was nearly fully subscribed and that there was robust interest among eligible small businesses. But it appears that the program’s design impaired the loans from going to the neediest areas and businesses and from preventing avoidable layoffs.

The preliminary evidence strongly suggests that PPP funding was more of a liquidity program for small businesses that needed a boost in payroll funding to get through the early weeks of mandatory lockdowns rather than a social insurance program designed prevent avoidable layoffs. That said, early research findings must be caveated by reports of data errors. The Small Business Administration should work to improve the accuracy of data reporting, particularly as business owners move to have their loans forgiven.

Given the shortcomings of the PPP, if policymakers could rewind the clock, what should Congress have done instead? The Paycheck Protection Program’s tripartite goals—keeping workers’ income steady, keeping workers attached to firms, and helping workers weather mandatory lockdowns—at times may have run at cross-purposes. It is hard to access the efficacy of a counterfactual, but proposals similar to the Danish model, in which small businesses were automatically provided with stopgap funding to cover revenue lost for a certain time, may have proven more successful.

Indeed, Paycheck Protection Program rules requiring that funding go directly to payroll support may have disadvantaged businesses in areas with high rent or mortgage costs, businesses that might take a while to hire back employees (including those operating in areas with longer periods of mandatory lockdowns), or businesses that needed to make substantial investments in social distancing measures before reopening. A blanket promise to cover revenue losses and invest in social distancing, via grants, would have better addressed these issues.

Similarly, policymakers should consider deployment mechanisms in the future that provide aid to small businesses directly rather than via banks, credit unions, and other lenders. Small businesses in certain areas should not be disadvantaged in accessing a government-authorized program simply because of the composition of lending institutions in their area. As discussed in a previous Equitable Growth analysis, options include expanding public banking options and increasing the in-house capacity of the Small Business Administration, which has only around 3,300 employees, with total salaries and expenses of around $447 million. Given the $18 billion spent on administering the Paycheck Protection Program through private lending institutions, an additional investment in agency capacity may be wise in terms of minimizing long-term costs while meeting policy goals related to the equity of rescue funding deployment. After all, emergency SBA funding may be needed again in the future, including but not limited to instances involving natural disasters.

With the available evidence today, what short-term changes could policymakers consider implementing to guide the last tranche of available funding?

One policy option worth considering is the Rebuilding Main Street Act from Sens. Chris Van Hollen (D-MD), Jeff Merkley (D-OR), and Chris Murphy (D-CT). This legislation would rejigger the Paycheck Protection Program to work in tandem with the enhanced Unemployment Insurance benefits under the CARES Act. Specifically, the proposal would provide grants to particularly hard-hit small businesses to cover fixed costs and expenses, provided that the employers use short-term compensation arrangements or a system whereby employers avoid layoffs and instead reduce the hours worked by each employee at the firm. Employees would then continue to receive Unemployment Insurance on a prorated basis to compensate for reduced wages. Short-term compensation arrangements are already in place in 26 states plus Washington, D.C.

These PPP enhancements could allow businesses to cover the fixed costs needed to get started again, including supplies, rent, mortgage, investments in social distancing, and personal protective equipment. And it would enable the firms to slowly ramp up the hours worked by employees as the business gradually recovers. At the same time, it would allow employees to maintain a relationship with their employers and more quickly resume past earnings as the economy recovers.

Research from Marth Gimbel of Schmidt Futures and Jesse Rothstein and Danny Yagan of the University of California, Berkeley looking at CARES Act programs compared to other global responses note that job losses have been lowest in countries that either contained the coronavirus early or had robust systems for subsidizing employment at reduced hours. Their research also points to historical data, noting that many credit Germany’s quicker recovery after the Great Recession to the short-term compensation program.

Beyond the macroeconomic benefits, research from Steven Davis of the University of Chicago and Till Von Wachter of Columbia University suggests that workers who are laid off from a job take a long time to gradually climb back up the job ladder and find a match as good as the one they once had. Reworking the Paycheck Protection Program with  enhanced Unemployment Insurance benefits to better interlock unemployment benefits and PPP lending objectives could help the United States achieve these goals.

Short of a wholesale redesign along the lines of the Rebuilding Main Street Act, policymakers might want to consider program enhancements to correct for the program’s funds not reaching the areas hardest hit by the coronavirus pandemic. Dedicated set-asides by state according to the number of people employed by eligible small businesses, or in certain sectors, may be warranted, if coupled with loosening rules to allow more investments in nonpayroll expenses. Of course, if this route is taken, it is especially imperative for policymakers to extend enhanced Unemployment Insurance benefits to offset any workers losing employment through the Paycheck Protection Program.

Policymakers may also want to consider certain program changes to better serve industries disproportionately left behind by the early rounds of PPP lending, especially the accommodation and food services industry. Economist T. William Lester of the University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill provides some policy recommendations for how to reach small restaurants and bars, for example.

Policymakers also must closely examine data on small business loan forgiveness by race and ethnicity when they become available. If initial survey evidence holds, then firms owned by Black and Latinx entrepreneurs may not have had equal access to PPP lending. At a minimum, the coronavirus pandemic’s impact on small business financing demonstrates that the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau should finalize the required rule on small business data collection so that policymakers and advocates have actionable information moving forward.

Finally, some research suggests that policymakers should prioritize extending social insurance benefits over continuation of the Paycheck Protection Program. Harvard’s Chetty and his co-authors suggest in their recent research that a better approach moving forward would be to invest in income support for individuals, including extending increased Pandemic Unemployment Insurance benefits past the current July 31, 2020 deadline. As the Opportunity Insights team notes, “it may be more fruitful to approach this economic crisis from the lens of providing social insurance to reduce hardship rather than stimulus to increase economic activity. Rather than attempt to put workers back to work in sectors where spending is temporarily depressed because of health concerns, it may be best to focus on mitigating income losses for those who have lost their jobs.”

Conclusion

The still-spreading coronavirus pandemic makes clear that no amount of declaring businesses reopened will create an economic recovery. Research suggests that consumer spending will remain woefully anemic until the public health crisis is under control. The Paycheck Protection Program, as currently designed, is not well-equipped to prevent avoidable small business closures or employee layoffs. Policymakers should consider implementing program improvements, particularly short-term compensation arrangements but also more modest measures, remain committed to income supports until safe jobs are actually available, and reassess the small business landscape once the virus subsides. Even if policymakers change course now, it is clear that significant investments in small businesses, perhaps akin to a domestic Marshall Plan to rebuild these critical engines of employment, entrepreneurship, and economic growth, may be needed to reverse the effects of the coronavirus and its recession.