How the coronavirus pandemic is harming family well-being for U.S. low-wage workers

As the effects of the new coronavirus sweep through the U.S. economy, low-wage workers are hit first and hardest. Today, economist Liz Ananat at Barnard College and psychologist Anna Gassman-Pines at Duke University released new analyses drawing from daily diary surveys conducted in a typical large U.S. city between February 20 and March 24. Each day, they surveyed 690 retail, food, and hospitality workers with young children and they also conducted a one-time survey on the impact of the new coronavirus with a subsample of 405 respondents. Their results show how the public health crisis is unfolding and how policy has not yet softened its economic and psychological blow.

Their findings are presented below in 10 charts that track the experiences of these workers and their families just prior to, and immediately following, the onset of the coronavirus crisis in their city during March 2020. The study was conducted before the most recent stimulus package—which greatly expands Unemployment Insurance—was passed. But the findings imply that if policymakers do not act quickly to facilitate benefit access for low-wage workers, even these newest supports may not reach the people who need them most.

The coronavirus recession’s impact on low-wage workers in a large U.S. city in 10 charts

March was the first month in which the economic shocks from the coronavirus pandemic reverberated to the city under study. During this month, more than two-thirds of the workers surveyed found themselves working less, with more than 40 percent experiencing layoffs. (See Figure 1.)

Figure 1

As work hours dwindled, parents slept poorly. They reported feeling fretful, angry, irritable, anxious, or depressed all day long. Their children increasingly demonstrated uncooperative behavior. (See Figure 2.)

Figure 2

The experience of parents and their children is deeply intertwined. As parents’ moods suffered, they reported that their young sons and daughters demonstrated uncooperative behavior, which, for children, is a harbinger of deeper psychological distress. (See Figure 3.)

Figure 3

Decreases in work hours are accompanied by falls in income. Nearly two-thirds of respondents reported that their income fell following the onset of the coronavirus crisis. One-third reported severe income declines. These workers’ incomes were now less than half of what they had been in normal times. (See Figure 4.)

Figure 4

Policymakers anticipated this economic hardship, and they acted. They made emergency childcare available for people in essential occupations, Unemployment Insurance available to people who were laid off or experienced reductions in hours, provided free meal pick-up for all minor children (many of whom lost access to free or reduced-price meals in schools), and distance learning for school-aged children whose classrooms were shuttered. All low-wage workers with young children were eligible for at least some of these supports. (See Figure 4.)

Figure 5

Yet, despite the initial action taken by policymakers, few families accessed these supports. Only 3 percent of the respondents who continued to work in jobs deemed “essential” received emergency childcare. And only 4 percent of those who were laid-off received unemployment benefits. While all sample members were eligible to pick up free grab-and-go meals at schools, just 1 in 10 received them, and only half of respondents with school-aged children were engaged in distance learning. (See Figure 6.)

Figure 6

Indeed, more than half of these low-wage workers did not receive any of the services for which their families were eligible. (See Figure 7.)

Figure 7

Though the public safety net did not reach low-wage workers and their families in these first weeks of the crisis, those workers who received compensation from their employers for their reduced hours experienced less income volatility than their counterparts who had to rely on the public safety net alone. (See Figure 8.)

Figure 8

Taking stock of these serious financial challenges facing families, the research team asked respondents, “If the crisis continues, for how many months do you think you will be able to pay for groceries?” Of those respondents who were able to provide a guess, nearly 1 in 10 predicted running out of money for groceries during the week of the survey, and half predicted not being able to pay for groceries sometime before the end of May. (See Figure 9.)

Figure 9

Similarly, the low-wage workers who were surveyed predict that if the crisis continues, they’ll be unable to pay for housing. Nearly 1 in 5 predict running out of rent money during the survey week, and three-quarters predict running out sometime before the end of June. (See Figure 10.)

Figure 10

Conclusion

For all kinds of people across the world, the shock of the coronavirus crisis has been devastating. But low-wage workers in the United States were in a fragile place even before the crisis began: Economic inequality left them and their families ill-equipped to cope with a sudden financial or health shock well before the pandemic’s onset.

And the coronavirus crisis is harming more than the pocketbooks of low-income families; it is also affecting the psychological well-being of parents and their children. These psychological effects are likely the result of both economic hardship and anxiety about the coronavirus itself—and perhaps even a reaction to respondents or their family members contracting the virus.

Over the past several weeks, policymakers have recognized that low-income families are suffering and have stepped up to provide supports to these families, but the supports won’t be effective at ameliorating the distress of families—or stabilizing the economy—if workers don’t access them.

The importance of an expanded U.S. Unemployment Insurance system during the coronavirus recession

On March 24, my colleagues Emmanuel Saez and Gabriel Zucman at the University of California, Berkeley, gathered some 100 fellow economists and other experts online to discuss the actions the U.S. Congress and the president need to take now to mitigate the impact of the coronavirus lockdown on people and the economy. This occurred a few days before the enactment of emergency legislation by Congress that was signed by President Donald Trump this past Friday. As one of the presenters at the online conference, my focus was on how best to use the Unemployment Insurance system, a critical part of the solution for laid-off workers and the economy more broadly.

Following is a summary of my comments, with updates due to the swiftly changing policy landscape.

As I reminded the group, fiscal policy—the use of both spending and tax measures—is and will continue to be central to our country’s efforts to minimize the damage from the shutdown of the U.S. economy due to the coronavirus pandemic. Broadly speaking, fiscal policy plays two key roles: providing social insurance to make whole, to the extent possible, those most directly and deeply harmed by the economic downturn, and support for aggregate demand—making sure that people have money to spend to support themselves and spur economic renewal.

In the current lockdown period, the predominant role of fiscal policy is to provide social insurance to workers and fill holes in the balance sheets of employers. Aggregate demand stimulus will primarily be useful when we have eased the current supply constraints. In other words, right now, people’s ability to purchase goods and especially services is constrained by a shortage of things to purchase and opportunities to purchase them. That doesn’t mean we should not provide any support at all for aggregate demand, such as the $1,200 payments that will be going out to most individuals in the coming weeks, but we want to make sure we have in reserve even greater support for aggregate demand when we actually can expand.

My focus, then, is on social insurance. How do we make sure, when we just saw more than 3 million people apply for Unemployment Insurance in one week (nearly five times the previous weekly record when seasonally adjusted), with millions more to follow, that their paychecks don’t fall dramatically? This is important because in the United States right now, due to a number of weaknesses in the federal law and additional restrictions at the state level, only about 25 percent of people who are unemployed actually receive unemployment benefits, and for those receiving benefits, on average, less than 50 percent of their paycheck is replaced. So, these mass layoffs are a huge hit to millions of workers and their families, and we need a way to deal with that.

Moreover, how can we avoid at least some permanent layoffs by making it possible for businesses to instead use a combination of furloughs, temporary layoffs, or other measures, such as work sharing, with the knowledge that their workers will be able to replace much of their wage loss? With such alternatives, the federal government can pick up part of endangered businesses’ payroll costs, helping them to survive, while maintaining long-term links between workers and firms.

To be clear, while I am focusing on unemployment insurance, one size will not fit all. There will be other ways to help businesses, including loans and grants, to help them keep workers on their payroll.

That said, I am focused on unemployment insurance for several reasons. First is the most obvious one: The Unemployment Insurance system is up and running, and we understand how it works. Second, it’s relatively fast. It can get checks out in weeks, not months. Third, it’s highly targeted. It goes to those losing part or all of their jobs, exactly the people who are being hurt the most. Fourth, the Unemployment Insurance system allows multiple options for retaining those employer-employee connections, including temporary layoffs, partial benefits—a reduction of hours with partial unemployment benefits—and, work sharing, in which an employer, instead of laying off, say, 30 percent of workers, reduces all workers’ hours by 30 percent, and the government fills in the rest of their income with these benefits. Finally, the Unemployment Insurance system has a long history in this country, including a history of emergency expansions during economic crises.

Many of the proposals I talked about last week have been incorporated in some form into the legislation that was just signed into law, and some were not. There will be time to address more of these issues now that the first major bill is complete, but this is an important step. .Below I compare elements of my original proposal to what was signed into law last week.

There are four key aspects to my proposal.

  1. Ease eligibility requirements, so that three-fourths, not one-fourth, of the unemployed can collect unemployment benefits. To do this, I recommend getting rid of the requirement that beneficiaries continue to seek work (since virtually no work is available), weakening the previous-earnings test, and making previously ineligible groups, such as self-employed people, eligible for benefits. The CARES Act enacted last week does much of this, via two separate vehicles: the Pandemic Emergency Unemployment Compensation increases benefits for those usually eligible for Unemployment Insurance. Additionally, the Pandemic Unemployment Assistance provides benefits to those who have lost jobs but don’t qualify for Unemployment Insurance benefits, meaning those who are self-employed.
  2. Significantly increase the rate at which wages are replaced by benefits. Currently, it varies by state, going approximately from 33 percent to 55 percent. During this period, it needs to be much higher, at least 85 percent, according to my proposal. Ordinarily, that high a rate could discourage people from seeking new work. But this clearly is not a problem right now. We are paying people to stay home. When we need to get people working again, this rate can decline. Similar to my proposal, the CARES Act also increases benefits, but it does so by providing a flat boost of $600 per week to recipients. I discuss the motivations and implications further below.
  3. We need to make sure the potential benefit duration is well longer than the standard 26 weeks. We need a trigger mechanism that ensures workers are covered beyond 26 weeks while this crisis is ongoing. Consistent with this recommendation, the CARES Act increases the maximum potential benefit duration to 39 weeks for now.
  4. We want to make sure we can maintain the existing matches between workers and employers. So, as noted above, we need to encourage work sharing, temporary rather than permanent layoffs, and partial benefits. All these approaches can help maintain those connections. This includes employers providing health benefits to workers who are on furloughs, such as those working for Macy’s Inc., which announced this move earlier this week. The CARES Act provides incentives to states to adopt and use these short-term compensation measures. But more needs to be done here, especially to prevent perverse incentives for employers to lay off workers or cut hours instead of embracing worksharing practices.
  5. Finally, the federal government needs to step up and fund the additional cost. It’s a comparative advantage to pay for this nationally. Moreover, there is no alternative.

What are the benefit increases for workers under my proposed plan? This will vary with the wage-replacement rate we want to achieve and the maximum absolute weekly benefits allowed under the program. Under the Unemployment Insurance program, states have considerable discretion as to both of these levels, so these figures are based on averages, not on any particular state.

Figure 1 shows the average weekly increase per worker for three levels of maximum benefits—$750, $1,000, and $1,500—and gradually increasing replacement rates. So, as the chart shows, if the program set a wage-replacement rate of 85 percent, with a maximum weekly benefit of $1,500, the average worker would see a weekly benefit of $773. When compared to a 50 percent replacement rate and a maximum cutoff of $750, it translates to a roughly $473 increase in weekly benefit amount.

Figure 1

Here, it should be noted that the legislation enacted by Congress takes a somewhat different approach. To make the program as simple as possible, the new law will provide most beneficiaries with a flat weekly benefit increase of $600. Overall, for workers eligible for unemployment benefits, this will raise their benefits even more than my proposal, which would have raised benefits by a little less than $500. The flat increase also means a particularly high increase in benefits for low-wage earners, many of whom may see their unemployment benefits exceeding their paychecks. In contrast, higher-wage earners would fare better with an increase geared to their previous wage. But I should note that for workers not traditionally eligible for Unemployment Insurance—the self-employed—the benefit amounts provided by the Pandemic Unemployment Assistance are lower, at one-half the state average benefit plus $600.

I also made a fairly crude estimate of the potential cost of the kind of program I proposed. Figure 2 provides one example. It shows the cost if the proposal resulted in 75 percent of unemployed workers, rather than the current 25 percent, receiving benefits, with the maximum weekly benefit set at $1,500 and the wage-replacement rate set at 75 percent.

Figure 2

As Figure 2 shows, at an unemployment rate of 20 percent (an entirely realistic figure, unfortunately), the approximate cost over six months would be $366 billion. The estimated cost of the Unemployment Insurance measures passed by Congress is roughly $260 billion, a difference that could be explained by fewer formerly ineligible people being brought into the system, among other differences and assumptions. Interestingly, this is about the cost the Unemployment Insurance component of the CARES Act was estimated to be by numerous analysts, including the Joint Committee on Taxation.

To summarize, Unemployment Insurance is a useful, fast, and effective way of providing social insurance to a sizable set of workers. At the same time, this is only part of the solution, especially for those in the upper half of the wage distribution. Providing additional mechanisms to keep workers on payrolls is important, but this gives an immediate boost to exactly those who need it, and it allows plenty of room to adjust the program in subsequent legislation, as well as address aggregate demand issues down the road, when those who now are losing all or part of their wages are able to come back to work.

The long-term consequences of recessions for U.S. workers

Policymakers have asked—in some cases, demanded—that people stay home and businesses shutter as a public health crisis has unfolded across the United States, inducing an economic downturn. Despite positive developments in legislation passed last week, those policymakers have not put in place all the steps needed to protect workers and businesses from a full-scale recession that may cast a shadow for years to come. Given the likely scope and scale of this crisis and the current public policy response—which, from both a public health and economic perspective, has been insufficient—it is looking increasingly likely that the United States may be on the cusp of a severe economic recession.

What does the evidence from the Great Recession of 2007–2009 say about what an extended recession could mean for working people over the long term, especially young workers?

There is extensive research on the effects that economic downturns have on workers’ employment and earnings, not just during a recession but also lingering for years and decades afterward. In a new working paper, University of California, Berkeley economist Jesse Rothstein finds that workers who happen to be entering the labor market when there’s a recession have both permanently lower employment rates and lower earnings long after the recession has ended. These effects for recent entrants are even worse than for other members of the U.S. labor force who have been in it longer, as Rothstein explains in a column about the paper:

Workers from these cohorts saw their annual employment rates drop by 2 percentage points to 4 percentage points per year, relative to older workers in the same labor market. Those who were established in the workforce by the beginning of the recession—those who graduated college in 2005 and earlier—essentially returned to prerecession levels of employment by 2014. But those who entered after 2005 have not; their employment rates remain depressed even as the overall market has recovered.

Unfortunately, these effects are not temporary. Rothstein estimates that the permanent effects, or scarring, of the Great Recession on young workers will result in those individuals earning 2 percent less through the early years of their careers and will reduce their employment throughout the course of their career by about one week. While these amounts might sound small for one individual, aggregated across an entire generation, they represent a large loss of earnings and employment.

Another new working paper that explores the negative effects the Great Recession had on young workers in particular is by U.S. Census Bureau economist Kevin Rinz. He finds that from 2007 to 2017, millennials whose local labor markets had higher unemployment lost 13 percent in cumulative earnings, compared to 9 percent for Generation X and 7 percent for the baby-boom generation. (See Figure 1.)

Figure 1

These worse earnings outcomes relative to older workers persisted even as these millennials were more likely to be employed again by 2017. Rinz then discusses a few different reasons why younger workers’ earnings would still be depressed even as their employment improves.

One of those ways is that younger workers, especially millennials, were still less likely to be working for high-paying employers even as their employment recovered. Meanwhile, older workers saw their chances of working for high-paying employers improve roughly proportionately to their likelihood of being employed. (See Figure 2.)

Figure 2

You can read more about Rinz’s paper in this column by Equitable Growth Director of Labor Market Policy Kate Bahn.

One of the reasons it’s so concerning to see that recessions have such negative consequences for young workers is because where you start out in the earnings distribution has important implications for your long-term earnings trajectory—even if you don’t have the bad luck to be entering the labor market during a recession. Research funded by Equitable Growth by Syracuse University economist Emily Wiemers and University of Massachusetts Boston economist Michael Carr found that people are less likely to move up the earnings distribution over the course of their career than they used to. They find that the likelihood of a worker who starts their career in the middle of the earnings distribution moving to the top decile of the earnings distribution has declined approximately 20 percent over the past 40 years.

This means people are more “stuck in place” in the earnings distribution throughout the course of their careers, with less chance of earning more as they grow older and more experienced. This also means that where one starts on the earnings ladder is more indicative of where you will finish in the earnings ladder than used to be true. This is true even for college-educated workers, who may have higher earnings overall but have actually seen their lifetime earnings mobility decline the most.

The combination of these cyclical factors caused by recessions and structural factors driven by long-term changes in earnings mobility have profound implications for the long-term economic opportunity that young workers face. As my co-author Elisabeth Jacobs and I explain in our report, “Are today’s inequalities limiting tomorrow’s opportunities?,” these changes together represent one way in which even highly skilled and highly “human capitalized” workers face lower prospects of economic mobility relative to prior generations.

This means that while much of our political and policy rhetoric continues to emphasize the role of individual skills, education, and hard work to explain economic outcomes, the reality is that far too often, economic outcomes reflect factors beyond an individual’s control, from racial and gender discrimination to the dumb luck of happening to be a young adult entering the labor market during a recession.

Research from the Great Recession indicates that the 2007–2009 downturn had deep and long-lasting negative economic impacts on people. The current downturn caused by our coronavirus-driven economic shutdown has already had dire impacts on workers, seen last week in the unprecedented jump in Unemployment Insurance claim filings. But as we have seen from the research above, recessions’ negative economic effects also linger for years afterward in depressed earnings and employment, and this current downturn may linger even longer due to underlying fragilities in the U.S. economy caused by historically high economic inequality and a porous social safety net.

That’s why it’s crucial that policymakers take swift and decisive action to ensure not only that income keeps flowing in the short term but also that permanent, inequality-fighting policy changes are enacted to improve the country’s safety net and enhance automatic fiscal stabilizers in the long term. The legislation enacted last week is a good down payment on that goal, but further interventions may be needed as our economy continues to suffer from the consequences of the coronavirus.

Getting money urgently to low-wage U.S. workers

To cushion the blow of the COVID-19 pandemic, the U.S. Congress last week passed and President Donald Trump signed the $2.2 trillion emergency stimulus package, including provisions to send checks of up to $1,200 to each tax-paying citizen and hundreds of billions of dollars more to small businesses to cushion the blow for their laid-off employees. The flow of this emergency relief from the federal government should prioritize low-wage earners, who are at significant health, economic, and financial risk due to the coronavirus and the looming recession. Mobile payments, using electronic transfers and mobile applications, could get money into their hands quickly.

A record number of people are losing jobs. In Michigan, Monday through Thursday last week, 80,000 people, many of whom are low-wage workers, filed Unemployment Insurance claims—a number which exceeds the 60,000 filings at the peak of unemployment following the Great Recession of 2007–2009. Across the United States, nearly 3.3 million people filed for Unemployment Insurance this past week, with expectations of millions more doing so in April.

Low-wage workers, who account for 44 percent of all U.S. workers (roughly 53 million people), are their families’ primary wage earners. These breadwinners are disproportionately women and minorities who live paycheck to paycheck and are therefore most at risk. With no income, these workers are unable to pay bills—rent, mobile phone, health insurance, car and student loans, and mortgages. Consumer spending drives more than two-thirds of Gross Domestic Product. Every bill they cannot pay (to a landlord, a mortgage lender, or a car company) and every business they cannot patronize (their mechanic, favorite restaurant, or neighborhood clothing store) starts a chain reaction that will only deepen this coronavirus recession.

Too little of this federal emergency relief money may well get into these consumers’ hands too late. Most people and small businesses have bills due at the end of the month. They need cash immediately. Direct payments will eventually reach most small businesses and families, but getting these funds to them could take several weeks or perhaps much longer. The most vulnerable who do not file taxes and do not receive benefits, such as Social Security, will be the hardest to reach.

Mobile money could be the answer. The federal government should learn from the decades-long experience with mobile money in developing countries and more recently in the United States. Mobile phone networks sent all Americans with a cell phone an emergency text alert this past October. They could get them money today, especially the most vulnerable.

Mobile payments use electronic transfers and mobile applications. In the United States, mobile payments connect to banks and other financial institutions. Ninety-six percent of American adults have cell phones, and 81 percent have a smartphone that could receive and make mobile payments. Thirty percent of smartphone users made mobile payments in 2019, and this amount was projected to grow before the COVID-19 pandemic. Mobile payments are faster than traditional payments and offer a good way to send money to the 16 percent of Americans who are underbanked.

Smartphone penetration is high among workers most likely to be missed by traditional payment mechanisms—people who have changed addresses and low-wage earners. Ninety-eight percent of adults ages 18 to 29 have smartphones, compared to 81 percent of adults overall. Nearly three-quarters of those earning less than $30,000 have smartphones. The share of African Americans (80 percent) and Hispanics (79 percent) who own smartphones is comparable to the total, but there are larger shares of blacks (23 percent) and Hispanics (25 percents) who use smartphones rather than broadband at home compared to whites (12 percent), according to the Pew Research Center.

Mobile payments preserve the value of the per-person amount distributed by the government by limiting high fees associated with using bank alternatives. With mobile payments, the recipient can choose a platform, such as Zelle and Paypal/Venmo, to connect to a bank. Most services have caps on daily transfers ($2,000 for Zelle and $10,000 for PayPal) and other security features to prevent fraud.

For all Americans, and especially the underbanked, the federal government’s forthcoming stimulus payments should be made available by allowing people to decide which credit union, community bank, or commercial bank to use with a guarantee of no or minimal fees for the recipient. Financial institutions should be reimbursed a small flat rate for these transactions. The U.S. Treasury Department should then use community banks, credit unions, and commercial banks affiliated with mobile payment platforms to facilitate not only the distribution of this emergency relief cash but onward mobile payments to landlords, mortgage servicers, and other creditors. Zelle, for example, is affiliated with 766 such financial institutions across the country.

This possibly very sharp but short economic downturn or an even longer recession is happening at an unparalleled pace. Mobile payments can get cash out fast, particularly to the most vulnerable.

—Lisa D. Cook is a professor of economics at Michigan State University. She was a senior economist at the White House Council of Economic Advisers and led the Harvard University team advising Rwanda on its first post-genocide IMF program.

Weekend reading: Supporting and protecting workers during the coronavirus recession edition

This is a post we publish each Friday with links to articles that touch on economic inequality and growth. The first section is a round-up of what Equitable Growth published this week and the second is relevant and interesting articles we’re highlighting from elsewhere. We won’t be the first to share these articles, but we hope by taking a look back at the whole week, we can put them in context.

Equitable Growth round-up

The importance of paid family, medical, and caregiving leave for all U.S. workers throughout the coronavirus pandemic and looming recession cannot be understated. These policies are not just benefits, but also necessities—and are especially needed during this public health and economic crisis. In an issue brief covering the different types of state-level paid time away from work, Jack Smalligan, Chantel Boyens, and Alix Gould-Werth explain the differences between paid sick days, paid medical leave, and paid caregiving leave and why each is important from both an economic and health perspective at this critical moment. In conjunction with the issue brief, Equitable Growth produced factsheets covering benefits for workers and the economy of paid medical and paid caregiving leave, as well as a factsheet on the research about the policy design of these programs.

In addition to these badly needed worker-protection policies, there are many other ways policymakers can confront the coronavirus recession that is either about to hit or already hitting the U.S. economy. Heather Boushey and Somin Park outline the various ways that lawmakers can keep income flowing and pause the expenses of individuals and businesses in the United States, ensuring that once the health crisis passes, people and companies will be ready to get back to work. Boushey and Park’s proposals include providing paid leave, boosting Unemployment Insurance and the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program, helping small businesses pay their bills, ensuring that corporate assistance puts workers first, distributing direct cash payments to Americans, and increasing support to states for Medicaid and the Children’s Health Insurance Program. These and other ideas would protect and support workers and their families in desperate need of assistance.

Another suggestion to prevent a long-term recession as a result of the coronavirus outbreak is to make the U.S. government the payor of last resort. This idea, put forward by Emmanuel Saez and Gabriel Zucman during an online conference this week, would essentially have the government pay wages and essential business maintenance costs in order to prevent locked-down businesses from going bankrupt and to allow idle workers to continue to be paid instead of being laid off. The amounts given to businesses do not need to be exact and would be verified and corrected once the lockdowns have ended, allowing businesses to “hibernate without bleeding cash.” The program would also be limited in duration, likely to three months. While this would obviously not fully offset the economic costs of a coronavirus recession, it would lay the foundation for a quick rebound once the public health threat is contained.

With the likely passage this week of a $2.2 trillion stimulus package, Congress has fought back—and, thus far, fought back hard—against the immediate effects of the coronavirus health and economic crisis, writes Claudia Sahm. One of the most commonly discussed elements of the new stimulus package is the direct cash payments that will go to Americans, called recovery rebates in the legislation. These rebates will cost more than $250 billion, or 2 percent of consumer spending in 2019, and will go to 8 in 10 people in the United States. Sahm XX covers XX what, exactly, we know about the rebates, why they are a sound policy idea—and unfortunately, why they will probably not be enough to truly stave off a deep and severe recession.

The federal government’s slow response at the start of the outbreak was a costly misstep, but President Donald Trump can correct this wrong by appointing so-called COVID-19 czar, argue Susan Helper, David Clingingsmith, and Scott Shane. In light of the fast-paced nature of the coronavirus crisis and its grave threat to both the lives and livelihoods of Americans, the president must appoint a coordinator who can “use federal powers to direct the production of needed medical supplies, including personal protective equipment, ventilators, test kits, hospital beds, and negative-pressure rooms, which help prevent cross-contamination.” Doing so would allow the federal government to execute a coordinated, quick, and apolitical response, and deliver much-needed medical supplies to hospitals and care providers across the United States.

There are a variety of other ideas that can be activated to support hospitals and healthcare workers, Helper, Clingingsmith, and Shane explore in another column. These ideas include converting now-empty hotels in the cities worst hit by the outbreak into temporary hospitals with negative-pressure rooms, and retraining medical personnel from different fields to treat COVID-19 patients. But the proposals must be paired with longer-term restrictions on social activity, which inevitably will have economic ramifications—and action must be taken swiftly in order to prevent the coronavirus recession from becoming the coronavirus economic depression.

Links from around the web

The coronavirus outbreak and resulting economic downturn are making clear the holes in the social safety net for millions of workers, writes Shelly Steward for the Aspen Institute’s blog, particularly those workers with demanding and often unpredictable schedules and few job protections. While many companies have committed to expanding their paid sick leave policies due to the crisis, this is not enough. Many of these policy changes are only in place for the duration of this coronavirus outbreak, and many require an official COVID-19 diagnosis. Steward urges Congress to consider long-term and more universal solutions—and in the meantime, states and cities can act to fill the gaps.

Many gig economy workers are facing an impossible choice: risking COVID-19 or starving, report Veena Dubal and Meredith Whittaker in The Guardian. Because companies such as Uber Technologies Inc. sometimes classify their workers as independent contractors, they don’t have to provide benefits to their drivers, including access to the minimum wage or unemployment insurance. Though this is supposed to be illegal—particularly in the state of California, where a law was recently passed to prevent this misclassification of workers—it still happens, and it is particularly harmful amid the coronavirus outbreak, Dubal and Whittaker write. (As a side note, the $2.2 trillion stimulus package would provide access to Unemployment Insurance to gig economy workers, so they won’t have to keep making this choice.)

Said stimulus package is a good start, but more must be done in the coming weeks and months, argues Dylan Matthews for Vox. While the package is an extraordinary display of bipartisan compromise, and a “shockingly ambitious measure from a Republican legislature,” it is imperative that more continues to be done as the country slips into a recession in order to strengthen the measures included. Matthews looks back at the previous economic crisis—the Great Recession of 2007–2009—and the stimulus package passed by President Barack Obama, as well as the lessons it can provide for the current crisis and package, detailing what is commendable and what needs improvement in the Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security Act.

The workers most at-risk of exposure to coronavirus are also those who tend to be paid among the lowest salaries, find Beatrice Jin and Andrew McGill in Politico. In an interactive graphic, the authors show how many of the 24 million workers making less than $35,000 per year—from cashiers and bartenders to nursing assistants and paramedics—are facing the highest risk of injury during the coronavirus pandemic. The majority of this group, making up about 15 percent of the American workforce, is so at-risk because their livelihood typically depends on direct human contact and because workers in their salary tier are less likely to receive benefits such as paid sick leave that would help them weather any disruption in work. They also typically occupy jobs where remote work is not an option.

The ability to work from home also reveals a stark contrast in race and education level throughout the U.S. economy, write Christian DavenportAaron Gregg, and Craig Timberg for The Washington Post. A recent survey shows that people of color and the high-school (or less) educated make up the majority of those who have to continue going to their workspaces during the coronavirus outbreak—and those whose health is most at risk and whose incomes are most likely to suffer during the economic downturn. Davenport, Gregg, and Timberg show how the inequalities of the labor market are being thrust into light in new ways: Those who can work remotely won’t face the same threats to their health and livelihood as those who can’t. Poor people of color make up the majority of the latter group, while better-off white and Asian American workers fall largely in the former group.

Friday Figure

Figure is from Equitable Growth’s Twitter thread explaining how the coronavirus outbreak and consequent layoffs have led to a historically high number of Unemployment Insurance claims, with almost 3.3 million workers making UI claims the week of March 15–21. That is approximately 2.6 million more than the previous record of 695,000 claims in one week.

Brad DeLong: Worthy reads on equitable growth, March 21-27, 2020

Worthy reads from Equitable Growth:

  1. Check out Heather Boushey on Twitter, in which she writes: “In response to the #coronavirus crisis, the nationwide economic shutdown has put the economy “on ice” so that it can be ramped back up after the health crisis is addressed. Concerns about falling into a deep and protracted #coronavirus recession are exacerbated by historically high economic inequality, which makes the United States particularly vulnerable to economic shocks. Policymakers should keep income flowing by helping small businesses pay their bills, ensuring any corporate assistance helps workers, boosting unemployment insurance, and providing #paidleave. The United States is one of only three industrialized countries that does not ensure every worker has access to paid time off when they are sick. We also need additional fiscal stimulus to ensure a recession does not turn into a full-scale economic depression. That means direct payments to families and more support for SNAP, Medicaid, and the Children’s Health Insurance Program. We need to remember that the economy isn’t something that happens to us—it’s the direct result of choices that policymakers make. The only entity with the power to mobilize resources and not further exacerbate rising inequality at such a large scale is the government.”
  2. Read my“Cases and Deaths from Coronavirus Doubling Every Three Days Is Very Bad News Indeed,” in which I write: “I confess I am positively unmanned by the every-three-days doubling of reported cases and deaths here in the United States. I had thought that we would see true cases doubling every seven days. And back when reported cases started doubling every three days, I was encouraged, because I thought it meant that we were catching up on testing, and so getting closer to detecting the bulk of the symptomatic cases. But now it looks like that was wrong: reported cases were doubling every three days because true cases were doubling every three days—that is what deaths tell us was happening to true cases up until three weeks ago. The lack of case curve-bending makes me think that testing is not improving. It makes me think that reported cases are doubling every three days because true cases are doubling every three days. That means that the Trump administration has only 40 percent as much time to get its ass in gear as I thought it did. And that means the chances it will are very very low indeed.”
  3. Also read myThe Trump Administration’s Epic COVID-19 Failure,” in which I write: “As officials at the U.S. Centers for Disease Control and other public-health bodies surely must have recognized, asymptomatic transmission means that the standard method of quarantining symptomatic travelers when they cross national (or provincial) borders is insufficient. It also means that we have known for almost two months that we were playing a long game against the virus. With its spread more or less inevitable, the primary task was always to reduce the pace of community transmission as much as possible, so that health-care systems would not be overwhelmed before a vaccine could be developed, tested, and deployed. In the long game against a contagious virus, how to mitigate transmission is no secret. In Singapore, which has largely contained the outbreak within its borders, all travelers from abroad have been required to self-quarantine for 14 days, regardless of whether they have symptoms. In Japan, South Korea, and other countries, testing for COVID-19 has been conducted on a massive scale. These are the measures that responsible governments take. You test as many people as you can, and when you locate areas of community transmission, you lock them down. At the same time, you build a database of all those who have already developed immunity and thus may safely resume their normal routine.”

 

Worthy reads not from Equitable Growth:

  1. This is by a substantial margin the best thing I have seen on the coronavirus, and where we are with respect to it. My confidence that the Trump administration and the Republican senatorial majority are up to the task of organizing this is too low to measure. Read Richard Danzig and Marc Lipsitch, “Prepare Now for the Long War Against Coronavirus,” in which they write: “It’s essential to clearly envision the problems we’ll face over the next 12 to 18 months and mobilize to respond right away. Here are five priority problems and the actions we should take now … Minimizing errors and uncertainties about and maximizing confidence in our judgments about cure will soon become as important as present efforts at disease detection. People who recover from Covid-19 probably can work in hospitals, emergency response settings and ordinary jobs without fear of infection … We need to identify these people and assess how soon after their recovery they become unlikely to infect others … Assuring that someone has immunity against this new virus requires tests that are distinct from the PCR tests of nose and throat swabs now being used to identify infections. We need to develop and distribute antibody tests … Problem: If current efforts at social distancing succeed in spacing out infections, we face many months of demand for treatment … It’s essential to reduce demand for hospitalization by establishing methods to support lengthy treatment at home … telemedicine, house calls by nurse practitioners, on-line instruction for home care-givers, and support for safe travel … the production of enormous quantities of ventilators, personal protective equipment for health care workers and other medical supplies, and to ramp up our capacity for viral testing … Pervasive illness affecting most of the U.S. population over the course of a year will threaten not just health care systems but other critical infrastructure as well … People responsible for food production and delivery, power distribution, telecommunication, drinking water, transportation, cyber services and police need to ramp up efforts to protect and maintain these systems, and to detect and report any fragilities and failures. The Defense Department should be engaged to backstop these systems … It is essential to ensure that the United States can hold a national election in November safely, securely and democratically, even if contagion persists and social distancing is still necessary …This problem might be best addressed by enlisting a private, non-partisan entity (for example, a major foundation) to offer expert advice to Congress and to state and federal officials. With a sense of urgency and more than half a year to plan, voting by mail or via the internet—or other alternatives—could be made to work everywhere … A long school shutdown and widespread illness will mean missed education, the loss of school nutrition for needy kids, difficulties for teachers separated from their workplace, and psychological effects … The 50 states can address these issues individually, or they can, more effectively, band together to devise high-quality approaches … We can win … by treating it as both an emergency and a long-term challenge. We are rich, ingenious and resolute enough to prevail. But this virus has already shown we cannot wait until the moment of need to get organized.”
  2. Let me endorse this as a thoughtful assessment of how important it is to keep the U.S. economy from sending anybody a “you are bankrupt/shut down” signal in this public health crisis. Instead, every business and every worker should be being sent a “you are, at most, on pause/be ready to resume” signal. How to make sure that signal is sent requires fiscal stimulus an order of magnitude greater than the $2.2 trillion currently in the headlines. For one thing, it requires tolerance of inflation, as prices of medical equipment and necessities rise and as social distancing temporarily reduces productivity elsewhere in the economy. Read Peter R. Orszag, “Social Distancing Makes Sense Only With Huge Fiscal Stimulus,” in which he writes: “Mandating social distancing in response to the Covid-19 crisis requires socializing the economic costs of doing so. We as a society can’t reasonably require social distancing, with the massive economic consequences it entails, and believe that most of those costs should be privately borne. We therefore need to either abandon social distancing (thereby overwhelming health systems and sparking untold deaths) or enact much larger stimulus measures. And by much larger I mean far larger even than the eye-popping figures the Trump administration is now pursuing … The disruption is so vast … that government failure to act will result in an avalanche of bankruptcies and extended unemployment that will, in turn, inflict lasting damage on businesses and families, even after the health crisis passes … not being able to put Humpty Dumpty back together again. It is why government intervention cannot be limited to the sectors most directly affected (airlines and hotels, for example) and must take new forms beyond the conventional tools (such as rebates to individuals). While many existing stimulus measures are necessary and helpful … they are terribly inadequate … The dilemmas we face will continue until an effective anti-viral or therapeutic can be found that allows us to contract the disease without suffering significant harm. In the meantime, even if current efforts are successful at attenuating the spread of the disease over the next several weeks, social distancing will need to be re-imposed in cycles. Given the plausible timetable for developing a vaccine, and unless we get very lucky and the virus itself mutates in a less harmful direction, these cycles could continue for well more than a year … This is a fiscal risk worth taking … [To] those who argue that the cost is too high or that a stunning increase in the deficit is too risky [I say:] If you don’t like the fiscal cost but you favor social distancing, what you’re really saying is that you are willing to accept millions of bankruptcies and the ripping apart of corporate and social fabrics across the world … The economic harm comes mostly from the sudden stop … The demographics of those suffering from coronavirus and those suffering from the economic virus are quite different … Emmanuel Saez and Gabriel Zucman have proposed that governments simply pay companies to cushion the shock: “In the context of this pandemic, we need a new form of social insurance, one that directly targets and works through businesses,” they wrote earlier this month. “The most direct way to provide this insurance is to have the government act as a buyer of last resort. If the government fully replaces the demand that evaporates, each business can keep paying its workers and maintain its capital stock, as if it was operating under business as usual.” And Andrew Ross Sorkin of The New York Times has suggested a universal loan program, with a zero interest rate and extended repayment terms. One thing is clear about stimulus measures in this crisis: Bigger is better.”
  3. In a good world, Jim Stock would already be back in the Eisenhower old executive office building chairing the Council of Economic Advisors during this crisis. He is vastly more thoughtful, more confident, and more up to speed on the issues and the trade-offs that we face, economically, during this public health crisis. But we are not in a good world. We are in a very bad one. Already, the United States his response to the coronavirus is the worst in the world. And it only looks as though the gap between us and other countries is going to grow over the next months. Read Jim Stock, “Coronavirus: Data Gaps and the Policy Response,” in which he writes: “Social distancing and business shutdowns … [affect] the case transmission rate β…. [One] policy design question is how to achieve that case transmission rate while minimizing economic cost. A second. .. is the optimal. .. β, trading off … economic cost[s] … against … deaths … [We] lack … data … Tests have been rationed … The fraction of tests that are positive do not estimate the population rate of infection … The COVID-19 asymptomatic rate … estimates in the epidemiological literature range from 0.18 to 0.86. However, the asymptomatic rate could be estimated accurately and quickly by testing a random sample of the overall population. The policy response and its economic consequences hinge critically on the asymptomatic rate. As we illustrate using two policy paths for β, without better knowledge of this knowable parameter, policymakers could make needlessly conservative decisions which would have vast economic costs.”

Congress fights back, and it’s absolutely necessary

A stimulus package to combat the economic effects of the coronavirus outbreak is in the works.

(This piece was updated on April 1, 2020 to reflect the IRS guidance on the economic impact payments related to the coronavirus recession.)

The coronavirus is killing people at a breathtaking pace—more than 1,000 and counting in the United States and thousands more around the world. Dr. Anthony Fauci and an army of public health experts tell us that we must shut down public life to fight this virus and save lives. Local officials from coast to coast, including Gov. Andrew Cuomo of New York, Mayor Muriel Bowser of Washington, D.C., and Gov. Gavin Newson of California have shuttered nonessential businesses and are asking people to stay at home to contain the virus.

The fight against the coronavirus and our economic recovery come with a price. Last week, more than 3 million people applied for support from Unemployment Insurance, and that number understates the number of workers who lost their jobs or had their hours cut. (See Figure 1.)

Figure 1

More than ever, millions of families are trying to figure out how to pay the bills and feed their children. Thankfully, Congress is fighting back hard. In the early hours of Thursday, the U.S. Senate unanimously passed a $2.2 trillion package to support the economy. Hundreds of billions of dollars will go to states to fight the health crisis, to Unemployment Insurance programs to support those who lose their jobs, to struggling employers big and small, and directly to many women, men, and children that the government can reach. Congress is acting on all fronts and sending big dollars to families, businesses, and states.

This support for the U.S. economy is urgently needed. In addition to workers being laid off, businesses and families are not going to be able to pay their rent at the end of this month. After a decade of economic expansion, finally the people long on the sidelines were coming back to work. It is always the case that the last in—workers or businesses—are the first out. The lost expansion is a tragedy, second only to the lost lives from a coronavirus currently without a cure.

The package passed by the Senate and the House of Representatives and was signed by President Donald Trump on Friday. The package is broad-ranging and has many necessary facets. One key piece will focus on getting money directly to many people—referred to as “recovery rebates” in the legislation. In the next month or two, many people will receive $1,200 from the government. Families will receive another $500 per child. Not everyone will receive money, and some will wait longer than others. Even so, the government is sending money to hundreds of millions of people.

The recovery rebates will total nearly $300 billion. That amount represents 2 percent of consumer spending in 2019 and twice the total dollars of the stimulus payments in 2008 during the Great Recession of 2007–2009. Most importantly, 8 in 10 people in the United States will likely receive a full or partial recovery rebate.

Why spend so much sending money directly to people, even those who still have their health and their jobs? We do not know who will be hit hard by the coronavirus. Many expect the unemployment rate to rise to more than 20 percent by this summer. That level would rival that of the Great Depression. Everyone single person in the country would likely either lose a paycheck or know someone who has.

The reality for many decades has been that the United States is never ready for a recession. Almost one-quarter of households do not have $400 on hand. Small businesses operate with thin margins. And states face balanced budget requirements. None of these groups can make ends meet when income, sales, and tax revenues plummet—especially not when expenses for medical care and care for family members jump.

What do we know right now about the money going to people? When will they get their rebates? Will it show up in their bank accounts before their next rent payment? Sadly, no one knows—neither the former officials who oversaw the 2008 stimulus payments nor the current staff at the Internal Revenue Service. On March 30, 2020 the IRS provided more information on the rebates, which you can find here. One thing we know from past experience is that public servants in the government will do whatever they can to get the money out as quickly as possible. No one wants to see a child go without food or a senior unable to pay for a prescription.

Here is what we know from the legislation—working its way to the president’s desk—on the recovery rebates:

  • Payments will be $1,200 per adult or $2,400 for couples filing an IRS return.
  • For families, there will be an additional amount equal to $500 per child largely under age 17.
  • Adults with incomes higher than $75,000 or couples with incomes more than $150,000 are eligible for a reduced or no payment.
  • The legislation directs the federal government to send the rebates as rapidly as possible. To do so, they will use the most recent payment information on hand at the IRS. People who have not filed their taxes this year but did file last year should receive a payment based on that information.
  • Individuals who receive benefits from Social Security (for retirement, survivor benefits, and disability benefits) and Railroad Retirement Insurance will receive rebates. Other non-filers who receive benefits from the federal government may also be eligible.
  • It takes the IRS time—weeks not days—to create a file of everyone’s payment information and their rebate amount. Once that happens, those who used direct deposit will get their money within days. Limits exist in how many paper checks can go out in one week, but the money will come.
  • In total, families will receive nearly $300 billion, three times stimulus payments in 2008.

No government support put together in an emergency will be perfect. Sadly, it is those people who are most in need who are the hardest to reach. Who will not get a recovery rebate? Too many. First, anyone who does not have a Social Security number, which includes undocumented immigrants paying taxes. Such families are in the path of the coronavirus and deserve the support too—if for no other reason than for public health reasons. In addition, dependents who are adult children, disabled, or elderly parents will not. They need money too.

Will the recovery rebates be enough? Will the rest of the $2 trillion package be enough? That will be determined by the length of the public health crisis, but the answer is probably “no.” By every indication, we are in a recession that will be at least twice as deep and incredibly faster in its severity than the Great Recession. The only apt comparison is the Great Depression. Is it time to throw in the towel and turn on the TV for the duration? No. Congress, the Federal Reserve, and the American people are not done fighting.

We can do better. We need to make policies to deal with recessions automatically. Congress has sent money to people many times in recessions. It should not have taken weeks to get us to a plan we often use. People could already have money in their pockets if the systems were a go three weeks ago. We cannot change the past, but we can prepare for the future. Direct payments to people can and should be automatic. Congress should commit, before a recession, to start many other policies, especially support for the unemployed, as soon as a sign of distress is clear.

This recession will be very severe and the recovery difficult. We need policymakers who will stay the course until we are back on our feet, and then prepare for the next recession so that we can start the next recovery sooner. We will get back on our feet. But we must also be ready to do so next time more swiftly and more surely than today.

To prevent a long-term recession, make the U.S. government the payor of last resort now

As a result of the COVID-19 outbreak, employee layoffs have surged and businesses have closed.

The United States is facing an unprecedented economic crisis. With a public health-driven, government-ordered shutdown of vast sectors of the economy to slow the spread of the coronavirus, we’ve never seen the U.S. economy crater so quickly.

Quick government action is needed to stanch the flow of mass layoffs and prevent the mass liquidation of businesses. The death of a business has serious long-term costs. The links between entrepreneurs, workers, and customers are destroyed and often need to be rebuilt from scratch. Laid-off workers lose employment benefits, including employer-provided health insurance.

This is a moment, if ever there was one, for economists to provide guidance to policymakers about how to deal with the situation from an economic perspective. That is why the two of us gathered some 100 economists and other policy experts by video conference on March 24 to answer these questions:

  • How do we help people who are losing their livelihoods?
  • How do we help businesses survive the crisis?
  • How, in particular, do we set in place policies to ensure that the downturn does not cause severe damage to the U.S. economy far beyond the actual shutdown?

Numerous ideas were put on the virtual table. Congress has now passed three measures, some elements of which were very much influenced by members of this group, though the approach the two of us advocate has not been adopted. But other countries have implemented similar measures. There is still time to consider our ideas in the United States.

The informal name for what we described to the group is “U.S. government as payor of last resort.” The message it sends to businesses—the message that should be coming from every head of state—is this: Do not lay off your workers or liquidate your business. Government will pay your idle workers and your necessary maintenance costs while you are shut down. Government money is coming soon.

The most direct way to keep businesses alive through this crisis is to have the government act as the payor of last resort. In other words, have the government pay wages and essential business maintenance costs. This would allow locked-down businesses to have their workers continue to be paid instead of being laid off and businesses to keep paying their necessary bills instead of going bankrupt.

There are two parts to this program. For wages, idle workers should immediately start receiving benefits we would call “Employment Insurance benefits.” These workers would still be formally employed, but they would no longer be a cost to their employers, and, importantly, no rehiring process would be needed when they can go back to work. In addition, self-employed individuals such as gig workers could report themselves as idle and be eligible for payments. The program would be run through the nation’s Unemployment Insurance system.

The second part of the program would be payments to locked-down businesses. These companies would report the costs necessary to maintain their business and receive payments for those costs from the government. Necessary costs are rents, utility payments, interest on debt, health insurance for idle workers, and other costs that are vital for the maintenance of the business.

The amounts do not need to be exact. Verification of costs and any needed corrections could take place once the lockdown is over. The advantage of this policy is that businesses could hibernate without bleeding cash and hence without risking bankruptcy.

We can figure out the approximate cost of this program by projecting anticipated loss of Gross Domestic Product. With a nationwide lockdown, about 30 percent of U.S. aggregate demand could evaporate over the next three months, leading to a 7.5 percent drop in annual GDP.

We estimate the cost of the program to be half of this drop, or 3.75 percent of GDP, a lower cost than we might have feared. We estimate that Employment Insurance benefits would replace about 60 percent of wages, while essential business costs are probably less than half of normal operating costs. That averages to approximately half of GDP. This payor-of-last-resort program should be very limited in duration—three months for instance—so the costs remain manageable and long-term business decisions are not affected.

Over the past few weeks, other countries have announced similar programs, particularly Denmark, the United Kingdom, and the Netherlands. Alas, the legislation adopted by the U.S. Congress this week does not go far enough and is not well-targeted to ailing sectors. Business loans help businesses but don’t compensate them for their losses. Direct payments to individuals help alleviate temporary economic hardship but are not well-targeted to those who lose their jobs and are not needed by those who don’t lose their jobs. Unemployment Insurance and paid sick leave policies come closest to helping laid-off workers and those unable to work, but they don’t prevent layoffs and they don’t help businesses.

The program we propose would not, of course, fully offset the economic costs of the coronavirus recession. No matter what governments do, there will be economic losses. But these measures would maintain the cash flow for families and businesses so that the shutdown has no secondary impacts on aggregate demand. This would lay the groundwork for a quick rebound once the epidemic is controlled. That should be our long-term goal.

Research shows paid leave is needed to protect families, workers, and businesses during the coronavirus recession and beyond

The challenge for U.S. workers of balancing family and job responsibilities amid the coronavirus recession without access to paid family and medical leave is, alas, a familiar story even before the pandemic hit the country. When a new child arrives, loved ones get sick, or a serious illness strikes, people need time away from work. But even at these times of joy or stress, bills and expenses will keep coming, and families must find a way to cope with financial uncertainty. This is not a new challenge, but it is often one that families deal with individually—with every household forced to patch together solutions as best they can.

Now, the rapid spread of COVID-19 and the economic measures taken to “flatten the curve” of its spread expose anew the deep problems with our nation’s lack of federal paid family leave and medical leave programs. Workers will have to take time away from work to take care of themselves, their families, and their communities to cope with this fast-escalating public health crisis.

In response to the pandemic, Congress earlier this month extended limited emergency paid leave for parents dealing with school closures. This measure is temporary and will not help workers who need to remain at home due to serious illness or a sick loved one. A permanent and robust family and medical leave system is needed to help families weather the current public health crisis and support families’ economic security and well-being for years to come.

Traditionally, the conversation around paid family and medical leave has centered around new parents, and, indeed, so has much of the research. Yet, there are many different reasons one may need time away from work. Paid family and medical leave programs at the state level typically cover paid time off to bond with a new child, respond to a spouse’s military service, deal with a loved one’s illness, and deal with one’s own serious illness. As policymakers consider paid family and medical leave options in response to COVID-19 and beyond, they are aided by extensive research on how to design a paid leave system that supports families and the economy. See our new factsheet on paid leave policies amid the coronavirus recession.

Much of what is known about paid family and medical leave comes from research on parental leave. While people will continue to have babies even during a pandemic, parental leave has not been the focus of the response to COVID-19. Rather, the pandemic highlights a critical need for paid medical leave and paid caregiving leave for those dealing with their own illness or that of a loved one.

Less research has been devoted to these types of paid leave, but studies on similar programs suggest that allowing paid time away from work could support individual health, public health, and economic security. See our new factsheets on paid caregiving leave and paid medical leave, and our longer issue brief on these topics amid the coronavirus recession.

The current and even more dire future consequences of the coronavirus recession means it is critical to enact policies based on evidence-backed research about what works. The COVID-19 pandemic highlights the need for permanent paid family and medical leave at the federal level. When this new pandemic is over or when the next one comes along, people will still start families, get sick, and need to care for loved ones. The research strongly suggests that paid family and medical leave can provide important health and economic benefits to families and the broader economy. Policymakers should lean on this research as they work to support families in this time of crisis and beyond.

Paid medical and caregiving leave during the coronavirus pandemic: What they are and why they matter

(This issue brief draws on a longer report by Jane Waldfogel and Emma Liebman, “Paid Family Care Leave: A missing piece in the U.S. social insurance system.”)

Overview

In response to the new coronavirus health crisis, workers across the United States need paid time off to deal with their health needs and the health needs of loved ones. At the state level, three main types of paid time away from work are provided to meet these needs: paid sick days, paid medical leave, and paid caregiving leave. (See Table 1.)

Table 1

The traditional mechanics of paid sick days in the United States are perhaps the most familiar to most people. As a worker amasses more hours on the job, she accrues time off at her full rate of pay to cover a few days of absence from work to attend to short-term medical needs. People use paid sick days to attend doctor’s appointments, recover from short-term illnesses such as colds, and to care for family members with short-term ailments. Paid sick days are offered voluntarily by many employers, and laws in many states and municipalities guarantee workers the right to earn paid sick days. Recently passed federal law gives some workers access to paid sick days for needs related to COVID-19, the scientific name for the disease caused by the new coronavirus, if they work for a qualifying employer.

Download File
Paid medical and caregiving leave during the coronavirus pandemic: What they are and why they matter

Paid medical leave and paid caregiving leave may be less familiar concepts. The term “paid family and medical leave” often conjures the image of leave to care for a new child. Yet paid leave encompasses much more. Paid family and medical leave programs at the state level typically cover four types of paid time off:

  • Leave to bond with a new child
  • Leave related to a spouse’s active duty military service
  • Leave to deal with one’s own serious medical issue
  • Leave to care for a loved one with a serious medical condition

Though some employers provide paid medical leave through private Temporary Disability Insurance providers, paid caregiving leave is not widely provided by employers. Large swaths of the U.S. workforce have no access to paid medical leave, nor to paid caregiving leave.

Over the past two decades, eight states and the District of Columbia have sought to extend coverage to more workers, passing laws that provide the workforce with both paid medical leave and paid caregiving leave. There is wide variation in leave length, but typical state policies allow for 6 weeks to 26 weeks of leave with partial wage replacement.

These programs are funded using a social insurance model, such as the Social Security program and the Unemployment Insurance program. A small payroll tax is collected to fund benefits for eligible workers who need time off with wage replacement when a qualifying event occurs. Some state paid leave programs provide job protection—the right to return to your job when your leave finishes—and some do not.

There are other legal protections at the federal level that give workers the right to unpaid leave that is job protected: the Family Medical Leave Act, the Americans with Disabilities Act, and the Pregnancy Discrimination Act. If a worker’s state paid leave program does not offer job protection, then, as a work-around, she can take job-protected unpaid leave through the Family Medical Leave Act, the Americans with Disabilities Act, or the Pregnancy Discrimination Act simultaneously with unprotected paid leave. Not all workers qualify for these federal protections, so some must take paid leave without a guarantee that their job will be available when they return.

When a personal medical need, family caretaking need, or public health crisis emerges, paid time away from work is critical for individuals, families, public health, and the broader economy. For decades prior to the new coronavirus crisis and looming coronavirus recession, Congress failed to establish a social insurance program providing wage replacement during personal medical leave and caregiving leave. Perhaps one reason that Congress has failed to act is a shortage of information on what precisely paid medical leave and paid caregiving leave are and what benefits they bring to individuals, family members, businesses, and the economy as a whole. Below, we discuss paid medical leave and paid caregiving leave in turn. We cover the evidence base on how medical leave and caregiving leave affect both health and economic outcomes.

Paid medical leave

To best draw conclusions on how paid medical leave affects people’s health and finances, we would look to causal inference studies that evaluate the effects of social insurance programs that provide paid medical leave. However, researchers rely on policy variation to draw conclusions about the effects of programs, and for paid medical leave, policy variation has been poorly timed. Rhode Island, California, New Jersey, New York, Puerto Rico, and Hawaii all launched programs prior to 1970—when data quality was limited—and their programs have remained relatively unchanged over time. The next paid medical leave program to be implemented was in Washington state, in 2020, and not enough time has passed to evaluate that program.

As a result, very few studies have been conducted on paid medical leave specifically. Yet by looking at the literature on private Temporary Disability Insurance and paid sick days, we can gather important information on how paid medical leave is likely to affect the health and economic outcomes of those who take it.

Health outcomes

Research on the impact of paid medical leave on health outcomes is still emerging. Evidence to date suggests there are several different mechanisms through which paid medical leave may have an effect. These include improved health management, reduced financial stress, and improved public health. Let’s examine each in turn.

Health management

One of the strongest signals that paid medical leave may impact health outcomes comes from research on paid sick days. Broadly speaking, having access to paid sick days is associated with a significantly lower risk of mortality across a wide range of conditions. The nature of this relationship is still being studied, but evidence suggests access to paid sick days better enables workers to manage a new health condition, for instance by seeking preventative care and earlier treatment of conditions.

Data from the National Health Interview Survey appears to support this idea. One study found that workers with access to paid sick days were significantly more likely to seek preventive medical care, such as mammograms, pap tests, and endoscopies, than other workers after controlling for other factors. Studies have also found that when workers have access to sick leave, they take more time off work for health-related reasons. Studies also find workers visit emergency rooms less. This suggests that workers with paid leave may be better able to schedule medical appointments, thereby avoiding the use of emergency rooms for less-urgent conditions.

Conversely, workers without access to paid sick days are significantly less likely to receive preventive health screenings, even when they are aware that they face higher medical risks. These findings are also important because early treatment of a health condition has been found to reduce the severity and duration of the condition.

Delaying or forgoing leave while sick or injured can have serious health consequences. One longitudinal study of a cohort of British civil servants, known as the Whitehall II study, found that unhealthy men who took no sick leave were twice as likely to experience a serious coronary event, compared to unhealthy men who took moderate amounts of sick leave. Similarly, a study that linked responses to a survey of Danish workers with administrative data on social welfare payments found that respondents who went to work ill more than six times over the past year had a 53 percent higher risk of taking medical leave for at least two weeks and a 74 percent higher risk of taking leave for more than 2 months after adjusting for confounding factors.

But not all the evidence is clear or consistent. A doctoral dissertation using the Medical Expenditure Panel Survey, which provides a 2-year follow-up to the National Health Interview Survey, did not find clear patterns of a change in leave-taking when workers experienced a job change that makes them lose or gain access to paid sick days.

Stress reduction

Paid medical leave may also improve health outcomes for workers by reducing stress associated with a financial insecurity due to a health shock. Taking time away from work to address a medical condition is a common source of financial strain for workers and families, one that can also add stress on workers who are already concerned with their health. Stress, regardless of its source, has been shown to negatively impact physical and mental health. In addition, research from developed countries shows that income levels directly affect mortality. Research also finds that severe debt is correlated with poor health.

To the extent that paid medical leave reduces stress associated with financial strain, it could also lead to improved health for workers. Research on the impact of the Earned Income Tax Credit and disability benefits suggests income supports can have significant positive effects. A study of the impact of an increase in this tax credit in 1993 was associated with an improvement in maternal health. It is thought that a reduction in financial stress was an important factor.

Similarly, a study taking advantage of the discontinuities in the Social Security Disability Insurance benefit formula finds “that $1,000 in annual SSDI payments decreases the annual mortality rate of lower-income beneficiaries by approximately 0.1 to 0.25 percentage points.” Beneficiaries with higher past earnings and the largest disability benefits did not experience the same benefits.

Public health

The literature on paid sick days suggests paid time off to address certain illnesses may have important positive effects on public health by helping to reduce the spread of contagious diseases. This evidence could have implications for medical leave or show opportunities for new research.

An analysis of local and state sick leave mandates in the United States using Google Flu Trend data found a significant reduction in the general flu rate after the mandates were implemented. These public health benefits also have spillover benefits for employers through reduced absenteeism. One study using seven panels of the Medical Expenditure Panel Study—which surveys people, their employers, and their healthcare providers—concluded that paid sick days reduce overall absenteeism by reducing the spread of influenza-like illness. The study estimated that reduced absenteeism due to paid sick days could have saved employers $630 million to $1.88 billion per year in 2016 dollars. It is possible that paid medical leave could also impact public health, but to what extent is unclear. Paid medical leave could be important to people suffering from complications due to COVID-19.

Economic outcomes

Serious medical conditions that require time away from work can pose a threat to workers’ economic well-being. They can lead to an immediate reduction in income from wages while the worker is on leave, an increase in out-of-pocket expenses for medical care, and a heightened risk of job loss.

Employers and the broader economy are also affected when work-limiting medical conditions lead to worker absences, reductions in productivity, and the loss of skilled staff. Government programs and spending also are affected when workers lose wages and employment, and must turn to public assistance programs for support.

Paid medical leave could help address these challenges, but existing research on the direct effects of paid medical leave specifically is scant and is limited to specific medical conditions. But related research on sick leave, income security, occupational health, and disability programs suggests paid medical leave could affect economic outcomes by reducing income volatility, helping workers to return to employment after taking leave, reducing productivity loses due to presenteeism, and supporting greater labor supply and long-term labor force participation.

Income shocks

Work-limiting medical conditions that threaten a worker’s economic stability often arise suddenly. These health and income shocks can put many medium- and low-wage workers and their families at risk of hardship when a medical condition forces someone to stop working for a period of time. A 2015 study by The Pew Charitable Trusts found that 1 in 3 families report having no savings at all and that approximately 41 percent of families did not have enough emergency funding to cover an unexpected $2,000 expense. For these families, taking weeks of leave to address a health condition without wage replacement would be very difficult or even catastrophic. A median worker’s weekly earnings, for example, in the third quarter of 2019 was $360, according to the Bureau of Labor Statistics. For this median-wage worker, 12 weeks of unpaid medical leave would reduce gross take home pay by $4,320.

Income disruptions make families significantly more likely to face eviction and to miss payments for housing and utilities. Families dependent on a single wage earner are especially vulnerable. Research on savings and assets, however, shows that even small amounts of savings can help families weather income disruptions. While 21.1 percent of families with savings of $249 or less missed a housing payment, that percentage falls to 15.2 percent when families have savings of between $250 and $749. Similarly, the additional income available to workers through paid medical leave could boost family finances enough to improve their ability to weather health-related income disruptions.

For many workers, a loss of wages due to medical leave is often further compounded by an increase in out-of-pocket medical expenditures, an important factor in analyzing the potential consequences for workers and families. A study of the 2007–2008 panel of the Medical Expenditure Panel Study found workers with a temporary disability pay approximately 22 percent of their healthcare expenditures out of pocket, or an average of $388. More broadly, the Federal Reserve found that “one-fifth of adults had major, unexpected medical bills to pay,” with these bills most often totaling between $1,000 and $4,999, and about 40 percent of those with bills had unpaid debt.

A Journal of the American Medical Association research letter summarized a survey of patients with stage III colorectal cancer that found respondents without paid sick or medical leave reported significantly higher personal financial burdens, including a higher rate of borrowing money and having difficulty making credit card payments, and a significantly greater likelihood of leaving their job. In addition, workers who lose their job may also lose access to employer-provided health insurance.

The consequences of unmitigated economic shocks due to medical problems extend across people’s financial lives and affect participation in social programs. The onset of poor health is a significant factor in early withdrawals of 401(k) retirement savings plans. Paid medical leave could help workers avoid or reduce the extent to which they tap retirement savings to deal with health shocks. For lower-income workers eligible for means-tested programs, such as the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program, taking unpaid medical leave could increase their benefits. Using National Health Interview Survey data and controlling for many factors, one study found that working-age adults without paid sick days are 1.41 times more likely to receive income from a state or county welfare program and 1.34 times more likely to receive Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program benefits. When workers receive paid leave benefits, however, they contribute additional tax revenue based on those benefits. To the extent that paid medical leave supports labor force participation, it also leads to higher contributions to the Social Security trust funds, both strengthening the program’s finances and increasing their retirement benefits.

Labor force participation

Creating a new paid medical leave benefit could have implications for long-term labor force participation. Yet the nature of the relationship between such a benefit and labor supply is complex and not fully understood.

In the short term, access to paid medical leave may reduce the risk of job separations. One study using several panels of the Medical Expenditure Panel Study found that access to paid sick days reduced job separations, suggesting paid medical leave may have a similar effect. More specifically, the study found that, after controlling for many worker and job characteristics, “paid sick days decreases the probability of job separation by at least 2.5 percentage points, or 25 percent.” This effect is comparable to what has been found with employer-provided health insurance. In addition, some experts suggest that a medical leave or short-term disability benefit creates an opportunity for employers to provide supports and accommodations that could improve overall labor force participation.

Over the longer term, some research suggests that the provision of short-term disability benefits, which are typically offered for a duration of six months or longer can increase applications to long-term disability insurance by reducing the costs associated with the long waiting period for those benefits. However, studies are mixed on the extent to which this effect is seen in actual labor force participation.

Further, it is not clear whether or how these findings pertain to shorter-duration paid medical leave benefits, such as those that only last 12 weeks. One study that looked at a change in German law to reduce the generosity of benefits for sick leaves lasting longer than six weeks found no evidence that the duration of absences decreased, as would be expected if a significant moral hazard existed. The study also found, however, that lower-income and middle-aged subgroups may be more sensitive to these changes. Similarly, one study used the gradual phase-in of nine city-level and four state-level sick leave pay mandates on employers and found neither employment nor wage growth was significantly affected.

Paid caregiving leave

The first state to implement a social insurance program covering paid caregiving leave was California, in 2004. New Jersey followed in 2009, and then Rhode Island (2013), New York (2018), and Washington state (2020) followed suit. The evidence thus far suggests that the state programs are popular, though perhaps underused. Each of these states implemented paid leave to bond with a new child (often referred to as “parental leave”) simultaneously to their enactment of paid caregiving leave (leave to care for older children and other family members), and most of the research literature to date has focused on paid parental leave, which is more commonly used than paid caregiving leave.

This larger body of work on paid parental leave, however, is instructive in thinking about the likely health and economic effects of paid caregiving leave. Here’s what we know from the available evidence.

Health outcomes

Evidence from parental leave studies indicates that state paid leave programs improve caregiver and care recipient health, suggesting that time with pay to focus on caregiving responsibilities helps caregivers maintain their own health, as well as care for others. One study using data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics to examine outcomes for parents of young children in California found that the introduction of paid family and medical leave improved the self-rated health of caregivers, as well as improving psychological health for mothers and reducing alcohol use for fathers.

Similarly, an Australian study found that the introduction of a national paid maternity leave program led to small improvements in both mental and physical health for mothers. And more research from California shows improvements in child health, as well as a 10 percent to 24 percent improvement in maternal mental health, suggesting that paid caregiving leave can yield dividends for the care recipient and caregiver alike.

Research on home-based care also offers suggestions about the health outcomes we might expect from caregiving leave. A 2019 study, for example, that used data from a demonstration project that randomly assigned cash allowances to Medicaid beneficiaries eligible for homecare, found that increased family involvement in home-based care improves health outcomes for the care recipient. The study found that recipients had a lower likelihood of emergency room use and lower incidences of bed sores and infections.

Taken together, these results are promising. Still, they are by no means exhaustive. More comprehensive research is needed to establish that state caregiving paid leave provisions improve health outcomes for leave-takers and care recipients across the board.

Economic outcomes

By providing workers with partial wage replacement during time away from work while caring for a loved one, paid caregiving leave has the potential to improve economic outcomes for workers and employers. The research literature suggests that caregiving leave is likely to boost labor force participation without harming employers.

Labor force participation

With the exception of a small number of studies, the bulk of the evidence suggests that paid leave for new parents increases labor force participation. The research suggests that paid parental leave in California, for example, increased the likelihood that a new mother was working a year after the birth of her child by 18 percentage points, and 2 years following the birth, mothers’ work hours and their weeks at work were 18 percentage points and 11 percentage points higher, respectively, than comparable mothers prior to the implementation of the paid leave policy. Perhaps these increases in labor force participation ameliorate poverty for the most vulnerable caregivers of new children. One study finds that the introduction of paid leave in California is tied to a 10.2 percent decrease in the risk of new mothers dropping below the poverty threshold and disproportionately helps women with lower levels of education and who are unmarried.

While the evidence base is comparatively thin with regard to caregiving leave, one study finds that following the implementation of paid leave in California, labor force participation of caregivers increased by 8 percent in the short run and even further (14 percent) in the long run. This effect was concentrated among women.

Employer responses

Employer responses to paid family leave programs in California, New Jersey, and Rhode Island have been predominantly neutral or positive. Although there had been some concerns before the laws went into effect about the potential costs associated with paid leave entitlements—such as increased administrative burdens or the need for firms to hire temporary replacements—the majority of employers across all states with operational paid leave programs and across all firm sizes have reported neutral or positive attitudes toward the laws. In a 2011 survey analyzing the California paid family leave program, 90 percent of employers reported that the program had a neutral or positive effect on profitability, and 8.8 percent reported that the paid family leave program had saved their firm money.

Similarly, a study of New Jersey’s paid family leave program found that 10 percent of employers felt that the program had a negative effect on the firm’s profitability, with 80 percent reporting neutral experiences and another 10 percent reporting that the program increased profitability. Research comparing employer responses before and after Rhode Island’s law went into effect found that the law had no overall impact on employers, and that two-thirds of employers were somewhat or very supportive of the law. A similar survey also found that two-thirds of employers in New Jersey were supportive of the law.

The lack of negative responses on the part of employers in California, New Jersey, and Rhode Island probably is because many employers are able to avoid hiring a new employee during the leave period of the absent employee and instead can distribute that leave-taker’s work to other employees. In addition, for employers who previously relied on their own paid leave provisions, paid leave programs could potentially decrease costs by allowing the state payroll tax to foot the bill rather than paying employees themselves.

Conclusion

As of the publication of this brief, Congress has failed to provide paid medical leave and paid caregiving leave to any workers in the United States, even those affected by COVID-19. The recently introduced PAID Leave Act would extend these benefits to workers affected by COVID-19 and a broader range of medical problems. The rise of COVID-19 shines a light on the need for permanent paid caregiving and medical leave enacted at the federal level.

People become seriously ill all the time. The research reviewed in this brief provides evidence that paid leave for the seriously ill and their caretakers over weeks and months can provide important health and economic benefits to individuals and to society broadly over months and years. Had a paid medical leave and paid caregiving leave social insurance program already been in place at the federal level when COVID-19 struck, the mechanics would have been in order to disburse funds to workers taking caregiving and medical leave as a result of the COVID-19 pandemic.