Must-read: Łukasz Rachel and Thomas D. Smith: “Towards a Global Narrative on Long-Term Real Interest Rates”

Graph 30 Year Treasury Inflation Indexed Security Constant Maturity FRED St Louis Fed

Must-Read: Łukasz Rachel and Thomas D. Smith: Towards a Global Narrative on Long-Term Real Interest Rates: “Many candidate explanations for the low level of real interest rates have been put forward…

…Less progress has been made on bringing together the different hypotheses into a unifying framework, on quantifying their relative importance and on predicting the future path for real interest rates. This column attempts to fill that gap, and suggests that persistent shifts to global desired savings and investment are behind the bulk of the fall in real interest rates. Those trends are unlikely to unwind anytime soon, so that the global equilibrium rate is likely to remain low, perhaps settling at or below 1% in the medium to long-run.

Must-read: Joe Stiglitz: “Why the Great Malaise of the World Economy Continues in 2016”

Must-Read: Joe Stiglitz: Why the Great Malaise of the World Economy Continues in 2016: “In early 2010, I warned… that… the world risked sliding into what I called a ‘Great Malaise’…

…Unfortunately, I was right: We didn’t do what was needed, and we have ended up precisely where I feared we would… a deficiency of aggregate demand, brought on by a combination of growing inequality and a mindless wave of fiscal austerity. Those at the top spend far less than those at the bottom, so that as money moves up, demand goes down. And countries like Germany that consistently maintain external surpluses are contributing significantly to the key problem of insufficient global demand…. The U.S. suffers from a milder form of the fiscal austerity prevailing in Europe… some 500,000 fewer people are employed by the public sector in the U.S. than before the crisis. With normal expansion in government employment since 2008, there would have been two million more.

The only cure for the world’s malaise is an increase in aggregate demand. Far-reaching redistribution of income would help, as would deep reform of our financial system–not just to prevent it from imposing harm on the rest of us, but also to get banks and other financial institutions to do what they are supposed to do: match long-term savings to long-term investment needs…. The obstacles the global economy faces are not rooted in economics, but in politics and ideology. The private sector created the inequality and environmental degradation with which we must now reckon. Markets won’t be able to solve these and other critical problems that they have created, or restore prosperity, on their own. Active government policies are needed. That means overcoming deficit fetishism. It makes sense for countries like the U.S. and Germany that can borrow at negative real long-term interest rates to borrow to make the investments that are needed…

A semi-platonic dialogue about secular stagnation, asymmetric risks, Federal Reserve policy, and the role of model-building in guiding economic policy

Sanzio 01 jpg 3 820×2 964 pixels

Sokrates: You remember how I used to say that only active dialogue–questions-and-answers, objections-and-replies–could convey true knowledge? That a flat wax tablet covered by written words could only convey an inadequate and pale simulacrum of education?

Aristoteles: Yes. And you remember how I showed you that you were wrong? That conversation is ephemeral, and very quickly becomes too confused to be a proper educational tool? That only something like an organized and coherent lecture can teach? And only something like the textbooks compiled by my lecture notes can make that teaching durable?

Aristokles: But, my Aristoteles, you never mastered my “dialogue” form. My “dialogue” form has all the advantages of permanence and organization of your textbooks, and all the advantages of real dialectic of Sokrates’s conversation.

Sokrates: How very true, wise Aristokles!

Aristokles How am I to take that?

Xanthippe: You now very well: as snark, pure snark. That’s his specialty.

Hypatia: This is all complicated by the fact that in the age of the internet real, written, permanent dialogues can spring up at a moment’s notice:

Sokrates: And with that, let’s roll the tape:


Other things linked to that are highly relevant and worth reading:


Things I did not find and place outbound links to, but should have:

  • Polya
  • Dennis Robertson
  • Donald Patinkin

Looking at the whole thing, I wince at how lazy people–especially me–have been with their weblog post titles. I should find time to go back and retitle everything, perhaps adding an explanatory sentence to each link…

Paul Krugman and Larry Summers Are Such Amazing F#@$*%$ Geniuses! Department

So as I finish my Pre-Federal Reserve Interest-Rate Liftoff Lollapalooza, I am left with three conclusions:

  1. Paul Krugman and Larry Summers are such amazing f#@$*%$ geniuses…
  2. If I simply wiped my brain, and reprogrammed the left half with Paul and the right half with Larry, I would be so much smarter than I am…
  3. Their influence on low-theory, analysis, and policy is immense, yet somehow… not big enough…

I confess that back when I somehow found myself taking point on the internet for the Larry-Summers-for-Fed-Chair movement, I thought that the choice between Janet and Larry had the potential to be a big deal if we wound up in the tails–that Larry might break the committee so that it could not act when it needed to, and Janet might fail to act in the absence of consensus when it need to act. But I did not think it would be a big deal anywhere near the center of the distribution.

Yet here we are in the center of the distribution, and somehow the difference the choice has made feels… substantial. Larry the Dove…

Here’s the whole lollapalooza:

What Is the Eccles Building Thinking Today? I: The Failure to Think Through the Consequences of “Secular Stagnation”

Olivier Blanchard, at least, has said that the secular decline in global real interest rates and increased macro instability means that the 2%/year inflation target was greatly ill-advised and needs to be raised to 4%/year. But, among the great and good who staff the finance ministries, central banks, and international organizations these days, he is nearly alone. And the other pieces of the policy puzzle that might get us out of our zero-lower-bound-secular-stagnation pickle–aggressive redistribution via taxes and transfers, higher debt levels for reserve currency-issuing sovereigns with exorbitant privilege to boost the supply of safe assets, reducing risk premia by governments’ assumption of the role of entrepreneurial risk-bearer of last resort, international organizations that emerging markets regard as friends rather than enemies–are nowheresville.

The prevailing view among the great and good who staff governments and organizations is that the interest rate-capacity utilization configuration is going to normalize “soon”. As Larry writes: “the ‘headwinds’ orthodoxy prevailing in the official community… has been consistently far behind the curve…. The ‘temporary headwinds’ interpretation of low neutral real rates has been wrong for the last few years and is not hugely plausible as a basis for predicting the next few…”

And with U.S. 30-year Treasury bonds at 3.0%/year nominal and German at 1.4%/year nominal, financial markets provide no warrant for believing what are now called “headwinds” will ease any time over the next generation.

Since World War II, central bankers and governments have at least believed that they had the tools to successfully manage the macroeconomy. Now I do not believe that they think they do have tools adequate to the likely macroeconomic environment over the next generation. Yet this lack of tools does not seem to bother the great and good very much today…

Must-Read: Larry Summers: Breaking New Ground on Neutral Rates: “Lukasz Rachel and Thomas Smith have a terrific new paper…

…document[ing]… the length and breadth of the decline… in real rates… over 25 years… shows the inadequacy of shorter-term explanations of low neutral real rates such as those of Ken Rogoff that focus on the financial crisis and its aftermath…. They present thoughtful calculations assigning roles to rising inequality and growing reserve accumulation on the saving side and lower priced capital goods and slower labor force growth on the investment side. They also note the importance of rising risk premia… [an] first important word on decomposing the causal factors behind declining real rates….

They reach the important conclusion that there is little basis for assuming a significant increase in neutral real rates going forward. This conclusion differs sharply from the ‘headwinds’ orthodoxy prevailing in the official community…. There will be much less scope to raise rates in the industrial world over the next few years than the world’s central banks suppose…. The zero lower bound is likely to be a major issue….

Rachel and Smith also share my concern that a world of chronic very low real rates is going to be a world of high volatility, imprudent risk taking, excessive leverage and frequent financial accident…. It is fashionable to invoke the brave new world of macro-prudential policy…. As best I can tell, US macroprudential policy as currently practiced has meaningfully impaired liquidity in some key markets and damaged the credit availability for small and medium sized businesses while not touching excessive flows to emerging markets and high yield corporate issuance…. I doubt that actual regulators who, after all, were proclaiming the health of the banking system in mid 2008 are capable of pulling it off consistently given the pressures they face.

Must-Read Pre-Liftoff Lollapalooza: Lukasz Rachel and Thomas D Smith: Secular Drivers of the Global Real Interest Rate

Must-Read Pre-Liftoff Lollapalooza: As Larry Summers says, this fits neither Ben Bernanke’s ascription of low real interest rates to a transitory global savings glut caused by the political-insurance preferences of non-return maximizing market actors, nor Ken Rogoff’s belief that it is overwhelmingly the result of overleverage and the need for the unwinding phase of a debt supercycle. The cures proposed are then (i) higher target inflation rates, (ii) higher public debt levels, (iii) more mobilization of risk-bearing capacity in private-sector financial markets, (iv) redistribution, and (v) an international lender of last resort that emerging markets trust.

Lukasz Rachel and Thomas D Smith: Secular Drivers of the Global Real Interest Rate: “Long-term real interest rates across the world have fallen by about 450 basis points over the past 30 years…

…We think we can account for around 400 basis points of the 450 basis points fall… slowing global growth [is] one force… but shifts in saving and investment preferences appear more important… demographic forces, higher inequality and to a lesser extent the glut of precautionary saving by emerging markets. Meanwhile, desired levels of investment have fallen as a result of the falling relative price of capital, lower public investment, and… an increase in the spread between risk-free and actual interest rates. Moreover, most of these forces look set to persist and some may even build further. This suggests that the global neutral rate may remain low and perhaps settle at (or slightly below) 1% in the medium to long run. If true, this will have widespread implications for policymakers — not least in how to manage the business cycle if monetary policy is frequently constrained by the zero lower bound.

Must-Read: Larry Summers: Central Bankers Do Not Have as Many Tools as They Think

Must-Read: As John Maynard Keynes famously wrote, a government dedicated to producing a high-pressure economy is needed to enable entrepreneurship, enterprise, and growth. A government that does not only fail to work to generate high-pressure now, but also lacks a plan for fighting the next recession, is a government that drives the Confidence Fairy far away indeed:

Lawrence Summers: Central Bankers do Not Have as Many Tools as They Think: “It is agreed that the ‘neutral’ interest rate…

…has declined substantially and is likely to be lower in the future than in the past throughout the industrial world because of a growing relative abundance of savings relative to investment…. Neutral real interest rates may well rise over the next few years…. This is what many expect…. [But a] number of considerations make me doubt the US economy’s capacity to absorb significant increases in real rates over the next few years… leav[ing] me far from confident that there is substantial scope for tightening in the US and there is probably even less scope in other parts of the industrialised world. The fact that central banks in countries, including Europe, Sweden and Israel, where rates were zero found themselves reversing course after raising rates adds to the cause for concern.

But there is a more profound worry…. Once a recovery is mature the odds of it ending within two years are about half…. When recession comes it is necessary to cut rates more than 300 basis points. I agree with the market that the odds are the Fed will not be able to raise rates 100 basis points a year without threatening to undermine recovery…. [Thus] the chances are very high that recession will come before there is room to cut rates enough to offset it. The knowledge that this is the case must surely reduce confidence….

The unresolved question that will hang over the economy is how policy can delay and ultimately contain the next recession. It demands urgent attention from fiscal as well as monetary policymakers.

The Keynes quote, from the General Theory:

If effective demand is deficient… the individual enterpriser who seeks to bring… resources into action is operating with the odds loaded against him. The game of hazard which he plays is furnished with many zeros…. Hitherto the increment to the world’s wealth has fallen short of the aggregate of positive individual savings; and the different eras been made up by the losses of those whose courage and initiative have not been supplemented by exceptional skill or unusual goo fortune. But if effective demand is adequate, average skill and average good fortune will be enough….

It is certain that the world will not much longer tolerate the unemployment which, apart from brief intervals of excitement, is associated… with present-day capitalistic individualism. But it may be possible by a right analysis of the problem to cure the disease while preserving efficiency and freedom…

Must-Read: Adam Posen: Some Big Changes in Macroeconomic Thinking from Lawrence Summers

Must-Read: Adam Posen: Some Big Changes in Macroeconomic Thinking from Lawrence Summers: “In the United States, since 1965, there has been a tripling of the non-employment rate…

…for men… 24 and 54… similar trends… elsewhere…. It is a real puzzle to observe simultaneously multi-year trends of rising non-employment of low-skilled workers and declining measured productivity growth. Either we need a new understanding, or one of these observed patterns is ill-founded or misleading…. Unless we can somehow transform that sustained lower demand for workers into the widespread leisure of the sort imagined by Keynes and some science fiction writers, with the income redistribution to support it, I would think this is very bad news for social stability and technological progress….

Unmeasured quality improvement… [the] fraction of the economy… [susceptible] has been rising, so the amount of mismeasurement (and therefore productivity understatement) would be rising…. [Thus] inflation is lower than even its currently low level–and that has the consequence that real interest rates are higher, so monetary policy at present is tighter… [and] farther away from its mandated inflation target…

Recessions in the OECD… in most cases the level of GDP is lower five to ten years afterward than any prerecession forecast or trend…. “The classic model of cyclical fluctuations… around the given trend is not the right model…. The preoccupation of macroeconomics should be on lower frequency fluctuations that have consequences over long periods of time….

Discussing… Abenomics’ results… I asked whether a message we should take from the Japanese experience is to avoid bad states of the economy at almost any cost…. [And] the very language we use to speak of business cycles, of trend growth rates, of recoveries of to those perhaps non-stationary trends, and so on–which reflects the underlying mental framework of most macroeconomists–would have to be rethought.

Intellectual broker: Secular stagnation vs. Ben Bernanke

Let me put here my first, much longer draft to what appeared on Project Syndicate: The Tragedy of Ben Bernanke


Ben Bernanke has published his memoir, The Courage to Act.

I am finding it difficult to read. I am finding it hard to read it as other than as a tragedy. It is the story of a man who found himself in a job for which he may well have been the best-prepared person in the world. Yet he soon found himself overmastered by the situation. And he fell and stayed well behind the curve in understanding what was going on.

Those of us with even some historical memory winced when, back in 2003, Robert Lucas flatly declared that the problem of depression-prevention had been solved “for all practical purposes, and has in fact been solved for many decades”. We remembered 1960s Council of Economic Advisers chairs Walter Heller and Arthur Okun saying much the same thing. Indeed, we remembered Irving Fisher in the 1920s saying much the same thing. Fisher’s hubris was followed by nemesis in the form of the Great Depression. Heller’s and Okun’s hubris was followed by nemesis in the form of the 1970s inflation. The joke was on Lucas.

But in a deeper sense the joke was on those of us who winced at Lucas–and also on the people of the North Atlantic. For, as we know, the economy since 2007 has not been a very funny joke the people of the North Atlantic.

Those of us with historical memory knew that the problem of preventing severe macro economic instability had not been solved. But even we believed that even sharp downturns would be transitory and short. Rapid recovery to full prosperity and the supply side-driven trend growth was all but guaranteed. Perhaps full prosperity could be delayed into an extended medium-run by actively-perverse and destabilizing government policies. Perhaps the full-prosperity equilibrium-restoring forces of the market would work quickly.

But they would work.

Indeed, back in 2000 it was Ben Bernanke who had written that central banks with sufficient will and drive could always, in the medium-run at least, restore full prosperity by themselves via quantitative easing. Simply print money and buy financial assets. Do so on a large-enough scale. People would expect that not all of the quantitative easing would be unwound. Thus people would have an incentive to use the extra money that had been printed to step up their spending. Even if the fraction of quantitative easing that thought permanent was small, and even if the incentive to spend was low, the central bank could do the job.

It is to Bernanke’s great credit that the shock of 2007-8 did not trigger another Great Depression. However, what came after was unexpectedly disappointing. Central banks in the North Atlantic–including Ben Bernanke’s central bank, the Federal Reserve–went well beyond the outer limits of what we had thought, back before 2008, would be the maximum necessary to restore full prosperity. And full prosperity continued and continues to elude us. Bernanke pushed the US monetary base up from $800 billion to $4 trillion–a five-fold increase, one that a naïve quantity theory of money would have seen as enough stimulus to create a 400% cumulative inflation. But that was not enough. And Bernanke found himself and his committee unwilling to take the next leap, and do another more-than-doubling to carry the monetary base up to $9 trillion. And so, by the last third of his tenure in office, he was reduced to begging in vain for fiscal-expansionary help closed-eared Congress, which refused. Some leading figures in the dominant Republican party made political hay by calling what he had done “almost treasonous”, and threatening, in the coded language applied a generation ago to civil rights and other agitators, to lynch him should he show up where he was not wanted.

So what went wrong? I have been thinking about this with mixed success, most recently for the Milken Institute Review. So let me try yet again to summarize:

As I understand Ben Bernanke’s perspective, he thinks that nothing fundamental went wrong. It is just that the medium-run it takes for aggressively-expansionary monetary policy to restore full prosperity has been artificially lengthened, and seems long to us indeed. Interventions by non-market–or perhaps it would be better to call them non-risk adjusted return maximizing–financial players have created a temporary global savings glut. Sovereign wealth funds for which loss aversion is key, the emerging-market rich seeing their positions in the North Atlantic as primarily insurance against political risk, and governments seeking to ensure freedom of action have pushed full-prosperity interest rates down substantially, and lengthened the medium-run it takes for shocks to dissipate. But, I believe Bernanke believes, these disturbances are ending. And so, if he were still running the Fed, he would think it appropriate to raise interest rates now.

An alternative view is held by the very sharp Ken Rogoff. He believes, I think, that Bernanke’s cardinal error was to focus on money when he should have been focusing on that. In our simple models which you focus son does not matter: when the money market is in full-prosperity equilibrium, the debt market is too. But in the real world a central bank and a broader government that focused not on expanding the stock of safe money but on buying back and inducing the writing-down of the stock of risky debt would have boosted private spending much more effectively and restored full prosperity much more quickly.

Yet a third possible view is that the Fed could have done it: if it had committed to a higher target inflation rate than 2%/year, and promised to do as much quantitative easing as needed to get to that target, it would have produced full prosperity without requiring anywhere near as much quantitative easing as has been, so far, undertaken without that favorable result.

And then there is fourth view, one that I associate with Larry Summers and Paul Krugman, that we have no warrant for believing that monetary policy can restore full prosperity not only not in the short-run, but not in the medium-run and probably not even in the long-run. As Krugman put it most recently:

In 1998… I envisaged an economy in which the… natural rate of interest… would return to a normal, positive level… [and so] the liquidity trap became a [monetary-]expectations problem… monetary policy would be effective if it had the right kind of credibility…. [But if] a negative Wicksellian [natural] rate… permanent… [then] if nobody believes that inflation will rise, it won’t. The only way to be at all sure… [is] with a burst of fiscal stimulus…

Their position is, after a long detour through the post-World War II neoclassical-Keynesian synthesis, a return to a position set out by John Maynard Keynes in 1936:

It seems unlikely that the influence of [monetary] policy on the rate of interest will be sufficient by itself…. I conceive, therefore, but a somewhat comprehensive socialization of investment will prove the only means the securing an approximation to full employment; though this not need exclude all manner of compromises and of devices by which the public authority will cooperate with private initiative…

The government, that is, will have to be infrastructure-builder, risk-absorber, safe debt-issuer, debt workout-manager, and to a substantial degrees sectoral economic planner of last resort to maintain full prosperity. Milton Friedman’s dream that strategic interventions by the central bank in the quantity of high-powered money would then be just that—a dream. And our confusion, and the attractiveness of Milton Friedman’s monetarism in the half-century starting with a World War II would be an accident of the particular circumstances of the uniquely rapid North Atlantic-wide demographic and productivity growth of the transient post World War II era.

I cannot claim—we cannot claim—to know whether Bernanke he will Rogoff or Krugman and Summers are correct here, or even weather if Bernanke he and his committee had found the nerve, and rolled double-or-nothing one more time to boost the American high-powered money stock to $9 trillion, we might have been back to full prosperity a couple of years ago. But I do think that the debate over this question is the most important debate within macroeconomics since the debate—strangely, a very similar debate, at least with respect to its policy substance—that John Maynard Keynes had with himself in the decade around 1930 that turned him from a monetarist into a Keynesian.


Intellectual Broker: (Trying to) Make Sense of Current (Small) Analytical Disagreements Between Paul Krugman and Larry Summers: Where Is the Can Opener?

Larry Summers tweets:

David Wessel picks it up:

And I attempt to Twittersplain, with how much success I do not know:

Larry Summers: Where Paul Krugman and I differ on secular stagnation and demand: “Paul Krugman suggests that I have had some kind of change of heart on secular stagnation…

…and converged towards his point of view…. I certainly appreciate the gravity of the secular stagnation issue more than I did…. But I think Paul exaggerates the change in my views considerably. The topic… was: ‘North America faces a Japan-style era of high unemployment and low growth.’ Paul argued in favor. I opposed the motion–not on the grounds that the US economy was in good shape, but on the grounds that our demand deficiency problems should be easier to solve than Japan’s… [because] it is dimensionally much less than the problems that Japan faced in four respects. Japan’s problems were different in magnitude, different in the depth of their structural roots, different in the… perspective… relative to the rest of the world… different in the degree of resilience [of] their system…. Paul responded in part by saying:

The question is, are we going to be stuck in a state of depressed demand of the kind that Larry has talked about. Larry and I agree that that is what has been happening… I think Larry and I agree almost entirely on the economics, on what needs to be done….

I think we have both been focused on demand and the liquidity trap for a long time. There are, though, two areas where I have had somewhat different views from Paul. I believe that structural issues are often important for demand and growth…. Second, I have never related well to Paul’s celebrated liquidity trap analysis. It has always seemed to me be a classic example of economists’ tendency to ‘assume a can opener’. Paul studies an economy in liquidity trap that will, by deus ex machina, be lifted out at some point in the future. He makes the point that if you assume sufficiently inflationary policy after this point, you can drive ex ante real rates down enough to stimulate the economy even before the deus ex machina moment.

This is true and an important insight. But it seems to elide the main issue. Where is the deus ex machina? Where is the can opener? The essence of the secular stagnation and hysteresis ideas that I have been pushing is that there is no assurance that capitalist economies, when plunged into downturn, will over any interval revert to what had been normal. Understanding this phenomenon and responding to it seems the central challenge for macroeconomics in this era. Any analysis that assumes restoration of previous equilibrium is, from this perspective, missing the main issue. I was glad to see Paul recognize this point recently.  I suspect it will lead to more emphasis on fiscal rather than monetary actions in depressed economies.

Paul Krugman: Liquidity Traps, Temporary and Permanent: “Larry Summers reacts to an offhand post of mine, seeking to draw a distinction between our views…

…I actually don’t think our views differ significantly now, but he’s right that what he has been saying differs from the approach I took way back in 1998. And I’ve both acknowledged that and admitted that the approach I took then seems inadequate now…. Japan now looks like an economy in which a negative natural rate is a more or less permanent condition. So, increasingly, does Europe. And the US may be in the same boat, if only because persistent weakness abroad will lead to a strong dollar, and we will end up importing demand weakness. And if we are in a world of secular stagnation–of more or less permanent negative natural rates–policy becomes even harder.

And I commented on Paul’s webpage thus: But, as I was tweeting to David Wessel, you scorn the Confidence Fairy while having some hope for the Inflation-Expectations Imp, while he scorns the Inflation-Expectations Imp but has some hope for the Confidence Fairy, no? And he has more hope for pump-priming small fiscal expansion to trigger virtuous circles and give the economy escape velocity, no? Small differences relative to those of the two of you vis-a-vis Rogoff, Mankiw, Feldstein, Bernanke, and, I think, even Blanchard. But differences, no?…