Things to Read on the Morning of August 14, 2015

Must- and Should-Reads:

Might Like to Be Aware of:

Must-Read: Ezra Klein (2014): The Home Page Isn’t Dead. It’s Just Resting

Must-Read: Ezra Klein (2014): The Home Page Isn’t Dead. It’s Just Resting: “The home page… is becoming the way your power users find the content…

…to share with your casual users…. [That] will likely change the way we build and curate home pages…. Medium… demanded my Twitter information before I could log in, and now the homepage I see there is full of things my friends have liked, or in some cases written–and that means I’m a lot likelier to share it…. Quartz’s designs makes every page… a mini home page. Readers… come in any door… but… still find themselves… [in] the living room….The home page, after all, is one of the last spaces that publishers actually control, and that committed readers reliably frequent. It’d be crazy to let it die.

What Rates of Economic Growth Could Better Economic Policy Produce Over an Eight-Year Presidential Term?

The rate of growth of U.S. economic potential is currently something like 2.4%/year. The 1/e time for the economy’s convergence to its long-run steady-state growth path is roughly twenty years–that is, the economy will close roughly 5% of the gap between its current potential and its long-run steady-state growth path a year. A huge institutional reform–one that was completely successful, and had a much broader impact than an ObamaCare–that raised the long-run productivity of the American economy by 20% would thus raise the growth rate over a president’s tenure in office from 2.4% to 3.4%. And that is far outside what we can expect to follow from any set of even the most far-reaching and successful changes in policy.

For unreasonably optimistic assessments of the benefits of the FAIR tax, I believe the boost to growth is 0.2%-points per year.

Thus over at Twitter, Justin Wolfers and others:

Must-Attend: George Evans, Roger Guesnerie, Bruce McGough and Bruce Preston: content/uploads/sites/4/2015/08/ConfProgram-2015.pdf”>Expectations in Dynamic Macroeconomic Models

Must-Attend (if you are in Oregon, that is): Up in Eugene they have long been doing a great deal of work on expectations and the stability of stochastic equilibrium that is genuinely useful. And have I ever said that I was first taught about equilibrium stability by Roger Guesnerie in the fall of 1979? There are probably smart things I could use to impress people in my Econ 2001a notes, if I could find the basement box that they are in. Mark Thoma tells us about:

George Evans, Roger Guesnerie, Bruce McGough and Bruce Preston: Expectations in Dynamic Macroeconomic Models: “Cars Hommes… Behavioral Learning Equilibria for the New Keynesian Model; Discussant: George Waters…

…Jasmina Arifovic… Escaping Expectations-Driven Liquidity Traps; Discussant: John Duffy. Bill Branch… Perpetual Learning and Stability in Macroeconomic Models; Discussant: Cars Hommes. Mordecai Kurz, Stabilizing Wage Policy; Discussant: George Evans. Diogo Pinheiro… Refinement of Dynamic Equilibrium; Discussant: Bruce McGough. Arunima Sinha… A Lesson from the Great Depression that the Fed Might have Learned: A Comparison of the 1932 Open Market Purchases with Quantitative Easing; Discussant: Vasco Curdia…. James Bullard….

Damjan Pfajfar… Are Survey Expectations Theory-Consistent? The Role of Central Bank Communication and News; Discussant: Fernanda Nechio. Stefano Eusepi… In Search of a Nominal Anchor: What Drives Inflation Expectations? Discussant: Sergey Slobodyan. In-Koo Cho… Gresham’s Law of Model Averaging; Discussant: Noah Williams. Martin Ellison… Time-Consistent Institutional Design; Discussant: Sergio Santoro. Klaus Adam… Can a Financial Transaction Tax Prevent Stock Price Booms?; Discussant: Pei Kuang. Kevin Lansing… Explaining the Boom-Bust Cycle in the US Housing Market: A Reverse-Engineering Approach; Discussant: Paul Shea. Thomas Sargent… Sets of Models and Prices of Uncertainty….

David Evans… Optimal Taxation with Persistent Idiosyncratic Investment Risk; Discussant: Max Croce. Anmol Bhandari… Fiscal policy and debt management with incomplete markets; Discussant: Kenneth Kasa. Chris Gibbs… Disinflationary Policies with Imperfect Credibility; Discussant: Eric Gaus. Kaushik Mitra… Comparing Inflation and Price Level Targeting: the Role of Forward Guidance and Transparency; Discussant: Bruce Preston.

That Friedrich von Hayek Was Inconsistent and That Milton Friedman Was Running a Con on His Ideological Allies Are Not to Their Benefit: Hoisted from the Archives from Two Years Ago

Two years ago today we noted Daniel Keuhn saying smart things about Friedrich von Hayek and Paul Krugman saying smart things about Milton Friedman. Keuhn’s major point was that Hayek is inconsistent and incoherent on both macroeconomic political economy issues, and we should recognize that incoherence. Krugman’s is that Friedman’s the-market-is-perfect-except-we-need-a-k%-money-growth-rule is deeply incoherent. Both are very smart points, but…

I do give Hayek much less credit than Daniel does for the times when he says the proper monetary policy is to stabilize the nominal level of total spending. In my view that position is, while not as bad as liquidationism, also batshit-insane. It calls for the overall price level to fall at a rate equal to the sum of population and productivity growth. It calls for nominal wages to fall as rapidly as the labor force increases? In the real world we live in, why would anybody want that?

The reason Hayek gives seems to be that… well, actually, there are no coherent reasons.

And the really existing Hayek deployed today is not the stabilize nominal GDP on its pre-2007 trend path Hayek. It is the liquidationist Hayek.

I think that Krugman overstates the inconsistency when he says that: “if markets can go so wrong that they cause Great Depressions, how can you be a free-market true believer on everything except macro?” It is possible, after all, that the vulnerability of the market economy to Great Depressions is its only major market failure. That is unlikely, but it could be the way that world is. Because it is unlikely, it is a hard position to argue for. But you can argue for it.

Daniel Kuehn Smacks Down Larry White: That Friedrich von Hayek Was Not Consistent or Coherent Does Not Redound to His Benefit: “Hayek said liquidationist things and he said stable nominal income things…

…and the latter do not erase the former. Larry White has a very odd response up to Paul Krugman…. White makes a great argument that Hayek said he wanted to stabilize MV…. [Hayek] also made alarmingly liquidationist statements. I hate this tendency to act like people are dummies because of Hayek’s inconsistency or the tendency to act like because Hayek said X on Tuesday it means he didn’t say Y on Friday. The latter absolutely does not follow from the former. It’s hard to get around this: ‘…if we pass from the moment of actual crisis to the situation in the following depression, it is still more difficult to see what lasting good effects can come from credit expansion.’…

You see this with Road to Serfdom too… [so] I… [am] tuning out of any posts about the book. Farrant and McPhail do a really masterful job on this one taking down the Caldwell/Boettke position by pointing out that–as with the MV stabilization/liquidationist issue–Hayek did indeed make strong slippery slope arguments sometimes and didn’t at other times. The Caldwell/Boettke camp usually responds to this by pointing out the times that Hayek wasn’t making the strong slippery slope arguments. But that… only demonstrates that Hayek was highly inconsistent!…

People are allowed to change their minds, and… be careless with words…. What bothers me….

  • Larry White treating Krugman like he’s being intellectually lazy for pointing out that Hayek was clearly a promoter of liquidationism… and
  • The failure to recognize that this seems to be a particularly common problem with Hayek. You wouldn’t get liquidationism jumbled up together with anti-liquidationism in Keynes or Friedman…. But you do with Hayek…. If we still can’t agree on the message of the Road to Serfdom or… the interwar macro work… the obvious conclusion is not that Krugman is a dummy–but that Hayek was all over the map. And it seems to me it’s reasonable to assume he is culpable for being all over the map…

Paul Krugman: The Eclipse of Milton Friedman: “Friedman’s larger problem… is… he was…

…a man trying to straddle two competing world views… an avid free-market advocate, who insisted that the market, left to itself, could solve almost any problem… [and] also a macroeconomic realist, who recognized that the market definitely did not solve the problem of recessions and depressions. So he tried to wall off macroeconomics… and make it… inoffensive to laissez-faire sensibilities…. We do need stabilization policy–but we can minimize the government’s role by relying only on monetary policy… and then not even allowing the monetary authority any discretion.

At a fundamental level, however, this was an inconsistent position: if markets can go so wrong that they cause Great Depressions, how can you be a free-market true believer on everything except macro? And as American conservatism moved ever further right, it had no room for any kind of interventionism…. So Friedman has vanished from the policy scene–so much so that I suspect that a few decades from now, historians of economic thought will regard him as little more than an extended footnote.

Friedman’s problem with the right–and the reason for his effective banishment by the right from the intellectual scene today–is not so much a logical problem as a rhetorical problem. People who believe the market is perfect can on a rhetorical level accept the proviso “…as long as you maintain a neutral monetary policy which is easily to calculate and automatic”. They cannot accept the proviso “…as long as the central bank and the government juggle enough balls well enough to make Say’s Law true in practice even though it is false in theory”.

But do you know who else thought that the market was perfect as long as the central bank and the government juggle enough balls well enough to make Say’s Law true in practice even though it is false in theory? No, this time the answer to the “do you know who else?” question is not Adolf Hitler:

John Maynard Keynes: The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money by John Maynard Keynes: “If the State is able to determine the aggregate amount…

…of resources devoted to augmenting the instruments and the basic rate of reward to those who own them, it will have accomplished all that is necessary…. Our criticism of the accepted classical theory of economics has consisted… in pointing out that its tacit assumptions are seldom or never satisfied, with the result that it cannot solve the economic problems of the actual world. But if… [the] aggregate volume of output correspond[s]… to full employment as nearly as is practicable, the classical theory comes into its own…. Then there is no objection to be raised against the classical analysis of the manner in which private self-interest will determine what in particular is produced, in what proportions the factors of production will be combined to produce it, and how the value of the final product will be distributed… no objection to… the modern classical theory as to the degree of consilience between private and public advantage in conditions of perfect and imperfect competition respectively… no more reason to socialise economic life than there was before….

When 9,000,000 men are employed out of 10,000,000 willing and able to work, there is no evidence that the labour of these 9,000,000 men is misdirected. The complaint against the present system is not that these 9,000,000 men ought to be employed on different tasks, but that tasks should be available for the remaining 1,000,000 men. It is in determining the volume, not the direction, of actual employment that the existing system has broken down. Thus I agree with Gesell that the result of filling in the gaps in the classical theory is not to dispose of the ‘Manchester System’, but to indicate the nature of the environment which the free play of economic forces requires if it is to realise the full potentialities of production…. There will still remain a wide field for the exercise of private initiative and responsibility. Within this field the traditional advantages of individualism will still hold good.

Let us stop for a moment to remind ourselves what these advantages are. They are partly advantages of efficiency — the advantages of decentralisation and of the play of self-interest. The advantage to efficiency of the decentralisation of decisions and of individual responsibility is even greater, perhaps, than the nineteenth century supposed; and the reaction against the appeal to self-interest may have gone too far. But, above all, individualism, if it can be purged of its defects and its abuses, is the best safeguard of personal liberty in the sense that, compared with any other system, it greatly widens the field for the exercise of personal choice. It is also the best safeguard of the variety of life, which emerges precisely from this extended field of personal choice, and the loss of which is the greatest of all the losses of the homogeneous or totalitarian state. For this variety preserves the traditions which embody the most secure and successful choices of former generations; it colours the present with the diversification of its fancy; and, being the handmaid of experiment as well as of tradition and of fancy, it is the most powerful instrument to better the future.

Whilst, therefore, the enlargement of the functions of government, involved in the task of adjusting to one another the propensity to consume and the inducement to invest, would seem to a nineteenth-century publicist or to a contemporary American financier to be a terrific encroachment on individualism. I defend it, on the contrary, both as the only practicable means of avoiding the destruction of existing economic forms in their entirety and as the condition of the successful functioning of individual initiative.

For if effective demand is deficient, not only is the public scandal of wasted resources intolerable, but the individual enterpriser who seeks to bring these resources into action is operating with the odds loaded against him. The game of hazard which he plays is furnished with many zeros, so that the players as a whole will lose if they have the energy and hope to deal all the cards. Hitherto the increment of the world’s wealth has fallen short of the aggregate of positive individual savings; and the difference has been made up by the losses of those whose courage and initiative have not been supplemented by exceptional skill or unusual good fortune. But if effective demand is adequate, average skill and average good fortune will be enough.

The authoritarian state systems of today seem to solve the problem of unemployment at the expense of efficiency and of freedom. It is certain that the world will not much longer tolerate the unemployment which, apart from brief intervals of excitement, is associated and in my opinion, inevitably associated with present-day capitalistic individualism. But it may be possible by a right analysis of the problem to cure the disease whilst preserving efficiency and freedom.

I have mentioned in passing that the new system might be more favourable to peace than the old has been. It is worth while to repeat and emphasise that aspect.

War has several causes. Dictators and others such, to whom war offers, in expectation at least, a pleasurable excitement, find it easy to work on the natural bellicosity of their peoples. But, over and above this, facilitating their task of fanning the popular flame, are the economic causes of war, namely, the pressure of population and the competitive struggle for markets. It is the second factor, which probably played a predominant part in the nineteenth century, and might again, that is germane to this discussion.

I have pointed out in the preceding chapter that, under the system of domestic laissez-faire and an international gold standard such as was orthodox in the latter half of the nineteenth century, there was no means open to a government whereby to mitigate economic distress at home except through the competitive struggle for markets. For all measures helpful to a state of chronic or intermittent under-employment were ruled out, except measures to improve the balance of trade on income account.

Thus, whilst economists were accustomed to applaud the prevailing international system as furnishing the fruits of the international division of labour and harmonising at the same time the interests of different nations, there lay concealed a less benign influence; and those statesmen were moved by common sense and a correct apprehension of the true course of events, who believed that if a rich, old country were to neglect the struggle for markets its prosperity would droop and fail. But if nations can learn to provide themselves with full employment by their domestic policy (and, we must add, if they can also attain equilibrium in the trend of their population), there need be no important economic forces calculated to set the interest of one country against that of its neighbours.

There would still be room for the international division of labour and for international lending in appropriate conditions. But there would no longer be a pressing motive why one country need force its wares on another or repulse the offerings of its neighbour, not because this was necessary to enable it to pay for what it wished to purchase, but with the express object of upsetting the equilibrium of payments so as to develop a balance of trade in its own favour. International trade would cease to be what it is, namely, a desperate expedient to maintain employment at home by forcing sales on foreign markets and restricting purchases, which, if successful, will merely shift the problem of unemployment to the neighbour which is worsted in the struggle, but a willing and unimpeded exchange of goods and services in conditions of mutual advantage.

Must-Read: Melissa S. Kearney and Phillip B. Levine: Early Childhood Education by MOOC: Lessons from Sesame Street

Must-Read: Melissa S. Kearney and Phillip B. Levine: Early Childhood Education by MOOC: Lessons from Sesame Street: “Sesame Street… was introduced in 1969 as an educational, early childhood program…

…with the explicit goal of preparing preschool age children for school entry…. We investigate whether the first cohorts of preschool children exposed to Sesame Street experienced improved outcomes… [via] an instrumental variables strategy exploiting limitations in television technology generated by distance to a broadcast tower and UHF versus VHF transmission to distinguish counties by Sesame Street reception quality…. Sesame Street accomplished its goal of improving school readiness; preschool-aged children in areas with better reception when it was introduced were more likely to advance through school as appropriate for their age. This effect is particularly pronounced for boys and non-Hispanic, black children, as well as children living in economically disadvantaged areas…

Must-Read: Lawrence Summers (2013): Reconstructing Macroeconomics

Must-Read: The view was that there was no harm done in modeling the Phillips curve as linear–that the inflation cost of having unemployment below the natural rate by 1%-point was offset by an equal inflation benefit to having unemployment above the natural rate by 1%-point. And the view was that inflation expectations were not “rational” in the Lucas but that there was no harm in modeling them as adaptive. But these–as Larry and I tried to argue back in 1988, without notable success–together synergized into a huge mistake that did a lot of harm:

Larry Summers (2013): Reconstructing Macroeconomics: “There is a central question: Should we think of macroeconomics as being about…

…as it was thought about before Keynes, and came to be thought of again in the 1990s–cyclical fluctuations about a trend determined somewhere else, where the goal if you were successful was to reduce [the fluctuations’] amplitude; or as centrally about tragic accidents where millions of more people were unemployed for millions more person-years at costs of trillions of dollars in ways that were avoidable with more satisfactory economic arrangements. Unless and until we adopt the second view, I think we are missing what is our principal opportunity to engage in human betterment. And as long as the question is conceptualized as ‘what friction should we insert into the existing DSGE model and we will have it?’, I don’t think we will get to the kind of perspective that I am advocating. Now it is easy to say this, it is easy to say this. It is much harder to provide a constructive vision of just how to do it. But there are a number of schools of work that to date… have been… abstract… multiple equilibria, fragile equilibria, and so forth… [that I think] have … [the] notion that… you have a very bad outcome that you somehow could have avoided without compromising the future…. It really is true that a little bit of avoiding what has happened over the past six years is worth a lot of making the amplitude of fluctuations around trend smaller. It seems hard to observe the past six years, which did not in fact achieve that much disinflation, and not think that it should somehow have been possible to avoid that waste.

Must-Read: Paul Krugman: The M.I.T. Gang

Must-Read: It is indeed very gratifying at some level to look back and recognize that my macro economics teachers in Cambridge in the early 1980s have indeed helped me to understand the world. What is not so gratifying is how limited they reach and their influence has been. It was not George W. Bush but, rather, Barack Obama who said in January 2010–wholly inappropriately–that:

families across the country are tightening their belts and making tough decisions. The federal government should do the same. (Applause.) So tonight, I’m proposing specific steps to pay for the trillion dollars that it took to rescue the economy last year…. Starting in 2011, we are prepared to freeze government spending for three years. Spending related to our national security, Medicare, Medicaid, and Social Security will not be affected. But all other discretionary government programs will. Like any cash-strapped family, we will work within a budget to invest in what we need and sacrifice what we don’t. And if I have to enforce this discipline by veto, I will…

It wasn’t Hank Paulson, but Tim Geithner of whom Zach Goldfarb reported:

Once, as Romer pressed for more stimulus spending, Geithner snapped. Stimulus, he told Romer, was “sugar,” and its effect was fleeting. The administration, he urged, needed to focus on long-term economic growth, and the first step was reining in the debt. Wrong, Romer snapped back. Stimulus is an “antibiotic” for a sick economy, she told Geithner. “It’s not giving a child a lollipop.” In the end, Obama signed into law only a relatively modest $13 billion jobs program, much less than what was favored by Romer and many other economists in the administration. “There was this move to exit fiscal stimulus a lot sooner than we should have, and we’ve been playing catch-up ever since,” Romer said in an interview…

Return heard some things from Peter Orszag about how he misjudged the situation and appropriate fiscal policy in 2010 and after. We have heard nothing from Tim Geithner, from Jack Lew, or from Barack Obama.

Paul Krugman: The M.I.T. Gang: “showed how small deviations from perfect rationality…

…can have large economic consequences; Mr. Obstfeld showed that currency markets can sometimes experience self-fulfilling panic. This open-minded, pragmatic approach was overwhelmingly vindicated after crisis struck in 2008. Chicago-school types warned incessantly that responding to the crisis by printing money and running deficits would lead to 70s-type stagflation, with soaring inflation and interest rates. But M.I.T. types predicted, correctly, that inflation and interest rates would stay low in a depressed economy, and that attempts to slash deficits too soon would deepen the slump. The truth, although nobody will believe it, is that the economic analysis some of us learned at M.I.T. way back when has worked very, very well for the past seven years….

There have been some important monetary successes. The Fed, led by Mr. Bernanke, ignored right-wing pressure and threats–Rick Perry, as governor of Texas, went so far as to accuse him of treason–and pursued an aggressively expansionary policy that helped limit the damage from the financial crisis. In Europe, Mr. Draghi’s activism has been crucial to calming financial markets, probably saving the euro from collapse.

On other fronts, however, the M.I.T. gang’s good advice has been ignored. The I.M.F.’s research department, under Mr. Blanchard’s leadership, has done authoritative work on the effects of fiscal policy, demonstrating beyond any reasonable doubt that slashing spending in a depressed economy is a terrible mistake, and that attempts to reduce high levels of debt via austerity are self-defeating. But European politicians have slashed spending and demanded crippling austerity from debtors anyway. Meanwhile, in the United States, Republicans have responded to the utter failure of free-market orthodoxy and the remarkably successful predictions of much-hated Keynesians by digging in even deeper, determined to learn nothing from experience….

Being right isn’t necessarily enough to change the world. But it’s still better to be right than to be wrong, and M.I.T.-style economics, with its pragmatic openness to evidence, has been very right indeed.

Puerto Rico’s predicaments: Is its minimum wage the culprit?

Puerto Rico today faces a serious debt crisis, recently defaulting on a bond payment. The proximate cause is a slowdown in economic growth since the mid-2000s, which has reduced tax revenues, and a declining labor market, where employment growth has been mostly in the red since 2007.

Figure 1

puerto-rico-fig-01

There are many explanations for the economic downturn and the resulting fiscal crisis, but some commentators have incorrectly blamed the island’s high minimum wage. To be sure, the federal minimum wage—which has applied to Puerto Rico since 1983—is much more binding there than it is on the mainland. Because hourly wages are substantially lower in Puerto Rico compared to the U.S. mainland, the federal minimum wage policy affects more of the workforce there. In 2014, for example, the federal minimum wage stood at 77 percent of the median hourly wage in Puerto Rico, compared to 42 percent in the United States. For comparability with existing estimates, if we consider wages of full time workers only, these figures are approximately 70 percent in Puerto Rico and 38 percent in the United States, respectively. Finally, the minimum wage stands at 56 percent of the wage earned by production workers in manufacturing, compared to 38 percent in the United States. Clearly, the Puerto Rico’s minimum wage exceeds the cautious rule-of-thumb of 50 percent of median wage of full-time workers suggested by one of us in previous work.

But does that make it a probable culprit for the island’s current debt and economic troubles? The short answer is: not very likely. The major problem with a minimum wage-centric explanation is timing. There has been no change in the relative minimum wage between Puerto Rico and the mainland over the past 32 years. And since the federal standard has not kept up with wage growth on the island, the bite of the minimum wage in Puerto Rico has eroded over this period.

First, the current inflation-adjusted value of the federal minimum wage is not higher than it was when Puerto Rico first adopted it. Puerto Rico’s minimum wage is worth slightly less today than in 1983, even though its economy, in terms of GDP per capita, has grown by 72 percent.

Second, real wages in Puerto Rico were lower three decades ago. As a result, if we measure the bite of the minimum wage as the ratio of the minimum wage to the average manufacturing wage, the bite was closer to 70 percent when Puerto Rico first adopted the federal minimum wage, much higher than it is today, at 53 percent. (We use the manufacturing wage for this comparison because the median wage series is not available over as long a historical period, to the best of our knowledge.)

Figure 2

puerto-rico-fig-02

Additional evidence suggests the current minimum wage in Puerto Rico is also less consequential today than it was during the 1980s. In 1983 the share of Puerto Rico’s workers affected by the minimum wage was around 44 percent, but by 2010 this share had fallen to around a third. It is difficult to explain the economic crisis in Puerto Rico starting in the mid-2000s with a minimum wage that is, if anything, on the wane.

Finally, we should note that some recent reports have also incorrectly measured the level of the minimum wage in Puerto Rico, stating that a full-time minimum wage worker in Puerto Rico earns 77 percent of the nation’s per capita income, as opposed to 28 percent in the United States. Data from the World Bank suggests that although the ratio of 28 percent is correct for the mainland, the statistic for Puerto Rico is closer to 53 percent as of 2013, the last year in which complete data are available.

Does this mean the island’s minimum wage has no negative consequences? It’s possible that the minimum wage led to somewhat lower levels of employment than would otherwise occur. After all, the minimum wage is much higher in Puerto Rico than the kind of increases we have studied elsewhere in the United States, where we find employment effects that are small and often indistinguishable from zero.

But clear evidence of job losses due to Puerto Rico’s relatively high minimum wage remains elusive. The two main scholarly papers on the topic reach different conclusions when analyzing the original Puerto Rican introduction of the federal minimum wage in 1983. In their 1992 paper, “When the Minimum Wage Really Bites: The Effect of the U.S. Level Minimum on Puerto Rico,” economists Alida Castillo-Freeman at the National Bureau of Economic Research and Richard Freeman at Harvard University found evidence of moderate-sized job losses by comparing unemployment trends over time, and by comparing wages and employment across industries on the island.

Yet in a careful reanalysis of the same data in 1994, Princeton University economist Alan Krueger found that some of the findings by Castillo-Freeman and Freeman proved fragile. One case in point: the more negative estimates from cross-industry comparisons were in part driven by the over-representation of many narrow manufacturing industries in their sample. And there was some indication of the effects occurring, implausibly, prior to the actual increases in the minimum wage. Finally, while some of the episodes of minimum-wage increases on the island were associated with higher unemployment, the opposite was true during other episodes.

Control groups for the Puerto Rican case are not easy to find, and so it is difficult to decipher what would have happened if the minimum wage in Puerto Rico were much lower. But, while there may be disagreement on whether the Puerto Rico’s minimum wage has caused the unemployment rate to be somewhat higher, both Professors Freeman and Krueger are in complete agreement today that it is unlikely either to be a major factor behind the current economic crisis, or an important part of the solution.

Indeed, the long-run decline in the bite of the minimum wage presents a serious challenge for those arguing otherwise, since the timing of the crisis is inconsistent with minimum wage having played a real role in it. Reasonable people may differ on the costs and benefits of applying the federal minimum wage to Puerto Rico. But it would be misguided to expect minimum wage policy to provide a cure for the island’s ailments.

Arindrajit Dube is an associate professor of economics at the University of Massachuetts-Amherst. Ben Zipperer is an economist at the Washington Center for Equitable Growth.