Monday DeLong Smackdown: Trying and Failing to Get in Touch with My Inner Austrian Back in 2004…

That I never figured out how to write this paper is deserving of a smackdown. Why did I never figure out how to write it? Because I never figured out what to say, or what the answer was:

Hoisted from 2004: Getting in Touch with My Inner Austrian: A Still-Unwritten Paper: Fragment of an Unfinished Ms.: Part II of an unfinished paper, “After the Bubble.” The paper currently lacks Parts I, III, IV, V, and VI:

II. Aggressively Expansionary Monetary Policy and Macroeconomic Vulnerabilities:

Let us begin with a passage from Mussa (2004), “Global Economic Prospects: Bright for 2004 but with Questions Thereafter” (Washington: Institute for International Economics: April 1), in which Michael Mussa writes about global financial imbalances:

Michael Mussa: Policy interest rates are exceptionally low in most industrial countries: zero in Japan and Switzerland, 1 percent in the United States, 2 percent in the euro area, and at or near historic lows in the United Kingdom and Canada…. The very low level of policy interest rates is an imbalance (relative to normal conditions) that reflects exceptionally easy monetary policies to combat economic weakness.

This policy imbalance poses an important challenge for the future conduct of monetary policy. Situations of low policy interest rates and low inflation tend to be associated with unusual inertia in the processes of general price inflation, which makes traditional indicators of rising inflationary pressures less reliable as measures of the need to begin to tighten monetary conditions. Also, these situations tend to be associated with high valuations of equities, real estate, and long-term bonds, which can become fertile ground for large, unsustainable increases in asset prices. In this situation, if monetary policy is tightened too much too soon (perhaps because of worries about unsustainable increases in asset prices), the result can be an unnecessary asset market crunch and economic slowdown, and monetary policy may have relatively little room to ease in order to counteract this outcome.

On the other hand, if monetary policy remains too easy for too long (perhaps because subdued general price inflation gives no clear signal of the need for monetary tightening), then large asset price anomalies may develop before corrective action is taken. The monetary authority would then confront the grim choice of trying to keep an unsustainable asset price bubble alive or trying to combat the collapse of such a bubble without a great deal of room for monetary easing.

A further concern related to the general monetary policy imbalance in the industrial countries is its effect on emerging market economies. Interest rate spreads for emerging market borrowers have contracted substantially and flows of new credit have increased. The boom in emerging market credit has not yet reached the frenzy of the first half of 1997, but it is headed in that direction. Another major series of emerging market financial crises (such as 1997-99) does not seem likely in the near term in view of the very low level of industrial country interest rates and the favorable global economic environment for emerging market countries. By 2005 or 2006, however, either upward movements in industrial country interest rates or deterioration of market perceptions of the economic and financial stability of some emerging market countries could trigger another round of crises.

Mussa is warning that the high asset prices produced by very low interest rates pose dangers that may turn out to be substantial. One way to read Mussa’s warning is as a polite–a very polite–criticism of Alan Greenspan’s self-praise of his own low interest-rate policy contained in Greenspan (2004), “Risk and Uncertainty in Monetary Policy” (Washington: Federal Reserve Board: January 3):

Alan Greenspan: Perhaps the greatest irony of the past decade is that… success against inflation… contributed to the stock price bubble …. Fed policymakers were confronted with forces that none of us had previously encountered. Aside from the then-recent experience of Japan, only remote historical episodes gave us clues to the appropriate stance for policy under such conditions. The sharp rise in stock prices and their subsequent fall were, thus, an especial challenge to the Federal Reserve. It is far from obvious that bubbles, even if identified early, can be preempted at lower cost than a substantial economic contraction and possible financial destabilization–the very outcomes we would be seeking to avoid…. The notion that a well-timed incremental tightening could have been calibrated to prevent the late 1990s bubble while preserving economic stability is almost surely an illusion.

Instead of trying to contain a putative bubble by drastic actions with largely unpredictable consequences, we chose, as we noted in our mid-1999 congressional testimony, to focus on policies “to mitigate the fallout when it occurs and, hopefully, ease the transition to the next expansion.”

During 2001, in the aftermath of the bursting of the bubble and the acts of terrorism in September 2001, the federal funds rate was lowered 4-3/4 percentage points. Subsequently, another 75 basis points were pared, bringing the rate by June 2003 to its current 1 percent, the lowest level in 45 years. We were able to be unusually aggressive in the initial stages of the recession of 2001 because both inflation and inflation expectations were low and stable. We thought we needed to be, and could be, forceful in 2002 and 2003 as well because, with demand weak, inflation risks had become two-sided for the first time in forty years.

There appears to be enough evidence, at least tentatively, to conclude that our strategy of addressing the bubble’s consequences rather than the bubble itself has been successful. Despite the stock market plunge, terrorist attacks, corporate scandals, and wars in Afghanistan and Iraq, we experienced an exceptionally mild recession–even milder than that of a decade earlier. As I discuss later, much of the ability of the U.S. economy to absorb these sequences of shocks resulted from notably improved structural flexibility. But highly aggressive monetary ease was doubtless also a significant contributor to stability…

Greenspan is confident that raising interest rates and thus raising the unemployment rate during the bubble of the late 1990s would have been the wrong policy, and that aggressively lowering interest rates after the bubble was the right policy. Lowering interest rates cushioned falls in bond prices. Lowering interest rates made use of bond financing for investment more attractive. Lowering interest rates boosted bond and real estate prices, induced households to refinance, and so provided a powerful spur to consumption spending that largely offset the post-bubble fall in investment spending. In Greenspan’s view, the aggressive lowering ofinterest rates was exactly the right thing to do in the aftermath of the bubble to shift spending from investment to consumption and so to keep the economy not far from full employment.

Mussa says: not so fast. Very low interest rates, coupled with assurances from high Federal Reserve officials that interest rates will stay very low for substantial periods of time, produce a situation in which the prices of long-duration assets—long-term bonds, growth stocks, and real estate—climb very high. What goes up may come down, and may come down rapidly. And should some class of asset prices come down rapidly and should it turn out that many debtors in the economy go bankrupt because their assets have lost value, serious financial crisis will result. The price of using exceptionally easy money to keep the collapse of the dot-com bubble from turning into a depression has been the creation of a three-fold vulnerability:

  1. If the assets the prices of which collapse when interest rates start to rise are emerging-market debt, then the memories of the 1990s and increasing risk will induce large-scale capital flight from the periphery to the core—an echo of the East Asian financial crises of 1997-1998.

  2. If the assets the prices of which threaten collapse when interest rates start to rise are domestic bond and real estate holdings that have been pushed to unsustainable levels by positive-feedback “bubble” buying, then the “monetary authority would… confront the grim choice of trying to keep an unsustainable asset price bubble alive or trying to combat the collapse of such a bubble without a great deal of room for monetary easing” to keep real estate and bond prices from falling far and fast.

  3. “If monetary policy is tightened too much too soon” (presumably because of fears of positive-feedback “bubble” buying), the result may be a credit crunch and a recession—with no guarantee that a reversal of the monetary policy tightening will undue the effects of the credit crunch. I do not believe that many economists would say that Mussa’s fears about the potential macroeconomic vulnerabilities created by the low interest-rate policy the Federal Reserve has pursued since the end of the dot-com bubble are unreasonable. (Few, however, carry their alarm to the degree that Stephen Roach of Morgan Stanley does.)

And Mussa expresses them in a coherent language—one in which sustained rises in asset prices induce positive-feedback trading that “bubbles” prices above fundamentals, one in which what goes up comes down rapidly, one in which large sudden falls in asset prices produce chains of bankruptcy and raise risk and default premia enough to threaten to cause deep recessions. The language has echoes of the great Charles P. Kindleberger’s (1978) Manias, Panics, and Crashes (New York: Basic Books), and of earlier writings about the consequences of excessive money-printing: “inflation, revulsion, and discredit.”

But what Mussa’s assessment of risks lacks is a model. And without a model, we have a hard time assessing his argument. Alan Greenspan frightened away the Evil Depression Fairy in 2000-2002 by promising not that he would let the Evil Fairy marry his daughter but by promising high asset prices—unsustainably high asset prices—for a while. Whether this was a good trade or not depends on the relative values of the risks avoided and the risks accepted. And to evaluate this requires a model of some sort…


References:

Alan Greenspan (2004), “Risk and Uncertainty in Monetary Policy” (Washington: Federal Reserve Board: January 3).

Michael Mussa (2004), “Global Economic Prospects: Bright for 2004 but with Questions Thereafter” (Washington: Institute for International Economics: April 1)…”

Must-Read: Dylan Matthews: You’re not imagining it: the rich really are hoarding economic growth

Must-Read: As I repeatedly say, people are spending a lot of time on their cellphones and such doing things that would have been very expensive or impossible back in 1980. That doesn’t speak to the distributional point at all—the rich (at least the young rich) benefit more from cheap electronic devices not just by being able to afford more of them but because they are information-age force multipliers for how to better spend your money. But it does speak to the average growth point:

Dylan Matthews: You’re not imagining it: the rich really are hoarding economic growth: “With… ‘distributional national accounts’… exactly where economic growth is going…

…and how much each group is seeing its income rise relative to the overall economy…. Saez, Piketty, and Zucman… answers basically all of the conservative critiques…. Incomes… employer-provided health care, pensions, and other benefits… taxes and government transfer programs… changes in income among adults, rather than households or tax units… the slower-growing inflation metric, rather than CPI. And what do they find? This:

The rich really are hoarding economic growth

Should-Read: Brink Lindsey and Steven Teles: The Captured Economy: How the Powerful Enrich Themselves, Slow Down Growth, and Increase Inequality

Should-Read: I would conceptualize this differently. It is not a “breakdown” of democratic governance that has allowed “wealthy special interests to capture the policymaking process”. Interests have always captured the policymaking process. (i) Sometimes these interests are broad coalitions interested in (progressive) redistribution. (ii) Sometimes these interests are (narrower) interests interested in promoting entrepreneurship, enterprise, and wealth. And (iii) sometimes these interests are (narrow) interests interested in negative sum policies that drive their own enrichment. Interests of type (i) promote the general welfare according to standard utilitarian theory. Interest of type (ii) promote the general welfare by enriching the economy. It is interests of type (iii) that are the problem. And the question is: why does it appear that interests of type (iii) are more powerful now than they used to be?

Brink Lindsey and Steven Teles: The Captured Economy: How the Powerful Enrich Themselves, Slow Down Growth, and Increase Inequality: “For years, America has been plagued by slow economic growth and increasing inequality…

…Yet economists have long taught that there is a tradeoff between equity and efficiency-that is, between making a bigger pie and dividing it more fairly. That is why our current predicament is so puzzling: today, we are faced with both a stagnating economy and sky-high inequality. In The Captured Economy, Brink Lindsey and Steven M. Teles identify a common factor behind these twin ills: breakdowns in democratic governance that allow wealthy special interests to capture the policymaking process for their own benefit. They document the proliferation of regressive regulations that redistribute wealth and income up the economic scale while stifling entrepreneurship and innovation. When the state entrenches privilege by subverting market competition, the tradeoff between equity and efficiency no longer holds.

Over the past four decades, new regulatory barriers have worked to shield the powerful from the rigors of competition, thereby inflating their incomes-sometimes to an extravagant degree. Lindsey and Teles detail four of the most important cases: subsidies for the financial sector’s excessive risk taking, overprotection of copyrights and patents, favoritism toward incumbent businesses through occupational licensing schemes, and the NIMBY-led escalation of land use controls that drive up rents for everyone else.

Freeing the economy from regressive regulatory capture will be difficult. Lindsey and Teles are realistic about the chances for reform, but they offer a set of promising strategies to improve democratic deliberation and open pathways for meaningful policy change. An original and counterintuitive interpretation of the forces driving inequality and stagnation, The Captured Economy will be necessary reading for anyone concerned about America’s mounting economic problems and the social tensions they are sparking.

Must- and Should-Reads: November 25, 2017

Must-Reads:


Should-Reads:


 

Must-Read: Paul Krugman (2009): The Obama Gaps

Must-Read:

  1. Paul Krugman is right…
  2. If you think Paul Krugman is wrong, see #1…

Paul Krugman (2009): The Obama Gaps: “The bottom line is that the Obama plan is unlikely to close more than half of the looming output gap, and could easily end up doing less than a third of the job…

…Why isn’t Mr. Obama trying to do more? Is the plan being limited by fear of debt? There are dangers associated with large-scale government borrowing…. But it would be even more dangerous to fall short in rescuing the economy. The president-elect spoke eloquently and accurately on Thursday about the consequences of failing to act—there’s a real risk that we’ll slide into a prolonged, Japanese-style deflationary trap—but the consequences of failing to act adequately aren’t much better.

Is the plan being limited by a lack of spending opportunities? There are only a limited number of “shovel-ready” public investment projects…. But there are other forms of public spending, especially on health care, that could do good while aiding the economy in its hour of need. Or is the plan being limited by political caution?… Keep the… price… below the politically sensitive trillion-dollar mark… inclusion of large business tax cuts, which add to its cost but will do little for the economy… [as] an attempt to win Republican votes in Congress.

Whatever the explanation, the Obama plan just doesn’t look adequate to the economy’s need. To be sure, a third of a loaf is better than none. But right now we seem to be facing two major economic gaps: the gap between the economy’s potential and its likely performance, and the gap between Mr. Obama’s stern economic rhetoric and his somewhat disappointing economic plan.

Should-Read: Paul Krugman: Schroedinger’s Tax Hike

Should-Read: Yes, it’s a grift. The only question is: who inside the Republican coalition is being grifted here?

Paul Krugman: Schroedinger’s Tax Hike: “The Senate bill… tries to be long-run deficit-neutral… by offsetting huge corporate tax cuts with higher taxes on individuals…

By 2027 half the population, and most of the middle-class, would see taxes go up. But those tax hikes are initially offset by a variety of temporary tax breaks…. Republicans are arguing that those tax breaks won’t actually be temporary…. But they also need to assume that those tax breaks really will expire in order to meet their budget numbers.

So the temporary tax breaks need, for political purposes, to be both alive and dead…. For now, they want to hold it all in suspension. Once upon a time you wouldn’t have imagined they could get away with it. Now…

Should-Read: Alexander William Salter and Daniel J. Smith: The Role of Political Environments in the Formation of Fed Policy Under Burns, Greenspan, and Bernanke

Should-Read: Alexander William Salter and Daniel J. Smith: Political Economists or Political Economists? The Role of Political Environments in the Formation of Fed Policy Under Burns, Greenspan, and Bernanke: “We analyze the writings and speeches of… Arthur Burns, Alan Greenspan, and Benjamin Bernanke…

…as they transitioned to becoming chairman of the Fed. The tension between their previously stated views and their subsequent policy stances as chairman of the Fed, suggest that operation within political institutions impelled them to alter their views. Our findings offer additional support for incorporating the concerns of political economy into monetary models and structures…

Should-Read: Paul Krugman: The Transfer Problem and Tax Incidence

Should-Read: To my knowledge, the Tax Foundation has never provided an answer to Paul Krugman’s critique that their “long run” takes not 10 years to arrive but 30:

Paul Krugman: The Transfer Problem and Tax Incidence: “These days, what passes for policymaking in America manages to be simultaneously farcical and sinister, and the evil-clown aspects extend into the oddest places…

…The actual economics of corporate tax incidence… [has] an intersection with international economics that… isn’t being [much] appreciated in the current discussion…. [In the] equaliz[ation of] after-tax rates of return in the long run… the long run is pretty darn long… return equalization should take decades….

Harberger… a closed economy with a fixed stock of capital… a tax on profits would fall on capital, basically because the supply of capital is inelastic. The modern counterargument is that we now live in a world of internationally mobile capital…. For a small economy facing perfect capital markets, the elasticity of capital supply is infinite… so any changes in corporate tax rates must fall on other factors, i.e. labor. Most analysis of tax incidence nonetheless allocates only a small fraction of the corporate tax to labor, for three reasons. First, a lot of corporate profits are… rents on monopoly power, brand value, technological advantages…. Third… rates of return probably aren’t equalized even in the long run…. I’m fine with all that….

I think it’s also important to ask exactly how inflows of capital that equalize rates of return are supposed to happen…. Suppose the US were to cut corporate tax rates…. How would the capital stock be increased? One does not simply walk into Mordor unbolt machines in other countries from the floor and roll them into America the next week. What we’re talking about is a process in which U.S. investment exceeds U.S. savings–that is, we run current account deficits–which increases our capital stock over time…. Exporters and importers don’t know or care about S-I; they respond to signals from prices and costs. A capital inflow creates a trade deficit by driving up the real exchange rate, making your goods and services less competitive. And because markets for goods and services are still very imperfectly integrated–most of GDP isn’t tradable at all–it takes large signals, big moves in the real exchange rate, to cause significant changes in the current account balance….

How much stronger does the dollar get?… The knowledge that we’re looking at a one-time adjustment limits how high the dollar can go, which limits the size of the current account deficit, which limits the rate at which the U.S. capital stock can expand, which slows the process of return equalization. So the long run in which returns are equalized can be quite long indeed…. I assume Cobb-Douglas production, with a capital share of 0.3. The capital-output ratio is about 3, implying an initial rate of return of 0.1. And the modelers at the Fed tell us… a 10 percent rise in the dollar widens the trade deficit by about 1.5 percent of GDP…. Assuming I’ve done the algebra right, I get a rate of convergence of… percent of the deviation from the long run eliminated each year… a dozen years to achieve even half the adjustment…. Openness to world capital markets makes a lot less difference to tax incidence than people seem to think in the short run, and even in the medium run…

Should-Read: Ned Phelps: Nothing Natural About the Natural Rate of Unemployment

Should-Read: Ned Phelps: Nothing Natural About the Natural Rate of Unemployment: “A compelling hypothesis is that workers, shaken by the 2008 financial crisis and the deep recession that resulted…

…have grown afraid to demand promotions or to search for better-paying employers–despite the ease of finding work in the recently tight labor market. A corollary hypothesis is that employers, disturbed by the extremely slow growth of productivity, especially in the past ten years, have grown leery of granting pay raises–despite the return of demand to pre-crisis proportions…. This does not mean there is no natural unemployment rate, only that there is nothing natural about it. There never was.

Should-Read: Justin Wolfers: @justinwolfers on Twitter

Should-Read: I’m really not surprised that the only economist out of 42 willing to believe this is from Robber-Baron Crony-Capitalism Stanford University. But I am embarrassed for my profession that there is even one:

Justin Wolfers: @justinwolfers on Twitter: “The University of Chicago surveyed 42 leading economists and found exactly one who believes the Republican claim that their tax bill will grow the economy. http://www.igmchicago.org/surveys/tax-reform-2

His comment doesn’t suggest he spent much time thinking about it:

A reduced corporate tax reduction is likely to grow GDP. Whether the overall tax plan is distributionally fair is another matter.

So does Darrell Duffie not believe in the government budget constraint? The right one-sentence is not Duffie’s but rather: “An unfunded tax cut that increases the deficit in an economy near full employment is likely to slow the growth of GDP”.

I would be interested in a further explanation from him: Why is it that we should think that the substitution effect should dominate the income effect here, and that consumption plus net exports is likely to fall rather than rise? But I don’t suppose I am likely to get a coherent one.