Must-read: Paul Krugman: “Globalization and Growth”

Must-Read: Paul Krugman: Globalization and Growth: “Brad DeLong… arguing that the really big benefits of globalization come from technology diffusion…

…which make it a much more positive force than I suggest. I used to believe the same thing, and still find myself thinking along those lines now and then. But I’d argue that economists need to be, at the least, upfront about the argument’s limitations. First, it doesn’t come out of the models. As Brad says, the map is not the territory; but guesses about such things are, well, guesses. There was a time when everyone knew that import-substituting industrialization was the key to economic takeoff, based on loose historical reasoning (America and Germany did it!). Then developing countries tried it en masse, and the results weren’t great.

Furthermore, my sense is that nonstandard free-trade arguments tend to involve, often unintentionally, a kind of bait and switch. Economists love to talk about comparative advantage…. Somewhere Alan Blinder said that economists would almost all agree on the slogan ‘Yay free trade.’ But the seeming authority of the comparative-advantage case then ends up being carried over, illegitimately, to arguments for trade that have nothing to do with comparative advantage. Yes, there could be positive externalities associated with trade, but there could be positive externalities associated with lots of things, and Ricardian models don’t give us any special reason to think that the trade ones are more important.

So how would you test such arguments? Well, in a way we did carry out an experiment. In the early 1990s there was a widespread orthodoxy that ‘outward-looking’ development policies were much more favorable to growth than ‘inward-looking’ policies… the rapid growth of Asian economies, which had followed an export-oriented path rather than… import substitution… in the 50s and 60s. The question, however, was whether you would see dramatic acceleration of growth in other places, such as Latin America, when policy shifted away from inward focus. And the answer turned out to be, not so much. Look at Mexico, which did a radical trade liberalization in 1985-88, then joined NAFTA. It has seen a transformation of its economy in many ways; it has gone from an economy that didn’t export much besides oil and tourism to a major manufacturing export power. And the effect on development has been… underwhelming.

So Brad could be right; but the evidence is far from conclusive. I would still argue very strongly that it’s crucial to keep markets open for poor countries. But we should be cautious in our claims about the virtues of free trade.

Does inequality affect high school dropout rates?

Melissa Kearney and Phillip Levine investigate how inequality affects the decisions of low-income students when it comes to completing high school.

One way that high levels of income and wealth inequality might affect economic growth is through the development of human capital. Inequality could warp workers’ ability to improve their level of education and skills in a number of ways—for example, income inequality and residential segregation might combine to create an inequitable and inefficient distribution of school spending. Or perhaps high levels of inequality might cause young people to become pessimistic about their future and underinvest in their education. A new paper from the Brookings Papers on Economic Activity reports new evidence for that second story.

The paper, by Melissa Kearney of the University of Maryland and Phillip Levine of Wellesley College, is part of the continuing investigation into the Great Gatsby Curve. The curve (based on work by Miles Corak and proposed by Princeton University economist and former Council of Economic Advisers chair Alan Krueger back in 2012) shows that countries with high levels of income inequality tend to have lower levels of intergenerational mobility. Of course, this is just a correlation—it’s still an open question of whether and how inequality has a causal effect on mobility.

Kearney and Levine try to untangle the possible causal relationship between the two. More specifically, they look at how higher levels of inequality might affect the decisions of students from low socioeconomic backgrounds when it comes to completing high school. Perhaps students will see higher inequality as motivation to work harder. Or maybe higher inequality will cause students instead to feel despair and drop out. It’s not clear which effect will be larger until we look at the data.

But let’s be clear about what the authors mean by inequality. In this paper, since Kearney and Levine look at the effects on students from low socioeconomic backgrounds (measured by the educational level of their mothers), they focus on inequality between those at the bottom and those at the middle of the income distribution. And they are looking at inequality within states and metropolitan areas.

The authors find that states and metropolitan areas with higher levels of inequality have higher high school dropout rates. But the result is only significant for boys from low socioeconomic backgrounds. Boys in high-inequality states are 6 percentage points more likely to drop out than similar boys in low-inequality states. While their analysis doesn’t definitively prove causation, it does show that many other possible explanations don’t reduce the strength of the statistical relationship.

Kearney and Levine’s argument is about students’ perceptions, but they also present some interesting evidence on “returns” to an extra year of school. In low-inequality states, the returns appear to be about the same across all classes. But in high-inequality states, the returns are not only slightly lower but also less equally distributed. This is particularly interesting in light of other research on differential rates of return to education. Perhaps this is why boys from low socioeconomic backgrounds perceive high school to not be worth the effort.

This analysis is far from a smoking gun on the causal relationship between inequality and mobility. No one paper ever will be. But it’s an interesting and thought-provoking step in our efforts to better understand the wide-ranging effects of inequality.

Must-reads: March 13, 2016


Speaker’s Notes for: Concrete Economics @ SXSW!

Speaking 12:30 PM Meeting 10AB Level 3 :: Signing 1:00 PM Bookstore Level 3:

Stephen S. Cohen, J. Bradford DeLong: Concrete Economics: The Hamilton Approach to Economic Growth and Policy] (Allston, MA: Harvard Business Review Press:1422189813) http://amzn.to/22ds5TK

The Book:

  • Small book
  • Readable book
  • Important book (we think)

The Thesis:

  • America’s political-economic governance from 1787-1975 or so was extraordinarily successful
  • America’s political-economic governance since 1975 or so not so
  • What changed?
  • America’s political-economic governance took an ideological turn about 1975

Hold It!: Wasn’t America Governed by Political-Economic Ideologies Before 1975?

  • No
  • There were strong ideologies:
    • Jefferson’s agrarian ideology
    • Madison’s (early) small-government ideology
    • Calhoun’s Herrenvolk ideology
    • Lochnerites–the claim the Constitution imposed Herbert Spencer’s Social Statics
  • But they all lost in the great political-economic scrum
    • Hamilton overcame Jefferson
    • Even Madison and certainly Madison’s successors overcame Madison
    • Lincoln overcame Calhoun
    • Teddy and Franklin Roosevelt overcame Herbert Spencer and the Lochnerites

What, Then, Did Govern America from 1787-1975?

  • Pragmatism
    • Hamilton’s state-led push for commerce, industry, finance
    • A very heavy governmental role in westward expansion–very bad for the Amerindians, very good for the settlers and the settler economy
    • Lincoln and his successors’ push for the acquisition of capital–farm capital via homesteads, human capital via education, plus corporate capital
    • Teddy Roosevelt’s Progressive curbing of overweening Gilded-Age power
  • All of these were ruthlessly pragmatic: looking not at ideology as a guide but at the world, and what seemed likely to work to increase popular wealth

But the New Deal! FDR Was Ideological!

  • No
  • FDR’s New Deal was the antithesis of ideology
  • FDR tried everything
    • Corporatism
    • Keynesianism
    • Agricultural subsidies
    • Antitrust
    • Social insurance
    • Unionism
    • And he reinforced what seemed to work
    • The New Deal policies that survived became an ideology, but they started out as the most ruthless pragmatism
  • And Eisenhower:
    • Highways, automobiles, suburbs, massive federal support for technology
    • But also fear of the military-industrial complex and a strong desire neither to break inherited things from the New Deal the worked
    • Eisenhowerism was, as Daniel Bell wrote, an attempt to institutionalize the permanent end of ideology

So What Has Gone Wrong in the Past 40 Years?

  • Belief that the inflation and oil shocks of the 1970s demonstrated that Eisenhowerism was tapped out
  • And the fault laid to insufficient love of the free market (and excessive big government)
  • Hence the big push for:
    • Spending two Pentagons on excess wealth for our overclass in an attempt to give them “incentive”
    • Spending a Pentagon on excess health care administration and excess unnecessary and harmful treatment
    • Deregulation and financialization leading to a Pentagon’s worth of waste in over-financialization
      • Is corporate control better? Is risk-bearing more advanced?
      • Plus two additional Pentagons’ worth of waste in permanent damage from the financial crisis
    • The only rich capital-inflow economy in history
      • A really rich country should be exporting capital
      • And leveraging its innovative, intellectual, and human-capital expertise over ever-growing communities of engineering and entrepreneurial practice
        • To some degree, we have been doing the second
      • But we have been letting “the market” greatly reduce the scale
  • From the middle-class perspective, 8 Pentagons worth of waste over the past 40 years–all of them driven by ideology (and interest)

What to Do Next?

  • All such books are supposed to end with: MY PLAN
  • We refuse: such “my plans” are never convincing
  • What we do seek to convince you of is this:
    • The world is a complicated place
    • The world surprises you–and the more bound you are to your ideology, the more you will be surprised
    • Feedback and pragmatism are better than ideological oversimplifications
    • Arguments against policies of the form “this breaks ideological principle X” should have much less purchase than we give them

Today That Principle Leads to a Total Rejection of the Republican Party and All of Its Works

  • But that fact is a judgment on the Republican Party as it is currently constituted
  • And whatever parties we have in 30 years will be equally vulnerable to ideological viruses–as vulnerable as were jefferson, Madison, Calhoun, the Lochnerites, and more recently the Bushites, Cruzites, Rubites, Gingrichites, and even the Kasichites.
  • We need to defeat them and be pragmatic–with Hamilton, the later Madison and company, Lincoln, Teddy and Franklin, and Ike…

Concrete Economics @ SXSW!: Speaking 12:30 PM Meeting 10AB Level 3 :: Signing 1:00 PM Bookstore Level 3

I guess that is it: Concrete Economics @ SXSW!: Speaking 12:30 PM Meeting 10AB Level 3 :: Signing 1:00 PM Bookstore Level 3:

Stephen S. Cohen, J. Bradford DeLong: Concrete Economics: The Hamilton Approach to Economic Growth and Policy] (Allston, MA: Harvard Business Review Press:1422189813) http://amzn.to/22ds5TK

The benefits of free trade: Time to fly my neoliberal freak flag high!

I think Paul Krugman is wrong today on international trade. For we find him in “plague on both your houses” mode. On the one hand:

Paul Krugman: Trade and Tribulation and A Protectionist Moment?: “Protectionists almost always exaggerate the adverse effects of trade liberalization…

…Globalization is only one of several factors behind rising income inequality, and trade agreements are, in turn, only one factor in globalization. Trade deficits have been an important cause of the decline in U.S. manufacturing employment since 2000, but that decline began much earlier. And even our trade deficits are mainly a result of factors other than trade policy, like a strong dollar buoyed by global capital looking for a safe haven.

And yes, Mr. Sanders is demagoguing the issue…. If Sanders were to make it to the White House, he would find it very hard to do anything much about globalization…. The moment he looked into actually tearing up existing trade agreements the diplomatic, foreign-policy costs would be overwhelmingly obvious. In this, as in many other things, Sanders currently benefits from the luxury of irresponsibility….

But on the other hand:

That said… the elite case for ever-freer trade, the one that the public hears, is largely a scam…. [The] claims [are] that trade is an engine of job creation, that trade agreements will have big payoffs in terms of economic growth and that they are good for everyone. Yet… the models… used by real experts say… agreements that lead to more trade neither create nor destroy jobs… make countries more efficient and richer, but that the numbers aren’t huge….

False claims of inevitability, scare tactics (protectionism causes depressions!), vastly exaggerated claims for the benefits of trade liberalization and the costs of protection, hand-waving away the large distributional effects that are what standard models actually predict…. A back-of-the-envelope on the gains from hyperglobalization — only part of which can be attributed to policy — that is less than 5 percent of world GDP over a generation…. Furthermore, as Mark Kleiman sagely observes, the conventional case for trade liberalization relies on the assertion that the government could redistribute income to ensure that everyone wins—but we now have an ideology utterly opposed to such redistribution in full control of one party…. So the elite case for ever-freer trade is largely a scam, which voters probably sense even if they don’t know exactly what form it’s taking….

And, Paul summing up:

Why, then, did we ever pursue these agreements?… Foreign policy: Global trade agreements from the 1940s to the 1980s were used to bind democratic nations together during the Cold War, Nafta was used to reward and encourage Mexican reformers, and so on. And anyone ragging on about those past deals, like Mr. Trump or Mr. Sanders, should be asked what, exactly, he proposes doing now.… The most a progressive can responsibly call for, I’d argue, is a standstill on further deals, or at least a presumption that proposed deals are guilty unless proved innocent.

The hard question to deal with here is the Trans-Pacific Partnership…. I consider myself a soft opponent: It’s not the devil’s work, but I really wish President Obama hadn’t gone there…. Politicians should be honest and realistic about trade, rather than taking cheap shots. Striking poses is easy; figuring out what we can and should do is a lot harder. But you know, that’s a would-be president’s job…. [But] he case for more trade agreements—including TPP, which hasn’t happened yet—is very, very weak. And if a progressive makes it to the White House, she should devote no political capital whatsoever to such things.

So I guess it is time to say “I think Paul Krugman is wrong here!” and fly my neoliberal freak flag high…

On the analytics, the standard HOV models do indeed produce gains from trade by sorting production in countries to the industries in which they have comparative advantages. That leads to very large shifts in incomes toward those who owned the factors of production used intensively in the industries of comparative advantage: Big winners and big losers within a nation, with relatively small net gains.

But the map is not the territory. The model is not the reality. An older increasing-returns tradition sees productivity depend on the division of labor, the division of labor depends on the extent of the market, and free-trade greatly widens the market. Such factors can plausibly quadruple The Knick gains from trade over those from HOV models alone, and so create many more winners.

Moreover, looking around the world we see a world in which income differentials across high civilizations were twofold three centuries ago and are tenfold today. The biggest factor in global economics behind the some twentyfold or more explosion of Global North productivity over the past three centuries has been the failure of the rest of the globe to keep pace with the Global North. And what are the best ways to diffuse Global North technology to the rest of the world? Free trade: both to maximize economic contact and opportunities for learning and imitation, and to make possible the export-led growth and industrialization strategy that is the royal and indeed the only reliable road to anything like convergence.

So I figure that, all in all, not 5% but more like 30% of net global prosperity–and considerable reduction in cross-national inequality–is due to globalization. That is a very big number indeed. But, remember, even the 5% number cited by Krugman is a big deal: $4 trillion a year, and perhaps $130 trillion in present value.

As for the TPP, the real trade liberalization parts are small net goods. The economic question is whether the dispute-resolution and intellectual-property protection pieces are net goods. And on that issue I am agnostic leaning negative. The political question is: Since this is a Republican priority, why is Obama supporting it without requiring Republican support for a sensible Democratic priority as a quid pro quo?

That said, let me wholeheartedly endorse what Paul (and Mark) say here:

as Mark Kleiman sagely observes, the conventional case for trade liberalization relies on the assertion that the government could redistribute income to ensure that everyone wins—but we now have an ideology utterly opposed to such redistribution in full control of one party…. So the elite case for ever-freer trade is largely a scam, which voters probably sense even if they don’t know exactly what form it’s taking….

Must-see: Kathleen Maclay: Chowdhury Center for Bangladesh Studies hosts Nobel-winning economist Amartya Sen

Must-See: Kathleen Maclay: Chowdhury Center for Bangladesh Studies hosts Nobel-winning economist Amartya Sen: “Chowdhury Center for Bangladesh Studies hosts Nobel-winning economist Amartya Sen…

…widely known for his work on income inequality and the roles of famine, poverty and freedom in developing countries around the world…. WHEN: 4-6 p.m., Sunday, March 13. WHERE: The sanctuary of the First Presbyterian Church, 2407 Dana St., Berkeley…. Sen is the Thomas W. Lamont University Professor and Professor of Economics and Philosophy at Harvard University…

Ordoliberalismus and Ordovolkismus

At the zero lower bound on safe nominal short-term interest rates, an expansionary fiscal policy impetus of d percent of current GDP will:

  1. raise current output by (μ)d,
  2. raise future output by (φμ)d, and
  3. raise the debt to GDP ratio by a proportional amount ΔD = (1 – μτ – μφ)d,

where [mu] is the Keynesian multiplier, τ is the tax rate, and φ is the hysteresis coefficient.

It will then require a commitment of (r-g)ΔD percent of future output the service the additional debt, where r is the real interest rate on government debt and g is the growth rate of the economy. The debt service can be raised through explicit and fiscal deadweight loss-inducing taxation, through inflation–a tax on outside money balances accompanied by disruption of the unit of account–or through financial repression–a tax on the banking system but also imposes financial distortions.

That is the simple arithmetic of expansionary fiscal policy in a liquidity trap.

The question of whether and how much expansionary fiscal policy a government facing a liquidity trap should engage and then becomes a technocratic one of calculating uncertain benefits and uncertain costs. Why uncertain? Because our knowledge of the parameters of the economy is uncertain. And we are particularly uncertain not just of the outcome of the key debt- amortization parameter r-g but of its ex-ante distribution as well. There is this an element of radical, almost Knightian, uncertainty here in the benefit-cost calculation. But it remains a benefit-cost calculation. And rare these days is the competent economist Who has thought through the benefit-cost calculation and failed to conclude that the governments of the United States, Germany, and Britain have large enough multipliers, strong enough hysteresis coefficients for infrastructure investment programs, and sufficient fiscal space–favorable likely distributions of r-g–to make substantially more expansionary fiscal policies than they are currently following almost no-brainers.

It is against the backdrop of this situation that we find aversion to fiscal expansion being driven not by pragmatic technocratic benefit-cost calculations but by raw ideology. And so we find Barry Eichengreen being… shrill:

Barry Eichengreen: Confronting the Fiscal Bogeyman: “The world economy is visibly sinking, and the policymakers who are supposed to be its stewards are tying themselves in knots…

…Or so suggest the results of the G-20 summit held in Shanghai…. All that emerged… was an anodyne statement… structural reforms… avoiding beggar-thy-neighbor policies. Once again, monetary policy was left… the only game in town…. Someone needs to do something to keep the world economy afloat, and central banks are the only agents capable of acting. The problem is that monetary policy is approaching exhaustion….

The solution is straightforward. It is to fix the problem of deficient demand… by boosting public spending. Governments should borrow to invest in research, education, and infrastructure…. Such investments cost little given low interest rates… [and] enhance the returns on private investment [as well]…. Thus it is disturbing to see… particularly… the US and Germany [refusing] to even contemplate such action, despite available fiscal space….

Barry blames Germany’s derangement on the ideology of Ordliberalism:

In Germany, ideological aversion to budget deficits… is rooted in the post-World War II doctrine of ‘ordoliberalism,’ which counseled that government should enforce contracts and ensure adequate competition but otherwise avoid interfering in the economy…. The ordoliberal emphasis on personal responsibility fostered an unreasoning hostility to the idea that actions that are individually responsible do not automatically produce desirable aggregate outcomes…. It rendered Germans allergic to macroeconomics….

Barry blames the U.S. derangement on a somewhat analogous ideological formation—call it Ordovolkism:

[In] the US… citizens have been suspicious of federal government power, including the power to run deficits, which is fundamentally a federal prerogative.… That suspicion was strongest in the American South… rooted in the fear that the federal government might abolish slavery…. During the civil rights movement, it was again the Southern political elite that opposed the muscular use of federal power…. The South [became] a solid Republican bloc and leave its leaders antagonistic to all exercise of federal power except for the enforcement of contracts and competition—a hostility that notably included countercyclical macroeconomic policy. Welcome to ordoliberalism, Dixie-style. Wolfgang Schäuble, meet Ted Cruz.

And Barry concludes by asking:

Ideological and political prejudices deeply rooted in history will have to be overcome to end the current stagnation. If an extended period of depressed growth following a crisis isn’t the right moment to challenge them, then when is?

Barry intends this last as a rhetorical question: It is the great Hillel’s “If not now, when?”, to which the proper answer is: “Then now!”

But it is quite possible that the best answer is, instead: “Never!”

While Austerian fear and suspicion of countercyclical monetary policy is rooted in the same Ordoliberal and Ordovolkist ideological fever swamps as objections to countercyclical fiscal policy, it is much weaker. It is much weaker because fundamentalist cries for an automatic monetary system—whether based on a gold standard, a k%/year percent growth rule, or John Taylor’s interest-rate rule—have crashed and burned so spectacularly so many times that they lack even the barest surface plausibility. History has definitively refuted Henry Simons’s call for rules rather than authority in monetary policy. The near-consensus agreed-upon task of institution design for monetary policy is not to construct rules but, instead, to construct authorities with technocratic competence and sensible objectives and values.

Thus one way around the Ordoliberal and Ordovolkist ideological blockages is to redefine a sufficient quantum of countercyclical fiscal policy as monetary policy. I call this “social credit”. Others call it “helicopter money”. Move the central bank’s seigniorage revenue stream outside of the government’s consolidated budget. Assign the disposition of this revenue stream to the central bank. It is not first-best. It may be good enough to do the job.

Another way of attempting to finesse the problem is to construct a fiscal council of some sort. Such an institution, assigned responsibility for the government’s investment budget, may attract the technocratic competence and status of the central banks, and so outflank Ordoliberal and Ordovolkist ideological blockages. Are haps.

But if neither of these expedients—neither social credit or helicopter money on the one hand nor fiscal councils on the other—will serve, then Barry Eichengreen is completely right: it is long past time for a frontal intellectual assault on the dangerous and destructive ideologies of Ordoliberalism and Ordovolkism.

And that assault would be, itself, part of a broader intellectual struggle. The major point of Steve Cohen’s and my Concrete Economics is precisely that ideology is a very bad guide the economic policy. This is simply another—albeit an unusually important—instance.

Must-read: Laura Tyson: “Closing the Investment Gap”

Must-Read: Investment has been weak because demand growth has been weak–and because the residential-investment credit channel broke in 2007, and neither Barack Obama nor Tim Geithner nor Jack Lew nor Ed de Marco nor Mel Watt nor any congressional coalition has taken any steps to fix it.

This is a very important channel for “hysteresis”–especially if, like me, you believe in powerful external benefits from investment, especially equipment investment:

Laura Tyson: Closing the Investment Gap: “BERKELEY – The weakness of private investment in the United States and other advanced economies is… worrisome… perplexing…

…Through 2014, private investment declined by an average of 25% compared to pre-crisis trends.
The shortfall in investment has been deep and broad-based, affecting not only residential investment but also investment in equipment and structures. Business investment remains significantly below pre-2008 expectations, and has been hit hard again in the US during the last year by the collapse of energy-sector investment in response to the steep drop in oil prices….

The investment shortfall in the US coincides with a strong rebound in returns to capital. By one measure, returns to private capital are now at a higher point than any time in recent decades. But extensive empirical research confirms that at the macro level, business investment depends primarily on expected future demand and output growth, not on current returns or retained earnings. According to the IMF, this ‘accelerator’ theory of investment explains most of the weakness of business investment in the developed economies since the 2008 crisis. In accordance with this explanation, investment growth in the US has been in line with its usual historical relationship with output growth. In short, private investment growth has been weak primarily because the pace of recovery has been anemic….

As the accelerator theory of investment would predict, much R&D investment is occurring in technology-intensive sectors where current and future expected demand has been strong. There is also evidence that the distribution of returns to capital is becoming increasingly skewed toward these sectors…

Must-read: Simon Wren-Lewis: “A (Much) Better Fiscal Rule”

Must-Read: Simon Wren-Lewis: A (Much) Better Fiscal Rule: “Today the Labour Shadow Chancellor John McDonnell…

…will give a speech where he puts forward an alternative fiscal rule… a rolling target for the government’s current balance: within 5 years taxes must cover current spending. It leaves the government free to borrow to invest…. There is a commitment to reduce debt relative to trend GDP over the course of a parliament. No doubt we will hear the usual cries from the opponents of sensible fiscal rules: Labour plan to borrow billions more than George Osborne and they plan to go on borrowing forever. The simple response to that should be that it is right to borrow to invest in the country’s future, just as firms borrow to invest in capital and individuals borrow to invest in a house. Indeed, with so many good projects for the government to choose from, and with interest rates at virtually zero, it is absolute madness not to investment substantially in the coming years….

Recessions come and go, you might respond, but higher debt will always be with us. That ignores two key points. First, prolonged and deep recessions cause lasting damage. UK GDP per head is currently over 15% below pre-recession trends. Does none of that have anything to do with the slowest UK recovery from a recession in centuries? Second using fiscal policy to end recessions quickly does not mean higher debt forever. The key point is that debt can be reduced once the recession is over and interest rates are safely above their lower bound. Doing that will be no cost to the economy as a whole, as monetary policy can offset the impact on demand. Obsessing about debt during a recession, by contrast, costs jobs and reduces incomes, as every economics student knows and as the OBR have shown….

Some Labour MPs and commentators. They say, quite rightly, that one of the main reasons the 2015 election was lost was because Labour were not trusted on fiscal policy. But the basic truth is that you do not enhance your fiscal credibility by signing up to a stupid fiscal rule. Apart from getting attacked for doing so by people like me, your collective heart is not really in it and it shows. You get trapped into proposing to shrink the state as Osborne is doing, or hitting the poor as Osborne is doing, or raising taxes which makes you unpopular. And if by chance it ever looks like you might be getting that trust back, Osborne or his successor will move the goalposts again.

The far more convincing way to get trust back is to adopt a fiscal rule that makes sense to both economists and the public (‘only borrowing to invest’), and actively talking about it….

The Conservatives know they are vulnerable on public investment. Osborne tries to give the impression that he is doing a lot of it, but the figures do not lie. In the last five years of the Labour government the average share of net public investment in GDP was over 2.5%. During the coalition years it fell to 2.2%, and for the five years from 2015 it is planned to average just 1.6%. That is not building for the future, but putting it in jeopardy, as those whose homes have been flooded have found to their cost.