The rigid DNA of the European Central Bank

The slow-motion economic crisis in Greece finally accelerated into high gear this week, with the imposition of a bank holiday and capital controls following the withholding of another round of capital by the European Central Bank from Greece’s insolvent banks. This is what it looks like when a fixed exchange regime such as the euro fails. To date, the critique of the Eurozone as a system has mostly centered on the inability of an independent central bank to govern an economy as large as Europe’s without also having a European Treasury with tax and spending authority to back it up.

The problems inherent in the Eurozone, however, run deeper than a mismatch between the European Union’s wide monetary and narrow fiscal authority. They can be found in the DNA of the Eurozone. The European Central Bank’s institutional priorities and rules baked in from the start doomed the euro project to eventual failure in exactly this way. The relevant DNA emerged from a strand of the macroeconomic research born in the “neoclassical revolution” of the 1970s. That literature gave intellectual heft to the idea that a central bank should be run completely independent of any democratically-accountable political authority and that the only policy objective a central bank should uphold is to prevent inflation at all costs.

That is how the European Central bank is set up. Its governors are appointed from the central banks of the Eurozone member states and are not subject to any confirmation, as determined by a treaty that supersedes the domestic law of all European Union members. The same treaty requires that the central bank only care about “price stability,” meaning preventing inflation.

The most influential paper undergirding the euro is “Rules Rather Than Discretion: the Inconsistency of Optimal Plans,” published by economists Fynn Kydland of Norway and Edward Prescott of the United States in 1977 (see here for a lucid summary of their work). Their paper is very much a creature of the “stagflation” of the early 1970s. The key idea is that central bankers face a “Time Consistency Problem,” in which no policy they announce will ever be believed.

To understand Kydland and Prescott’s argument, first imagine that unemployment is negatively related to inflation. That is, higher inflation is associated with lower unemployment, and vice versa. Central bankers want to minimize both unemployment and inflation, so they face an inherent tradeoff. Now imagine that the economy exists for only two periods. In the first period, workers and firms form their expectation for inflation in the second period. If the central bank can convince workers and firms in the first period that inflation will be low in the second, then when that second period rolls around the central bank will have a strong incentive to generate surprise inflation in order to lower unemployment. But if workers and firms understand how the game is played, they’ll know a surprise is coming, so they cannot be induced to believe inflation will be low when they form expectations in the first period. Once workers and firms expect high inflation, if the central bank doesn’t deliver it in the second period, then unemployment will be high.

Because of these dynamics around expectations and trust, in the world of Kydland and Prescott’s simple model, an outcome with no inflation and low unemployment is unattainable. Any central banker who tries to reduce unemployment will only end up increasing inflation by inducing workers and firms to expect inflation, which the central banker then has to deliver to avoid unemployment.

To sidestep the Time Consistency Problem, Kydland and Prescott proposed what they called “rules” whereby the central bank should use a mathematical formula to dictate policy, eliminating their discretion. There’s no role for individual central bankers weighing options, hence no opportunity for them to try to fool workers, and hence no concern that workers will be afraid of being fooled and not trust an announced discretionary policy.

As several later writers noted, there’s no guarantee this mathematical formula would not itself be changed, so even mathematically-defined rules based on independent economic data may be just as bad, in practice, as discretion! Instead, as the Time Consistency literature evolved, the critical element in setting anti-inflationary policy is to appoint central bankers with strong reputations for fighting inflation. Everyone will believe them.

The result of this academic wrangling was a consensus in favor of endowing central bankers with no political accountability and tasking them to do whatever’s necessary to curtail inflation should it ever arise. By doing so, they assure inflation never arises in the first place. That is the view that was incorporated into the Maastricht Treaty of 1992 that set up the European Central Bank and gave it the notorious single mandate to reduce inflation, with no eye to mitigating recessions or unemployment.

Inflation has indeed been low in the Eurozone, including in countries such as Spain, Italy, and Greece where inflation had been famously high when these nations had their own currencies and autonomous central banks. But over this same period, inflation has also been low across developed economies, including those without independent central banks (such as the United Kingdom, where the move to independent policymaking only happened in 1997, to no discernible effect), and those with central banks charged with an explicit dual mandate for price stability and full employment (as in the United States).

The problem is that sometimes an economy needs inflation to function well. That’s true of Greece now—a massive debt overhang means that Greek businesses and households aren’t spending. Creditor-enforced austerity means the Greek government isn’t spending either. And an over-valued currency means that no one outside Greece wants to buy what the country is selling.

But the European Central Bank can never allow inflation because in the strange world of the Time Consistency Problem, that would reveal it to be irresponsible and secretly pro-inflation, ultimately leading to hyperinflationary expectations throughout the Eurozone. So despite the massive economic, social, and political cost, the European Central Bank insists on a prolonged depression rather than moderate inflation to work off Greece’s debt overhang. The idea that 25 percent of Greece should be unemployed and the other 75 percent should lose half their income in order to uphold the rigid diktat of an economics paper published in 1977 is not politically sustainable. Instead, Greece may well leave the euro. Either way, the Eurozone will leave its rigid DNA intact. Until the next crisis.

Looking Beyond the Latest U.S. Jobs Data

Every month the top-line data about the growth of jobs and wages in the U.S. economy are swiftly dissected by the financial markets for indications about the strength and direction of the economy. Yet the importance of these monthly statistics as they relate to U.S. income inequality and more long-term economic growth is often ignored.

Take the increase in hourly wages in June as well as the number of new jobs added in the U.S economy as reported today by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Over the past year, hourly wages in the private sector grew by 2.0 percent, and over the past three months they grew at an annual rate of about 2.2 percent. With nominal wages rising at those rates and annual inflation close to zero, current hourly pay increases are amounting to significant real wage gains (adjusting for inflation).

Yet at the same time, nominal wage growth of less than 3.5 to 4.0 percent is not an encouraging phenomenon over the long term as it implies increasing inequality between those who rely on earned income and owners of capital. Over a longer period, with the current rate of wage gains workers will be taking home a smaller share of national income, assuming the Federal Reserve inflation target of 2.0 percent and productivity growth of about 1.5 percent.

Similarly, the 223,000 new jobs added in June along with revisions to prior months means that over the past three months the U.S. economy added about 221,000 jobs on average. These gains are a welcome development, but they represent less than 0.2 percent of the average monthly employment level about 142 million. These net changes in employment also obscure the large flows in and out of employment, as workers are hired and as employees separate from their workplaces to take other jobs or slip into the ranks of the unemployed.

Employers hired more than 5 million workers in April, the most recent data available from the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey, and nearly 4.9 million left their jobs. The monthly turnover rate—total hires into employment and total separations from employment—was close to 3.5 percent, more than 20 times the size of the net employment change reported in that month.

In addition, these aggregate employment flows mask large differences in turnover rates across industries, with lower-paying industries in particular experiencing higher turnover. (See Figure 1.)

070215-turnover-earnings-01

By turning to another data source on employment flows, the Quarterly Workforce Indicators, we can compare how industry-specific turnover rates relate to average pay. The quarterly turnover rate for the overall private sector is typically about 19.6 percent, when measured over the past decade. In the manufacturing sector, where workers are paid about 23.2 percent more than the average worker, turnover rates are much lower, at 9.7 percent. In the accommodation and food services industry, where the average employee earns substantially less, turnover rates are higher than average, at 30.9 percent.

There are several reasons why lower paying industries have higher turnover, such as having workers that are younger, with lower levels of education, or with less training. But research on the minimum wage shows that when specific industries, such as restaurants, are compelled to pay a higher wage, worker turnover falls sharply. After a minimum wage increase, restaurants tend to hire fewer workers, but fewer workers leave these jobs as well. Total restaurant employment levels do not change much in response to higher minimum wages, but restaurant workers now stay at their job longer, gaining more experience.

In the case of a minimum wage increase, pay increases reduce flows in and out of employment for industries and demographic groups that are most affected by minimum wages, among them restaurants and younger workers. In contrast, when the overall labor market improves, we should expect higher turnover along with higher wages. As overall demand grows, hiring rates will rise as employers hire more workers, but so will separations: it is easier for employers to recruit workers from one job to another by offering higher wages.

Although minimum wage policies seem to affect employment flows without changing employment levels, other policies, such as the recently proposed changes to the federal overtime rule, may affect both. Employers may respond to this measure by reducing hours, but they will correspondingly hire more workers to satisfy demand. In this way, the overtime measure will increase the number of jobs through the hiring rate.

Both gross flows and net changes are key markers for economists and policymakers alike to explore whenever new employment and wage growth data are released. They enable a broader understanding of the overall direction of the U.S. economy as it relates to inequality and growth.

More Musings on “Monetary Economics”

There is, I think, a profound reason why those who have been able to understand the business cycle over the past two centuries have been those who have defined themselves as doing “monetary economics”, and those who have not been able to understand the business cycle have not…

Three things strike me while rereading Schumpeter’s 1934 “Depressions” (and also his 1927 Explanation of the Business Cycle):
1. How much smarter Schumpeter is than our modern liquidationists and austerians–he manages to say a great many true things. He manages to say them even though his fundamental belief–that structural adjustment requires a downturn and a wave of bankruptcies that releases resources into unemployment–is mistaken. That false belief turns his overall argument into chaff. But there are a lot of insights nevertheless. How much more fun and useful it would be right now to be debating a Schumpeter right now than the ideologues calling for, say, more austerity for and more unemployment in Greece!

  1. How very strange it is for Schumpeter to be laying out his depressions-cause-structural-change-and-growth theory of business cycles at the very same moment that he is also laying out his entrepreneurs-disrupt-the-circular-flow-and-cause-structural-change-and-growth-theory of enterprise. It is, of course, the second that is correct: Growth comes from entrepreneurs pulling resources into the sectors, enterprises, products, and production methods of the future. It does not come from depressions pushing resources into unemployment. Indeed, as Keynes noted, times of depression and fear of future depression are powerful brakes halting Schumpeterian entrepreneurship: “If effective demand is deficient… the individual enterpriser… is operating with the odds loaded against him. The game of hazard which he plays is furnished with many zeros…. Hitherto the increment of the world’s wealth has fallen short of the aggregate of positive individual savings; and the difference has been made up by the losses of those whose courage and initiative have not been supplemented by exceptional skill or unusual good fortune. But if effective demand is adequate, average skill and average good fortune will be enough…”

  2. How Schumpeter genuinely seems to have no clue at all that the business cycle is a feature of a monetary economy–how very badly indeed he needed to learn, and how he never did learn, what Nick Rowe and company teach today about the effects of monetary stringency on economic coordination.

The key, I think, is that Schumpeter–and Hayek, and all the other Austrians past and present–never grappled with the Mill-Bagehot-Wicksell-Fisher traditions in monetary economics. Overinvestment is one thing that can produce an excess demand for safe and liquid assets. It is not the only thing that can. It is not the case that excess demand for safe and liquid assets necessarily implies a previous bout of overinvestment. And it is not the case that curing the excess demand for safe and liquid assets always requires painful “liquidation” and austerity.

There was an alternative road of understanding open to Schumpeter, Hayek, and company–one that the line of argument from Mill through Wicksell and Fisher to Keynes and Friedman took. It goes roughly like this:

  1. Demand for safe and liquid financial assets sometimes spikes. It can spike because previously investors were over-sanguine, and their beliefs have now come back to normal. It can spike because investors were previously realistic, and are now overly pessimistic. It can spike because of news about increasing fundamental risk. It can spike because of news about decreasing expected returns.

  2. No matter what the cause, there emerges an excess demand for safe and liquid financial assets.

  3. That excess demand is, by Walras’s Law, the counterpart of an excess supply at full employment of currently-produced goods and services.

  4. That excess supply causes inventories to pile up, and production, employment, and incomes to fall.

  5. Because of sticky prices and sticky nominal contracts, declines in the price level–declines in the prices of currently-produced goods and services relative to money–cannot quickly rebalance the economy at full employment. Sticky prices do not fall fast enough to do so. And non-sticky prices that do fall produce chains of bankruptcies that further boost demand for money–for safe and liquid assets.

  6. Hence the economy gets stuck, for a while at least, with lots of involuntary unemployment.

This is a clear, coherent story about downturns. It says that downturns can be triggered by a recognition of overinvestment. But it also says that downturns can be triggered by other things. And there is no reason why the recognition of overinvestment has to be followed by a period of high involuntary unemployment. Structural adjustment and sectoral rebalancing may be desirable, but periods of structural adjustment and sectoral rebalancing do not always require high structural unemployment. And curing high demand slack-driven involuntary unemployment does not require slowing structural adjustment: you do not have to refill a tire through the puncture.

Yet neither Schumpeter nor Hayek nor any of their latter-day epigones could ever go to that Mill-Bagehot-Wicksell-Fisher-Keynes-Friedman argument. Instead, we have an alternative axis–a Ricardo-Marx-Schumpeter-Hayek-Hoover axis–that denies that anything other than budget surpluses and “sound money” can ever be appropriate economic policies. Why not? The root of the rejection of Mill-Friedman really does seem to me a belief that the market and its “general gluts” cannot be improved by macroeconomic management, either because (Ricardo-Schumpeter-Hayek-Hoover) the market is and must be good, or because (Marx) the market is and must be bad.


Joseph Schumpeter (1934): Depressions: What Can We Learn from Past Experience?

The problems presented by periods of depression may be grouped as follows: First, removal of extra economic injuries to the economic mechanism: Mostly impossible on political grounds. Second, relief: Not only imperative on moral and social grounds, but also an important means to keep up the current of economic life and to steady demand, although no cure for fundamental cases.

Third, remedies: The chief difficulty of which lies in the fact that depressions are not simply evils, which we might attempt to suppress, but–perhaps undesirable–forms of something which has to be done, namely, adjustment to previous economic change.

Most of what would be effective in remedying a depression would be equally effective in preventing this adjustment. This is especially true of inflation, which would, if pushed far enough, undoubtedly turn depression in to the sham prosperity so familiar from European postwar [i.e., World War I] experience, but which, if it be carried to that point, would, in the end, lead to a collapse worse than the one it was called in to remedy.

Fourth, reforms of institutions intended to remedy the situation but suggested by the moral and economic evils of both booms and depressions: The crucial point of these reforms lies in the coincidence of a political atmosphere exceptionally favorable, and an economic situation exceptionally unfavorable to their success. No doubt they will always be carried amidst enthusiastic clapping of hands. But they will also be stigmatized in the future by their tendency to prevent or retard recovery. This should not blind to us to any merits they may have, but it is a plain and undeniable fact.

The Atmosphere of Periods of Depression: We have seen that the course of events in all periods of depression presents a significant family likeness. So do the attitudes of the people. Defeat on the battlefield destroys the prestige of military rulers and their confidence in themselves; crises destroy whatever of both these things business leaders may enjoy. Their cry for help is the more damaging for them the more they disapproved of government interference before. For the time being, the majority of people grows out of humor with the economic system under which they live, and becomes inclined to favor what in some cases we call reaction and in others radicalism. In fact, it makes astonishingly little difference which way they more politically. The consequences are much the same in both cases….

The Upshot: There is on reason to despair–this is the first lesson to be derived from our story. Fundamentally the same thing has happened in the past, and it has–in the only two cases which are comparable to the present one–lasted just as long. We are more keenly alive now to human suffering, and we are dealing with the situation under political pressure by political methods, but substantially we are confronted only with problems which the world was confronted with before.

In all cases, not only the two which we have analyzed, recovery came of itself. There is certainly this much of truth in the talk about the recuperative powers of our industrial system. But this is not all: our analysis leads us to believe that recovery is sound only if it does com of itself. For any revival which is merely due to artificial stimulus leaves part of the work of depressions undone and adds, to an undigested remnant of maladjustment, new maladjustment of its own which has to be liquidated in turn, thus threatending business with another crisis ahead. Particularly, our story provides a presumption against remedial measures which work through money and credit. For the trouble is fundamentally not with money and credit, and policie of this class are particularly apt to keep up, and add to, maladjustment, and to produce additional trouble in the future…


Essays On Entrepreneurs Innovations Business Cycles and the Evolution of Joseph Alois Schumpeter Google Books
Essays On Entrepreneurs Innovations Business Cycles and the Evolution of Joseph Alois Schumpeter Google Books
Essays On Entrepreneurs Innovations Business Cycles and the Evolution of Joseph Alois Schumpeter Google Books
Essays On Entrepreneurs Innovations Business Cycles and the Evolution of Joseph Alois Schumpeter Google Books
Essays On Entrepreneurs Innovations Business Cycles and the Evolution of Joseph Alois Schumpeter Google Books
Essays On Entrepreneurs Innovations Business Cycles and the Evolution of Joseph Alois Schumpeter Google Books
Essays On Entrepreneurs Innovations Business Cycles and the Evolution of Joseph Alois Schumpeter Google Books
Essays On Entrepreneurs Innovations Business Cycles and the Evolution of Joseph Alois Schumpeter Google Books
Essays On Entrepreneurs Innovations Business Cycles and the Evolution of Joseph Alois Schumpeter Google Books
Essays On Entrepreneurs Innovations Business Cycles and the Evolution of Joseph Alois Schumpeter Google Books

Must-Read: Danny Hakim: U.S. Chamber of Commerce Works Globally to Fight Antismoking Measures

Must-Read: May I say: should the TPP includes any language allowing tobacco companies to use its dispute-resolution mechanisms, that in and of itself is a technocratic deal-breaker? That the effects on global public health from giving tobacco companies such an anti-regulatory shield make it unlikely that there are any net benefits to global society from the TPP?

Danny Hakim: U.S. Chamber of Commerce Works Globally to Fight Antismoking Measures: “In Washington, the U.S. Chamber’s tobacco lobbying has been visible in the negotiations over the Trans-Pacific Partnership…

…One of the more controversial proposals would expand the power of companies to sue countries if they violate trade rules. The U.S. Chamber has openly opposed plans to withhold such powers from tobacco companies, curbing their ability to challenge national antismoking laws. The chamber says on its website that ‘singling out tobacco’ will ‘open a Pandora’s box as other governments go after their particular bêtes noires.’… Mr. Donohue, the chamber’s head, sought to raise the issue in 2012 directly with Ron Kirk, who was then the United States trade representative…. Mr. Kirk is now a senior lawyer at Gibson, Dunn, a firm that counts the tobacco industry as a client. He said… [he] could not recall a specific conversation on tobacco…. The chamber declined to make Mr. Donohue available for an interview.

Must-Read: Caroline Freund and Sarah Oliver: Gains from Harmonizing US and EU Auto Regulations under the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership

Must-Read: Caroline Freund and Sarah Oliver: Gains from Harmonizing US and EU Auto Regulations under the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership: “The removal of regulatory differences in autos…

…is estimated to increase trade by 20 percent or more. The effect on trade from harmonizing standards is only slightly smaller than the effect of EU accession on auto trade. The large economic gains from regulatory harmonization imply that TTIP has the potential to improve productivity while lowering prices and enhancing variety for consumers.

Must-Read: David Atkins: Another Opportunity to Test Who is Right About the Economy

Must-Read: David Atkins (December 2014): Another Opportunity to Test Who is Right About the Economy: “Both academic studies and everyday experience are increasingly showing…

…that voodoo economics just doesn’t work, even as Republicans double down on their fantasy budget scoring. Sam Brownback’s abject failure in Kansas is yet another data point, as is the exposure of red states that have over-relied on the fossil fuel economy while pretending their short-lived growth was the product of royalist economics. Well, now more progressive states will have an opportunity to prove out the advantage of demand-side economics once again with upcoming increases to the minimum wage:

The minimum wage will rise in 20 states and the District of Columbia… with the start of the new year…. In 11 states and D.C., the rise is the result of legislative action or voter-approved referenda…. The size of the hikes range from 12 cents in Florida to $1.25 in South Dakota. Among those states hiking the minimum wage, Washington state’s will be highest at $9.47. Oregon’s is next at $9.25….

I’m looking forward to the test, and expect good results.

Must-Read: Martin Wolf: The Difficult Choices Facing the Greeks

Must-Read: I do not know enough about the Greek situation to have an informed view. But if now is not the time for Greece to undertake a large-scale sovereign default, exit from the eurozone, and devalue, when would be the time? Continued cooperation with a Troika that wants Greece to run large surpluses would seem worse for Greece than a resort to cash-on-the-barrelhead balanced trade. And there seems no upside for the Troika: no German is made materially better off by a deeper depression in Greece.

Martin Wolf: The Difficult Choices Facing the Greeks: “The Syriza government has failed to put forward a credible programme… has instead made populist gestures…

…It is, in brief, a dreadful government produced by desperate times. Yet the eurozone, too, deserves substantial blame for the outcome. One would never guess from its rhetoric that Germany was a serial defaulter in the 20th century. Moreover, there is no democracy, including the UK, whose politics would survive such a huge depression unscathed…. Syriza is the outcome of infantile and irresponsible Greek politics. But it is also the result of blunders committed by the creditors since 2010 and, above all, insistence on bailing out Greece’s foolish private creditors at the expense of the Greek people. Yet all these mistakes are now sunk costs….

[The Troika] seems to demand a move from a primary fiscal balance (before interest) of close to zero this year to a surplus of 3.5 per cent of gross domestic product by 2018… [and thus] fiscal measures that would raise the equivalent of 7 per cent of GDP and shrink the economy by 10 per cent. One does not put an overweight patient on a starvation diet just after a heart attack. Greece needs growth. Indeed, the economic collapse explains why its public debt has exploded relative to GDP….

Greek voter[s], face a choice…. The devil is… the never-ending demands of the eurozone for further austerity…. The deep blue sea is sovereign default and monetary sovereignty. If I am Prime Minister Alexis Tsipras, I think there is a third way–endless bailouts and few conditions. But I am sure he is deluded. So which would I choose? Being cautious I would be tempted to stick with the devil I know. but I might well do better to risk the sea.

A key tool to fight housing inequality remains intact

Supreme Court Justice Anthony Kennedy summed up the need to continue to combat housing inequality in the United States succinctly late last month. “De jure residential segregation by race was declared unconstitutional almost a century ago,” he said, “but its vestiges remain today, intertwined with the country’s economic and social life.”

Justice Kennedy’s majority opinion in Texas Department of Housing and Community Affairs v. The Inclusive Communities Project, Inc. upheld the “disparate impact” portion of the Fair Housing Act of 1968. Disparate impact allows plaintiffs to challenge housing-related policies of governments or private entities if they have a discriminatory affect—even if the discrimination is not intentional. The case before the Supreme Court involved a dispute over whether low-income housing for predominately black Dallas residents should be built in the city or the suburbs. In its majority opinion, the Supreme Court upheld the standard that a policy need not be intentionally discriminatory to be challenged, but the plaintiff does need to provide evidence of discriminatory effects.

Given recent research on the persistence of racial and economic segregation over the past two decades, it might be worth a look at how policies affect the persistence of discrimination, whether intentional or not. The report “Neighborhood Income Composition by Household Race and Income, 1990-2009” examines how race and income interact in neighborhoods. Scholars Sean Reardon at Stanford University, and Lindsay Fox and Joseph Townsend at the Center for Education Policy Analysis find that middle-class black and Latino households (with annual incomes around $55,000-$66,000) tend to live in neighborhoods with incomes similar to those in very poor white households (around $12,000) live. Additionally, even high-income black and Latino households do not live in the same kinds of neighborhoods as white households with similar incomes.

At least part of this is because black and Latino middle-class households are more likely to live in neighborhoods that contain a larger proportion of black and Latino residents than similarly economically situated white households. The reasons for this kind of segregation could vary—personal choice and discrimination, intentional or not, come to mind as motivators for the differences. And the court’s defense of disparate impact comes as a boon to those advocates working against segregation.

But how these disparities manifest themselves in our economy are of great importance and must be addressed. If, as Harvard University economist Raj Chetty posits, where you grow up matters for future success, then these disparities could be affecting significant portions of the population more severely than previously thought. That is not to say that mixed-income black and Latino neighborhoods should not exist. But insofar as the households in these neighborhoods are unable to achieve success, policymakers ought to be concerned.

Reardon, Fox, and Townsend point to a growing body of research that suggest that long-term exposure to neighborhood poverty affects child development, educational success, mental health, and adult earnings. This means that black and Latino families, which already have lower average incomes that white and Asian households, may face compounded deleterious effects based on the neighborhoods they tend to live in.

In upholding disparate impact, the Supreme Court took a major step toward preserving more inclusive communities. But given the realities of persistent economic and racial segregation, more must be done to ensure that residents of neighborhoods throughout the country are able to thrive, and to participate in the growth of the U.S. economy.