Must-Read: Paul Krugman: Obamacare and the Cockroaches

Must-Read: Still looking, without success, for conservatives at think tanks willing to be reality-based on health care…

Paul Krugman: Obamacare and the Cockroaches: “Zombie ideas are claims that should have been killed by evidence…

…but just keep shambling along, like the notion that vast numbers of Canadians, frustrated by socialized medicine, come to America in search of treatment…. Cockroaches are claims that disappear for a while when proved ludicrously wrong, but just keep on coming back…. The notion that Obamacare hasn’t really reduced the number of uninsured as a cockroach… [and] is back, as Charles Gaba notes. He says that Avik Roy’s latest is embarrassing, which I guess it is–but how much more embarrassed can the guy who did the totally spurious work on ‘rate shock’ get? I’d say, rather, that the latest is impressive in the way it uses multiple layers of misrepresentation to obscure what you might have thought was too obvious to deny…

Obamacare and the Cockroaches The New York Times

Must-Read: Ryan Cooper: How Climate Change Ate Conservatism’s Smartest Thinkers

Must-Read: It is important to note that global warming is not unique here. There has been no sign of the reemergence of technocratic voices on the right in health care, macroeconomics, anti-poverty policy, inequality, or–increasingly–national security..

Ryan Cooper: How Climate Change Ate Conservatism’s Smartest Thinkers: “Ross Douthat grappled yesterday with the issue, arguing that…

…he’s basically okay with doing nothing….

We could be wrong; indeed, we could be badly wrong, in which case we’ll deserve to be judged harshly for misplacing priorities in the face of real perils, real threats. But on the evidence available [at] the moment, I’m willing to argue that we have our priorities in order, and the other side’s allegedly forward-looking agenda does not….

Like Clive Crook, Will Wilkinson, and Walter Russell Mead, Douthat doesn’t seriously engage with the evidence… constructs a lengthy Rube Goldberg analogy to ‘insurance’… to cast doubt on every portion of the climate hawk case, but he doesn’t take the obvious next step of trying to work through what that means on a quantitative basis…. Without numbers, Douthat’s case is nothing more than vague handwaving that reads very much like he has cherry-picked a bunch of disconnected fluff to justify doing nothing…. Saying we can chance 3 to 4 degrees of warming and that sensitivity is much lower than previously thought might give us enough space to push CO2 concentrations up to 5-600 ppm or so. But right now we’re barreling towards 1000 ppm and beyond….

Like Douthat, the few conservatives who even talk about climate (like Reihan Salam and Ramesh Ponnuru, who he mentions) are constantly saying whatever policy is on deck at the moment is no good. It’s too inefficient; it’s too expensive; it’s trampling on democracy; we should be doing technology instead, etc, etc…. Consistent advocacy against every single climate policy amounts to little more than putting a patina of credibility on the denialist views of the Republican majority.

Must-Read: Kevin Hoover: The Methodology of Empirical Macroeconomics

Must-Read: Yes. The combination of representative-agent modeling and utility-based “microfoundations” was always a game of intellectual Three-Card Monte. Why do you ask? Why don’t we fund sociologists to investigate for what reasons–other than being almost guaranteed to produce conclusions ideologically-pleasing to some–it has flourished for a generation in spite of having no empirical support and no theoretical coherence?

Kevin Hoover: The Methodology of Empirical Macroeconomics: “Given what we know about representative-agent models…

…there is not the slightest reason for us to think that the conditions under which they should work are fulfilled. The claim that representative-agent models provide microfundations succeeds only when we steadfastly avoid the fact that representative-agent models are just as aggregative as old-fashioned Keynesian macroeconometric models. They do not solve the problem of aggregation; rather they assume that it can be ignored. While they appear to use the mathematics of microeconomics, the subjects to which they apply that microeconomics are aggregates that do not belong to any [really-existing] agent. There is no agent who maximizes a utility function that represents the whole economy subject to a budget constraint that takes GDP as its limiting quantity. This is the simulacrum of microeconomics, not the genuine article.…

[W]e should conclude that what happens to the microeconomy is relevant to the macroeconomy but that macroeconomics has its own modes of analysis.… [I]t is almost certain that macroeconomics cannot be euthanized or eliminated. It shall remain necessary for the serious economist to switch back and forth between microeconomics and a relatively autonomous macroeconomics depending upon the problem in hand.

Must-Read: Dani Rodrik: When Economics Works and When it Doesn’t

Must-Read: I wonder: There is an awful lot of bad right-wing economics. There is much less bad left-wing economics. But if the left wing were stronger as a political movement–as strong as the right wing–would there be as much bad left- as right-wing economics. I suspect not, but that is merely a guess. But if it is a correct guess, the next question is: “Why?”

Mark Thoma sends us to Dani Rodrik: When Economics Works and When it Doesn’t: “If we take as our central model one under which the efficient markets hypothesis is correct…

…in the run-up to the financial crisis… the steady increase in house prices or the growth of the shadow banking system… wouldn’t have bothered you at all. You’d tell a story about how wonderful financial liberalisation and innovation are…. But if you took the same [set of] facts, and applied the kind of models that people who had been looking at sovereign debt crises in emerging markets had been developing… you’d get a very different kind of story. I wish we’d put greater weight on stories of the second kind rather than the first. We’d have been better off if we’d done so…

The Earned Income Tax Credit

The Earned Income Tax Credit is a federal refundable tax credit designed to encourage work, offset federal payroll and income taxes, and raise living standards for low- and middle-income working families. Introduced in 1975, the EITC has grown to be one of the largest and least controversial elements of the U.S. welfare state, with 26.7 million recipients sharing $63 billion in total federal EITC expenditures in 2013.

The placement of the EITC within the tax code has three important effects:

  1. It provides a simple means of administering the credit without the large overhead of caseworkers and other staff needed for traditional means-tested spending.
  2. It symbolically links the credit to participation in the formal economy—non-workers are ineligible. This is also an important source of popularity among politicians and policymakers on both sides of the aisle, and also likely reduces the “stigma” that attaches to recipients of traditional welfare.
  3. Tax credits are not always perceived as spending, and may not count toward congressional spending caps.

The broad political support is buoyed by an expansive academic literature that details the EITC’s benefits. Research over the past two decades has documented large increases in net incomes for low-income families who work, and startling improvement in the well-being of children in those families. EITC expansions of the 1990s dramatically increased work among single parents as well (though the expansions may have had much smaller negative effects on the employment of secondary earners in married couples). Recent research has also found extremely important benefits for children’s educational achievement and attainment.

This brief will provide an overview of the academic research evaluating the EITC’s success in boosting well-being, reducing poverty, and encouraging work among working parents. It will also detail some unintended consequences of the EITC, and provide a brief outline of proposed modifications.

View full PDF here alongside all endnotes

Who is eligible for the Earned Income Tax Credit, and for how much?

The EITC primarily goes to working parents with children, although a small number of childless individuals are also eligible. In the 2015 tax year, families with incomes below $29,000 to $53,300 (depending on the number of children and marital status) were eligible. For childless individuals, the threshold is $14,820 (or $20,300 for a married couple), and the credit is much smaller. (See Table 1 in Appendix.)

The size of the credit is dependent on how much a worker earns, the family structure (married or single), and the number of children. (See Figure 1.) For each family type, the credit is a fixed percentage of earnings until it reaches its maximum. Beyond this point, the credit is unchanged even as earnings continue to rise. For a married couple with two children, this “plateau” range spans earnings from $13,870 and $23,630, over which the credit is a constant $5,548. The credit then phases out until it reaches zero, at an earnings level of $49,974 for a married couple with two children.

In addition to the federal Earned Income Tax Credit, a number of states have incorporated EITCs into their own tax systems. These states typically offer a refundable (but sometimes non-refundable) credit equal to a percentage of the tax filer’s federal EITC. As of now, 26 states and the District of Columbia have their own EITC programs, ranging from 4 percent (for a family with one child in Wisconsin) to 40 percent (Washington, D.C.) of the federal credit. California is the most recent state to add a state EITC, with a program that takes effect in tax year 2015.

Does the Earned Income Tax Credit encourage work?

The EITC’s structure can be expected to encourage work among single parents, but to discourage it for many would-be secondary earners in married couples. Among workers, some face incentives to work more while many more face incentives to work less.

We begin with the case of a single parent faced with a decision whether to work at all. If she does not work, she will not receive an EITC (although she may receive Temporary Assistance for Needy Families, food stamps, or other transfers). If she does work and her earnings are less than $44,454 (for a two-child family), she will receive a positive EITC. This will partially offset other income taxes if any are owed, and will be refunded if they are not. Clearly, the EITC tilts this decision in favor of working, dramatically so for an individual with potential earnings below the end of the plateau range (which is $13,870 in 2015 for a single mother with two children).

For married couples, the effect can be the opposite. If one spouse makes enough to take the family out of the phase-in range on their own, then the second earner can only reduce the family’s credit by working. And while families in the phase-in range are encouraged to work more, those in the phase-out range may be encouraged to work less in order to be eligible for a larger EITC payment.

A large body of literature empirically examines the labor supply effects of the EITC expansion in the 1990s. Essentially all of the studies agree that this expansion led to sizeable increases in single mothers’ employment rates, concentrated among less-skilled women and among those with more than one qualifying child. There is some evidence of declines in married women’s labor supply, but this effect is unambiguously smaller.

What are the unintended consequences of the Earned Income Tax Credit?

Standard public economic theory implies that a negative effective tax rate that encourages more people to work will lead to a decline in overall pre-tax wages. This implies that a portion of the money spent on the EITC actually benefits employers of EITC recipients and of other workers competing in the same labor market as the recipients. This means that the EITC (like any other policy that increases labor supply, importantly including welfare work requirements) functions in part as a subsidy to employers of the workers in question. As the target recipients of the EITC tend to be relatively low income, the employer share of the benefit flows to employers of low-skill labor.

One implication is that the minimum wage can be an efficient complement to the EITC, improving the latter’s effectiveness by limiting employers’ ability to capture the credit. This runs contrary to many policy discussions in which minimum wage opponents point to the EITC as a superior alternative. Incidence considerations imply that the two policies are best thought as complements rather than substitutes, and that EITC increases strengthen the case for raising the minimum wage.

How does the Earned Income Tax Credit help the well-being of low-income working families?

Poverty

The EITC is extremely successful as an anti-poverty program. Credit eligibility is concentrated among families whose incomes (after taxes and transfers) would otherwise be between 75 percent and 150 percent of the poverty line, and take-up rates are substantially higher than in many other anti-poverty programs.

The dramatic expansion of the EITC in the mid-1990s was associated with a decline in child poverty rates in the United States (though this was almost completely reversed during the Great Recession). There were a number of causes for this decline—welfare reform and the strong economy of that period among them—but several studies have found that the EITC was an important contributor to the reduction in poverty due to its work incentives. The Census Bureau’s Supplemental Poverty Measure estimates that the poverty rate was 15.5 percent in 2013, but would have been 18.4 percent without the EITC and Child Tax Credit.

This estimate does not count the extra earnings that EITC recipients have due to their increased work. Hilary Hoynes of the University of California-Berkeley and Ankur Patel of the U.S. Treasury Department find that labor supply effects approximately double the EITC’s anti-poverty effectiveness, and that the mid-1990s expansion reduced the share of families below the poverty line by 7.9 percentage points.

The program’s effect on child poverty is even stronger: The poverty rate for those under 18 years of age was 16.4 percent, but (again ignoring labor supply responses) would have been 22.8 percent without the refundable tax credit. Based on these numbers, the EITC can be credited with lifting 9.1 million people—including 4.7 million children—out of poverty. The effects on total poverty are far larger than those of any single program except Social Security, and the effects on child poverty are the largest without exception. Again, accounting for the program’s effects on employment and earnings would lead to even larger anti-poverty effects.

Children’s educational outcomes

There is robust evidence that the EITC has quite large effects on children’s academic achievement and attainment, with potentially important consequences for later-life outcomes. Gordon Dahl of the University of California, San Diego and Lance Lochner of the University of Western Ontario find that EITC income raises combined math and reading test scores by about 6 percent of a standard deviation per $1,000 received. The EITC test score impacts appear to be larger for boys, children under 12, black or Hispanic children, and for children whose parents are unmarried. Effects of this magnitude are likely to translate into substantially better life outcomes.

There is also evidence of effects on the amount of education obtained, as distinct from achievement on standardized tests. The University of Michigan’s Katherine Michelmore found that a $1,000 increase in the maximum EITC is associated with 18- to 23-year-olds in likely EITC-eligible households being one percentage point more likely to have ever enrolled in college, and 0.3 percentage points more likely to complete a bachelor’s degree. A rough estimate of the present value of a college degree is $1 million, meaning that a 0.3 percent increase in college graduation is worth about $3,000. That means the return is about 3-to-1 for the initial investment—a large effect, especially considering that college graduation rates are not the main intention of the EITC to begin with. Similarly, Day Manoli of the University of Texas-Austin and Nick Turner of the Treasury Department also find that an extra $1,000 of EITC rebate in the senior year of high school increases college enrollment by 0.2 to 0.3 percentage points.

Health

William Evans of the University of Notre Dame and Craig Garthwaite of Northwestern University examine the EITC’s effects on women’s health before and after the 1993 expansion, finding that women reported improved mental and physical health. The expansion also led to sizable improvements in infant and child health. Hilary Hoynes; Douglas Miller of the University of California-Davis; and David Simon of the University of Connecticut find that the EITC expansion reduced the incidence of low birth weight, a widely used indicator of poor infant health.

What are some proposed modifications to the Earned Income Tax Credit?

Changes within the same basic structure

There have been a number of proposals to expand the EITC either as a whole or for particular groups. Recently, these discussions have centered on temporary EITC expansions (a larger credit for three-child families and an extended schedule for married couples) introduced in 2009, which are due to expire in 2017.

One area of concern has been incentives for non-custodial parents, or parents who do not have primary custody of their children. A focus in this area has been to create incentives for the payment of child support, by allowing these parents to receive the credit but conditioning it on the payment of child support. Non-custodial parent credits have recently been implemented in New York and Washington, D.C. An evaluation of the New York program by Austin Nichols, Elaine Sorenson, and Kye Lippold at the Urban Institute found increased work and payment of child support among non-custodial parents eligible for the credit.

A more consequential change would be to expand the EITC for childless workers more generally. This has attracted support of late from President Obama as well as prominent Republicans (notably Representative Paul Ryan (R-WI), now Speaker of the House). President Obama’s most recent proposal, part of his 2016 budget, would double the childless worker credit and extend the age ranges at which taxpayers are eligible. Work I did earlier this year with Hilary Hoynes examines the distributional impacts of the Obama proposal and of a more aggressive proposal that would bring the childless EITC to parity with that available to families with children.

Gordon Berlin, president of MDRC (a non-profit social policy research organization), proposes a more radical modification in the structure of the EITC. He would make EITC eligibility depend on individual earnings, without regard to marriage or children. This would eliminate the second worker penalty, alter marriage incentives, and generate tens of billions of dollars in additional credit payments, mostly to married couples. The expansion of the plateau phase for taxpayers married filing jointly during the 2000s have made the proposal cheaper to implement, but budgetary concerns make implementation of the proposal unlikely. A somewhat less aggressive proposal comes from the Hamilton Project’s Melissa Kearney and Lesley Turner, who propose a secondary earner deduction that would reduce but not eliminate the second worker penalty in the EITC.

There are also several recent proposals for a new EITC aimed exclusively at workers with a documented work-limiting disability, aimed at increasing employment of those with disabilities and thereby reducing strain on the Social Security Disability Insurance trust fund. Two studies done by Jun Huang of Columbia Business School and Maximillian Schmeiser at the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, as well as Boston College’s Matthew Rutledge, examine the likely impact of EITC expansion on people with work-limiting disabilities and find an increase in labor force participation among workers with resident children compared to those without.

Administration of the Earned Income Tax Credit

Many EITC recipients hire tax preparers to help file their taxes. In fact, the IRS estimates that 15 million EITC recipients used paid tax preparers in 2013, and one study estimates total tax preparation fees at $2.75 billion. Until recently, many of these for-profit preparers were also in the business of marketing short-term loans (known as refund anticipation loans) against eventual EITC refunds, at very high implicit tax rates.

Recent bank regulation efforts have largely eliminated refund anticipation loans, although there are still other financial products designed to capture a portion of the tax refund. The IRS encourages claimants to simply write “EITC” on their tax returns rather than attempting to calculate it, presumably in part to simplify returns so that recipients do not need to engage preparers. Moreover, not-for-profit tax preparation services exist in many areas. Nevertheless, the high cost to recipients of tax filing services remains a concern.

A second administration issue relates to the EITC’s arrival as a lump-sum payment, months after the period that it nominally covers. It seems clear that the EITC would be more effective in supporting low-income families if it could somehow be delivered more evenly throughout the year. Until 2011, EITC recipients could choose to receive a portion of their credit with each paycheck rather than as a lump sum at tax filing time via the Advance EITC program. But take-up of this option was very low—only 1 percent to 2 percent of EITC claimants—leading to its cancellation. The reasons for this are not well understood. Thus, while there is the desire to change the method of payment, I am not aware of workable proposals to do so.

Conclusion

The Earned Income Tax Credit has become the centerpiece of the U.S. safety net, surpassing all other transfer programs (save perhaps Social Security) in the number of beneficiaries, total expenditures, or poverty reduction impacts. The evidence clearly indicates that it is a remarkably successful program, with important impacts on recipients’ labor supply and health and on their children’s health and educational outcomes.

Appendix

Photo of mother and daughter, veer.com

Must-Read: Zack Cooper et al.: The Price Ain’t Right? Hospital Prices and Health Spending on the Privately Insured

Must-Read: Yes. Constraining hospital and doctor-group market power is very important to creating a more efficient health-care system. Why do you ask?:

Zack Cooper et al.: The Price Ain’t Right? Hospital Prices and Health Spending on the Privately Insured: “Insurance claims data for 27.6 percent of individuals with private employer-sponsored insurance in the US…

…between 2007 and 2011… [shows] the variation in hospital prices within and across geographic areas…. First, health care spending per privately insured beneficiary varies by a factor of three across the 306 Hospital Referral Regions (HRRs) in the US…. The correlation… [with] Medicare… across HRRs is only 0.14. Second, variation in providers’ transaction prices across HRRs is the primary driver of spending variation for the privately insured, whereas variation in the quantity of care provided across HRRs is the primary driver of Medicare spending variation…. Third, we document large dispersion in overall inpatient hospital prices and in prices for seven relatively homogenous procedures…. Finally, hospital prices are positively associated with indicators of hospital market power… prices in monopoly markets are 15.3 percent higher than those in markets with four or more hospitals.

Must-Read: Nick Bunker: Trying to Get a Grip on the “Gig Economy”

Must-Read: Our smart young Equitable Growth whippersnapper Nick Bunker reads Dourado and Koopman and, correctly, sees the “gig economy” as a positive way of trying to turn our current sow’s ear of a low-pressure labor market into some reasonable facsimile of a silk purse. When put that way, what we need is not a halfway house between W-2 employees and 1099 independent contractors, but more expansionary monetary and fiscal policy:

Nick Bunker: Trying to Get a Grip on the “Gig Economy”: “The trend… starts around the year 2000…

…The sharing economy companies didn’t get started until at least eight years later… follows rather than causes the bulk of the increase in independent contracting. Dourado and Koopman point out that business dynamism… began to decline around 2000 as businesses stopped creating jobs at the rate they once did. These new gig-based or sharing economy businesses seem to be seizing the opportunity created by a structural change in the U.S. labor market rather than causing it…. If we want to understand this trend, perhaps we should change the focus of our investigations.

The upside of expanding access to the Earned Income Tax Credit

With the end of the year approaching, Congress has been concentrating on extending a package of tax code provisions known collectively as the “tax extenders.” The bill, which seems likely to pass, includes a number of tax credits and deductions that run the gamut from a credit for research and development, a break for Broadway shows, and some provisions left over the from the 2009 Recovery and Reinvestment Act.

One provision in the debate is the Earned Income Tax Credit, or EITC, with a temporary boost to the program being considered for permanent status. The credit is a key part—perhaps the key part—of U.S. antipoverty efforts at the moment. But while it’s done quite a bit of work in reducing the amount of Americans in poverty, it clearly has room for improvement—namely regarding who is eligible for the credit.

Among certain policymakers and researchers, a consensus of sort has emerged that workers without children should also be fully eligible for the Earned Income Tax Credit. Because the program was originally intended for workers with children, specifically mothers, workers without children don’t currently have access to the full extent of the tax credit. Given the success of the program, expanding access makes sense.

It’s worth noting, however, that these workers won’t simply go from being unaffected by the program to getting a benefit. In fact, given the structure of the Earned Income Tax Credit, some of them have seen their wages depressed by the program. Expanding access to the tax credit will rectify this problem.

When thinking about the benefits of a tax increase, cut, credit, or deduction, always remember to consider the incidence. Policymakers may raise or lower a tax rate in hopes of affecting one group of people, but the actual harm or benefit from the change might not fall directly on said group. The burden of sales taxes, for example, isn’t borne by retailers but rather passed onto consumers in the form of higher prices.

When it comes to the Earned Income Tax Credit, the full value doesn’t go to the worker. According to research by economist Jesse Rothstein of the University of California, Berkeley, employers capture about 36 percent of the value of the tax credit. By encouraging more people to enter the labor force, the EITC boosts the labor supply and pushes down wages. Employers then get to employ labor at a lower wage, and that’s how they capture some of the incidence. Workers who are eligible for the EITC see a net increase in their after-tax income, but ineligible or non-participating workers see a decrease in their incomes as they have only their wages as income and don’t get the tax credit. Allowing these workers to get the EITC would rectify this problem.

At the same time, given this partial capture of the tax credit via lower wages, policymakers might want to consider other ways to shift the bargaining power of workers. One way would be increasing the minimum wage, which would also prevent the partial capture. A higher minimum wage and an expanded Earned Income Tax Credit are complementary policies, rather than substitutes for each other. At the same time, a policy like the EITC might be less effective during a period of slack labor market. So fiscal and monetary policy geared toward full employment would be a good complement. The Earned Income Tax Credit is far from perfect, but it is quite good. Building on its success, expanding complementary programs, and applying its lessons to other programs are all things policymakers should consider in the year ahead.

Update 1:54 PM on 12/15/2015: For readers interested in more information on the EITC, check out Jesse Rothstein’s recently published Equitable Growth brief on the issue.

 

(Morgan Lane Photography/Veer Photo)

Trying to get a grip on the gig economy

If headlines on websites and anecdotes from residents of major urban areas were evidence, the rising importance of the gig economy would be without doubt. But the plural of anecdote isn’t data. Amid the growing hype about “sharing economy” companies such as Uber, Airbnb, and TaskRabbit, analysts have gone to the available data to see if this trend is actually important for the overall economy. The evidence so far has been less than kind to the excitement over the immediate transformation of the U.S. labor market into a gig economy. But even if these companies end up being important players in the years to come, they certainly are not the catalyst of radical change right now.

The first place analysts turned to in order to evaluate the gig economy was survey data—specifically, data from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.  Josh Zumbrun and Anna Louie Sussman of the Wall Street Journal and Adam Ozimek of Moody’s Analytics took a look at the BLS data and found no evidence of an increasing amount of workers registering as self-employed or freelancing, or even that these workers make up a large share of the nation’s labor force. The share of U.S. workers that are self-employed is about 6 percent, according to one BLS data series.

A study by the Freelancers Union and Upwork last year, however, found a much larger role for self-employment. The study claimed that 53 million workers, or about a third of all U.S. workers, were freelancers in 2014. That’s a headline-grabbing number, but as Larry Mishel of the Economic Policy Institute shows, the data are a bit overstated. In short, the study considers anyone who made any money outside of a traditional employment situation a “freelancer,” but doesn’t consider whether that work is the person’s main source of income. Only about 35 percent of the study’s “freelancers” are independent contractors who support themselves through independent work. That group of workers only makes up 12 percent of the workforce.

Another way to look at this question is to look at tax data on contractors. The kind of tax form generated by a working relationship—a W-2 for traditional employment and a 1099 for contract work—can give an estimate of the relationship between the two kinds of employment. In a new paper for the Mercatus Center at George Mason University, Eli Dourado and Christopher Koopman look at the trends in the number of these forms using data from the Internal Revenue Service. They find that, since 2000, there has been a significant increase in the number of a certain kind of 1099 forms (1099-MISC) as the growth in W-2 forms has stagnated. The absolute number of W-2 forms is still much larger, however, than the number of 1099s. Other research has found a similar trend.

What’s particularly interesting about the trend Dourado and Koopman find is that it starts around the year 2000. The sharing economy companies didn’t get started until at least eight years later. That means the rise of sharing economy companies follows rather than causes the bulk of the increase in independent contracting. Dourado and Koopman point out that business dynamism—the rate at which new businesses are started—began to decline around 2000 as businesses stopped creating jobs at the rate they once did. These new gig-based or sharing economy businesses seem to be seizing the opportunity created by a structural change in the U.S. labor market rather than causing it.

Where does this leave us on the importance of the gig economy? The data show that independent contractors won’t become a major share of workers anytime soon. And while the number of contractors may have increased in recent years, sharing economy companies aren’t the likely cause. If we want to understand this trend, perhaps we should change the focus of our investigations.

(AP Photo/Jeff Chiu)

Must-Reads: December 14, 2015

  • Steve Greenhouse:
    A Safety Net for On-Demand Workers?: “With Los Angeles having approved a $15-an-hour minimum wage and with many Uber drivers netting considerably less than that per hour, why exactly shouldn’t drivers be covered—and protected—by minimum wage laws?”
  • Miriam Ronzoni: Where Are the Power Relations in Piketty’s Capital?: “There seems to be a friction between the diagnosis… of the power of capital… and the suggested cure… [of] well-minded citizens… recogniz[ing] the… problem” :: The extremely-sharp Miriam Ronzoni excellently puts her finger on a substantial hole in Thomas Piketty’s _Capital in the Twenty-First Century_…
  • Ananya Roy: The Land Question: “The infrastructure problem, it turns out, is effectively a land problem…”
  • David Roberts: Why Conspiracy Theories Flourish on the Right: “The most engaged conservative voters… won’t trust conservative elites any more than they trust liberals, scientists, or the media…”
  • Matt Bruenig: Why Education Does Not Fix Poverty: “To the extent that education does nothing to provide better income support for those who do find themselves in these vulnerable situations, its effect on overall poverty levels will always be weak, or, as with the US in the last 23 years, totally nonexistent…”
  • Mark Thoma: Why It’s Tricky for Fed Officials to Talk Politically: “I think I disagree with Brad DeLong…” :: I would beg the highly-esteemed Mark Thoma to draw a distinction here between “inappropriate” and unwise…
  • Matthew Yglesias: Trumpism Is a Natural Consequence of the GOP Refusing to Moderate on Taxes or Immigration: “There has been no meaningful move to the center on economics, and–as predicted–the results are ugly…” :: “[Republicanism] is almost like you are in a religion…you are not leaving your religion…
  • Ben Thompson: Digital Dopamine: As someone who in 1993 put my copy of “Civilization” in the microwave, on the grounds that I could be either a computer-game addict or a deputy secretary of the Treasury, but probably not both, I have very mixed feelings about this…
  • Robert Johnson, Brad DeLong, Linda Bilmes, and Steve Clemons: Connecting American Foreign Policy to Economic Policy: “How might a reimagined American foreign policy… bolster the… economy…?”
  • Steve Roth (2014): The Pernicious Prison of the Price Theory Paradigm: “Steve explains it all far better, with circles and arrows and a paragraph on the back of each one…”