Must-Read: Dean Baker: Stanley Fischer Rewrites Fed Inflation Target, Prepares to Throw People Out of Work

Must-Read: Stanley Fischer is off message. The right message for Stanley Fischer to be saying right now is not: “We are close to our targets… within hailing distance…”

Personal consumption expenditures Market based PCE excluding food and energy chain type price index FRED St Louis Fed

The right message is:

  1. We are deeply disappointed in our failure to hit our inflation target over the past five years.
  2. By the end of this year, our failure will have left us with a price level 3% lower than we had committed to trying to attain back at the end of 2010.
  3. That means a 3% higher real debt burden on all those who borrowed than they–trusting us–planned for back in 2010.
  4. That means a 3% windfall for all those who loaned.
  5. In fact, since 1995 we have undershot our cumulative target by 7%.
  6. Thus those who believe that our 2%/year target is not an average but a ceiling have some evidence on their side.
  7. Nevertheless, we regard 2%/year not as a ceiling but as an average going forward.
  8. And we will strive to do better in the future than we have in the past.
  9. We will strive as hard as we can to have inflation on a core PCE basis average 2% per year over the next five years.
  10. We really could use some help from more expansionary fiscal policy.
  11. Please hold us accountable.

Dean Baker: Stanley Fischer Rewrites Fed Inflation Target, Prepares to Throw People Out of Work:

MarketWatch…. quotes Stanley Fischer… as saying, “We are close to our targets” for inflation and unemployment…

…that the current 1.6 percent inflation rate shown by the core personal consumption expenditure (PCE) deflator is “is within hailing distance” of the Fed’s 2.0 percent target…. [But] the 2.0 percent target was always identified as an average, not a ceiling. This means that periods of below 2.0 percent inflation should be averaged out with periods of above 2.0 percent inflation…. The year over year measure of the core inflation rate since the beginning of 2011. Not only has it been below 2.0 percent for the last four years, it shows no tendency to increase….

I Do Not Understand the View from the Financial Markets…

I want to say that people like Global Head of Credit Products Strategy at Citigroup Matt King are simply not thinking clearly. The macroeconomic regularities that seem obvious to me simply are not there to him. What he ought to be saying is:

  1. Mammoth safe asset shortage–in large part because since 2007 nobody trusts any of his peers’ issuing departments to create a AAA asset.
  2. Hence destructively low yields.
  3. Hence those that can need to bend every policy nerve toward creating large amounts of safe assets–which means borrow-and-spend on the part of governments: expansionary fiscal policy.

But that is rarely what he or his peers are saying. Thus I hesitate. Could they possibly be misreading the situation in such an obvious way? What are they seeing and thinking about that I am missing?

Thus I never know what to do with pieces like this:

Alexandra Scaggs: There’s No Yield, and Citi Isn’t Going to Take It Anymore:

Citi’s Matt King has some harsh words for central bankers… echoes a group of fund managers who say central banks’ stimulus efforts are distorting the way global markets function…. With negative yields on $13 trillion of safe assets, investment managers are crowding into the shrinking group of investments with yield–or into securities they may be able to sell to central banks. This has been frustrating for those fund managers, to say the least…. Here are some of the reasons he thinks markets are broken:

(1) A greater share of global equity-market variance is explained by macro factors…. (2) Credit spreads aren’t responding to climbing leverage and defaults…. (3) Normal market relationships are breaking down…. (4) Cross-asset correlations are high, even though volatility is low….

It’s clear that global central banks have had a big effect on markets. A bigger challenge is answering the following question: so what? Lower borrowing costs should be a benefit of central bank stimulus, you’d think. But King says corporate borrowing isn’t helping the economy as much as policy makers would like, and raises the risk that the leverage will make any economic downturn worse. He continues:

Most doctors–and even patients–know that when a course of drugs seems not to be working, you don’t simply keep on doubling the dosage. This applies particularly when the patient, if no longer as sprightly as they used to be, is nevertheless doing more or less fine. The side effects of such a course are more likely to kill than to cure. Yet this is what central banks now seem intent on doing. They have too much invested in their models to consider changing them in our view…

I look at graphs like this:

FRED Graph FRED St Louis Fed

And I think:

  • If the Fed had followed policies to put short-term safe nominal interest rates at 3%/year right now, then you add on the impact of that on inflation–pushing inflation down from just below 2%/year to just negative–and you have a real value of the dollar in all likelihood 30% more than it is today. Would exports be as high in such a world?

  • If the Fed had followed policies to put short-term safe nominal interest rates at 3%/year right now, then you add on the impact of that on inflation–pushing inflation down from just below 2%/year to just negative–and you have real hurdle rates on business investment on the order of 5%-points/year higher than they are now. Would business investment–which is, in spite of the weak overall economy and sluggish growth, normal– be as high in such a world?

  • If the Fed had followed policies to put short-term safe nominal interest rates at 3%/year right now, then you add on the impact of that on inflation–pushing inflation down from just below 2%/year to just negative–and you have potential homebuyers facing greatly accelerated amortization burdens. Would residential investment–pathetic as it is–be as high in such a world?

If King has a magic wand that can boost government purchases massively, then yes–higher interest rates might well be appropriate. But he doesn’t. So what is the magic wand that would boost what component of spending to offset downward pressure on exports, business investment, residential investment, and consumer durables spending that would come from higher interest rates and lower inflation right now? Or what is the magic wand that would make buyers of exports, planners of business investment, and buyers of new houses from reacting to the signals prices are sending them?

I just do not get it. King seems to envision a world in which interest rates are higher and he is happier because he can clip coupons on his portfolio, and all without anybody changing any of their spending decisions. I do not see how that world can possibly be.

Indeed, I don’t think even King would like the world he says he wants to see: business corporation and real estate equity cushions are ample on average, but in the anti-Panglossian world of bond finance that your counterparties have ample equity cushions on average isn’t worth very much in terms of guaranteeing the quality of the assets you are long, is it?

Must-Read: Alexandra Scaggs: There’s No Yield, and Citi Isn’t Going to Take It Anymore

Must-Read: Alexandra Scaggs: There’s No Yield, and Citi Isn’t Going to Take It Anymore:

Citi’s Matt King has some harsh words for central bankers…

…echoes a group of fund managers who say central banks’ stimulus efforts are distorting the way global markets function…. With negative yields on $13 trillion of safe assets, investment managers are crowding into the shrinking group of investments with yield–or into securities they may be able to sell to central banks. This has been frustrating for those fund managers, to say the least. (This journalist remembers getting laughed at when she asked an expert how to determine the value of a Treasury security, because the Federal Reserve still owns more than $2 trillion of them.) Instead of gauging market fundamentals… investors are primarily concerned with the outlook for central bank policy. So they crowd into trades that could profit off of the actions of central bankers in Europe, Japan or the UK. That’s why Bill Gross and Paul Singer have both bemoaned the effect central banks have had on the global markets and the economy recently. Gross says it’s causing growth to stagnate, and Singer is warning of a sharp reversal.

King agrees. Here are some of the reasons he thinks markets are broken:

(1) A greater share of global equity-market variance is explained by macro factors…. (2) Credit spreads aren’t responding to climbing leverage and defaults…. (3) Normal market relationships are breaking down…. (4) Cross-asset correlations are high, even though volatility is low….

It’s clear that global central banks have had a big effect on markets. A bigger challenge is answering the following question: so what? Lower borrowing costs should be a benefit of central bank stimulus, you’d think. But King says corporate borrowing isn’t helping the economy as much as policy makers would like, and raises the risk that the leverage will make any economic downturn worse. He continues:

Most doctors–and even patients–know that when a course of drugs seems not to be working, you don’t simply keep on doubling the dosage. This applies particularly when the patient, if no longer as sprightly as they used to be, is nevertheless doing more or less fine. The side effects of such a course are more likely to kill than to cure. Yet this is what central banks now seem intent on doing. They have too much invested in their models to consider changing them in our view…

A fresh look at the wage gap on African American women’s Equal Pay Day

Ultraviolet members protest Macy's lobbying against an equal pay bill. They're asking the retail giant to pledge to never lobby against equal pay again. Photo Credit: Melissa Byrne

According to the National Organization for Women, today is African American women’s Equal Pay Day, when African American women will have worked all of 2015 through today—an additional 236 days—in order to earn the same amount that men made last year. In other words, in 2015, on average, black women earned about 63 cents per every dollar earned by a man. This isn’t necessarily surprising given what the research says about pay equity, but it sparked further interest at Equitable Growth to see what the wage gap looks like for African American women up and down the income ladder.

Equitable Growth’s new interactive tool allows for a careful look. Though our interactive’s numbers don’t quite match the National Organization for Women’s Equal Pay Day levels due to methodological differences (primarily, our interactive covers a slightly different time period), they still prove the same point: Men across the board are paid substantially more than African American women. By our calculations, men earn a median wage of $19.61 per hour, while African American women earn a median wage of $14.25, an hourly wage differential of $5.36 or a pay gap of about 38 percent relative to African American women’s hourly rate. (See Figure 1.)

Figure 1

When looking across the wage distribution detailed in Figure 1, the same pattern is clear—men get paid more. Low-wage male workers make about $9.22 per hour compared to the $8.15 earned by low-wage black women, a pay gap of about 13 percent. Near the top, however, the pay gap is substantially larger, approximately 46 percent, with men earning $47.44 and African American women earning $32.50.

These data also demonstrate that the pay gap between men and black women is narrower for workers at the bottom, but widens as a worker moves up the wage distribution. This same pattern also holds when we observe the wage distributions for different genders, races, and ethnicities. (See Figure 2.)

Figure 2

At the bottom of the distribution, low-wage workers from different demographic backgrounds have relatively similar wages. Low-wage Latinas and African American women earn the least ($8.14 and $8.15 per hour, respectively), while low-wage white men earn the most ($10.00). This clustering of wages at the bottom is likely a result of current federal and state minimum wage policies, which legally mandate employees to be paid at least $7.25 per hour (or more, in many states).

For workers in the middle range of each demographic group, the gender gap is bigger. Median-wage Latinas and African American women are the lowest-wage recipients, earning $12.65 and $14.25 per hour, respectively. In contrast, white men earn the highest median wages, making $21.79. At the top, where the gap is largest, the lowest wages are $28.83 (Latinas) and $32.50 (African American women), while the highest wage is $50.54 (white men), a difference of more than $20.00. The spreading out at the top reflects discrimination across both gender and race.

What explains these wage gaps? On one hand, social and cultural norms at work, occupational sex segregation, and a lack of workplace policies, among other factors, play a role in pushing women out of higher-paying jobs. On the other hand, racial discrimination, which appears in hiring practices and other labor market interactions, disproportionately leaves workers of color with lower pay than their white counterparts. African American women (and Latinas) are doubly disadvantaged, as they experience both of these forms of discrimination.

Increasing educational attainment by women of color is probably the most commonly suggested solution to closing the gender wage gap. Yet over the past two decades, women have outpaced men in college enrollment and college enrollment for black women has surged. Despite these gains in education, African American women still earn less. So other solutions would seem to be in order. But first, it’s worthwhile to examine the wage distribution by a worker’s educational attainment. Comparing the earnings of white men with high school degrees to African American women with college degrees shows there are many similarities in their wages despite the much higher level of educational attainment for this group of African American women. (See Figure 3.)

Figure 3

The lowest-paid white men with high school diplomas earn $9.31 per hour, which is only about 15 percent less than the $10.69 earned by African American women with a four-year college degree. At the median, white men with a high school degree make $18.00 per hour, or only about 17 percent less than the $21.08 earned by the median college-educated African American women. Even for the best paid workers in both groups, the pay gap is only about 22 percent, with white male high school graduates receiving $34.79 per hour, compared to $43.27 top-earning African American women with college degrees.

Closing the pay gap for African American women clearly is no simple task. On the policy front, raising the minimum wage and the tipped minimum wage at the federal, state, and local levels would make a positive difference for women of color. So, too, would increased unionization, crackdowns on workplace discrimination, and improved work flexibility and childcare policies. But the wage gap will persist for African American women as long as structural racism goes unaddressed, which admittedly is a more complex and challenging issue. In the meantime, African American women’s Equal Pay Day helps serve as a reminder that much work is left in order to achieve pay equity across gender and race.

Must-Read: Seth Lloyd: Quantum Computer Reality

Must-Read: Seth Lloyd: Quantum Computer Reality:

The 15th-century Renaissance was triggered by a flood of new information which changed how people thought about everything…

The same thing is happening now. All of us have had to shift, just in the last couple decades, from hungry hunters and gatherers of information to overwhelmed information filter-feeders…. Information processing is moving electrons from here to there. But for a “qubit” in a quantum computer, an electron is both here and there…. Thus with “quantum parallelism” you can do massively more computation than in classical computers. It’s like the difference between the simple notes of plainsong and all that a symphony can do….

Quantum computers can solve important problems like enormous equations and factoring–cracking formerly uncrackable public-key cryptography, the basis of all online commerce. With their ability to do “oodles of things at once,” quantum computers can also simulate the behavior of larger quantum systems, opening new frontiers of science, as Richard Feynman pointed out in the 1980s.

Simple quantum computers have been built since 1995, by Lloyd and ever more others. Mechanisms tried so far include: electrons within electric fields; nuclear spin (clockwise and counter); atoms in ground state and excited state simultaneously; photons polarized both horizontally and vertically; and super-conducting loops going clockwise and counter-clockwise at the same time; and many more. To get the qubits to perform operations—to compute—you can use an optical lattice or atoms in whole molecules or integrated circuits, and more to come.

The more qubits, the more interesting the computation. Starting with 2 qubits back in 1996, some systems are now up to several dozen qubits. Over the next 5-10 years we should go from 50 qubits to 5,000 qubits, first in special-purpose systems but eventually in general-purpose computers…. And there’s also the fascinating field of using funky quantum effects such as coherence and entanglement to make much more accurate sensors, imagers, and detectors. Like, a hundred thousand to a million times more accurate. GPS could locate things to the nearest micron instead of the nearest meter.

Even with small quantum computers we will be able to expand the capability of machine learning by sifting vast collections of data to detect patterns and move on from supervised-learning (“That squiggle is a 7”) toward unsupervised-learning—systems that learn to learn.

The universe is a quantum computer…. Biological life is all about extracting meaningful information from a sea of bits. For instance, photosynthesis uses quantum mechanics in a very sophisticated way to increase its efficiency. Human life is expanding on what life has always been—an exercise in machine learning.

Posted in Uncategorized

Must-Read: Henry Aaron: How to Rescue Obamacare as Insurers Drop Out

Must-Read: Henry Aaron: How to Rescue Obamacare as Insurers Drop Out:

There is a good fix for much of this problem…

From the day it opened its doors, the D.C. Health Exchange has required that all individual insurance policies be purchased through the D.C. exchange…. Once enrolled, customers’ applications go directly to the private company of their choice, where service is the same as it would have been had they applied directly to the insurer. Because the D.C. individual market is one big marketplace, there is no “inside” and “outside” the exchanges, with profit in one area and loss in the other…. If the federal exchange and all of the other state exchanges were to adopt the “one big marketplace” rule, the risk that insurers such as Aetna and UnitedHealth would selectively abandon customers in Obamacare exchanges would evaporate. Merging the relatively healthy individuals who now buy coverage outside the exchanges with those using Obamacare would help stabilize insurance for the whole group.

Predictably, insurers might balk at facing intensified competition they’re unaccustomed to. Some would incorrectly allege that customer choice had been limited. But in truth, customers would have expanded choice and improved service, because the exchanges can provide them unbiased information about coverage, costs and networks under all insurance plans. Creating one unified market would not solve every problem that insurers now confront. They would still have to learn how to manage risk in a world where they cannot charge absurdly high premiums or deny insurance to anyone. But establishing one big marketplace in each and every Obamacare exchange is low-hanging fruit, waiting to be plucked.

Macroeconomic Policy Reform: A Tentative Agenda

It was 24 years ago this week that Larry Summers and I warned that if we were to push the target inflation rate much below roughly 5%/year, then, in the immortal words of Dr Suess’s the Fish in the Pot:

“Do I like this? Oh, no, I do not. This is not a good game”, said our fish as he lit. “No, I do not like it, not one little bit!”

As I see it, if we want good macroeconomic business-cycle stabilization policy over the next generation, we need to do one or more of four things. I think the more of them we do, the better. And I want Summers and Bernanke to chair a commission this fall and winter to establish the order in which we should attempt to do these four things, and to start building the political and technocratic coalition to get them accomplished:

  1. Raise the inflation target when the economy has any chance of hitting the zero lower bound on short-term safe nominal interest rates–either by nominal GDP or price-level catchup targeting, or by raising the inflation target to 4%/year or so. The way to sell this is to say that the Fed has a dual mandate, that dual mandate requires tradeoffs, and that those tradeoffs are best accomplished via targeting recovery too and growth along a 6%/year nominal GDP growth path.

  2. Give the Federal Reserve the tools that it needs in order to properly manage aggregate demand. That means such things as:

    • Deciding by itself how it is going to use its seigniorage revenue, rather than returning its profits to the Treasury as a matter of course. (Yes, this is helicopter money.)
    • Funding mechanisms to support what ought to be state-level automatic stabilizers in a downturn–states should not be cutting construction and education and public safety spending when the economy as a whole is in recession, and thus when there is plenty of slack in the labor market.
    • More aggressive use of regulatory asset-quality and reserve-requirement tools as countercyclical policy instruments.
  3. Act to substantially reduce the risk premium on safe highly-collateralizable assets, both to repair a significant microeconomic financial market failure and to raise the medium-run equilibrium short-term safe real interest rate–the r*–in order to provide the central bank with more sea room on the lee shore it finds itself on. This requires operating both on the side of boosting market risk tolerance and expanding the supply of safe assets. This means moving beyond “government debt and deficits are always bad!” to “under certain conditions, the national debt of those sovereigns with exorbitant privilege that create safe assets when they issue debt can be a global blessing.”

  4. Reintegrate macroeconomic policy. Return forecasting from three separate exercises–the White House’s Troika (CEA-Treasury-OMB), Congress’s OMB, and the Federal Reserve–back to the Quadriad (Federal Reserve-CEA-Treasury-OMB) or on to a Pentiad (Federal Reserve-CEA-Treasury-OMB-CBO), with the principals to whom it reports being not just the President and the FOMC, but also the Majority and Minority Leaders of the Senate and the Speaker and Minority Leader of the House.

The argument against (4) is, of course, that the Fed needs to be insulated from the broader policy-political world because (a) the Fed can do the job by itself, and (b) having its elbow joggled by the policy-political world would only bolix things up. Well, the past decade has proven to us that (a) the Fed cannot do the job by itself, and (b) Fed “independence” does not keep the policy-political world from bolixing things up. The moment the Republican Party decided in January 2009 to go all-in in root-and-branch opposition to Obama, it necessarily also decided to go all-in in root-and-branch to policies pursued by Obama–which meant root-and-branch opposition to the Federal Reserve as well.

And certainly if we are not going to do (2), we definitely need to do (4).


Some very recent background reading:

Larry Summers: A Thought Provoking Essay from Fed President Williams:

John Williams has written the most thoughtful piece on monetary policy that has come out of the Fed in a long time…. He stresses the desirability of raising r* by pursuing structural policies to raise growth and affirms the importance of fiscal policy. I yield to no one in my enthusiasm for improved education and educational opportunity, but I do not think it is plausible that it will change the neutral rate appreciably in the next decade given that the vast majority of the 2030 labor force will be unaffected.

If Williams is overenthusiastic on education, he is under enthusiastic on fiscal stimulus.  He fails to emphasize the supply side benefits of infrastructure investment that likely enable debt financed infrastructure investments to pay for themselves as suggested by DeLong and Summers and the IMF.  Nor does he note at current interest rates an increase in pay as you go social security could provide households with higher safe returns than private investments…. Nor does Williams address the possibility of tax measures such as incremental investment credits or expansions in the EITC financed by tax increases on those with a high propensity to save.  The case for fiscal policy changes in the current low r* environment seems to me overwhelming….

Williams’s comments on monetary policy have generated more interest…. If the Fed believed that a 2 percent inflation target was appropriate at the beginning of 2012 when it believed the neutral real rate was above 2 percent, I cannot see any argument for not adjusting the target or altering the framework when the neutral real rate is very plausibly close to zero.  The benefits of a higher target have increased and so far as I can see nothing has happened to change the cost of a higher target. I am disappointed therefore that Williams is so tentative in his recommendations on monetary policy…. Moreover even accepting the current framework, I find the current policy framework hard to comprehend.  If as it asserts, the Fed is serious about the 2 percent inflation target being symmetric there is an anomaly in its forecasts….

Finally there is this:  Everything we know about business cycle history suggests an overwhelming likelihood that there will be downturns in the industrial world sometime in the next several years. Nowhere is there room to cut rates by anything like the normal 400 basis points in response to potential recession.  This is the primary monetary and indeed macroeconomic policy challenge of our generation. I hope it will be very much in focus at Jackson Hole.


Greg Ip: The Case for Raising the Fed’s Inflation Target:

Six years ago, Olivier Blanchard, then chief economist at theInternational Monetary Fund, floated the idea that central banks should target 4% inflation instead of 2%. I remember giving a colleague countless reasons why he was wrong. It was I who was wrong….

Last week John Williams, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, made the case for a higher inflation target in a bank newsletter. The subject will almost certainly be in the air when Fed officials and their foreign counterparts meet next week at the annual Jackson Hole symposium…. The historical case for low inflation rested on the assumption that high inflation created damaging distortions and more frequent recessions. Low inflation or deflation was a trivial risk because central banks could easily drive inflation higher by promising to print more money. But in 2008, central banks around the world cut interest rates to nearly zero and printed copious amounts of money, and only lackluster growth followed….

Here are my original objections and how they have changed.

  1. Central banks have invested their credibility in a 2% target. If they raise it, the public will assume they’ll raise it again, and expectations will rapidly become unanchored…. If anything, central banks are too credible: Investors seem to believe 2% is a ceiling, not a midpoint.

  2. As inflation rises, individual prices become more volatile, which makes the economy less efficient and more prone to booms and busts. This is still true, but against that we can see the harm from not being able to lower real (inflation-adjusted) rates further is much larger than anticipated. Meanwhile, the microeconomic harm of higher inflation is elusive….

  3. Since inflation is below 2% now and there are no new tools to get it higher, it will undermine central banks’ credibility to raise the target. Japan’s success in getting inflation back above zero, albeit not to 2%, suggests adopting a higher inflation target can bring a shift in expectations, and actions, that help make it happen.

  4. A higher inflation target makes real interest rates more negative, which would spur reach-for-yield and other speculative excesses. This is true but the alternative may be worse….

  5. What happened in 2008 was unique. Why change the target for something that happens maybe twice per century? Interest rates have been near zero now for more than seven years, and there is every reason to think similar episodes are going to happen again…. Williams sees ample evidence that deep-seated structural forces have dragged down the real natural interest rate—which keeps the economy at full employment without stoking inflation—from around 2.5% before the recession to 1% now. It may be lower….


John Williams: Monetary Policy in a Low R-Star World:

The inflation wars of the 1970s and 1980s led to a broad consensus on two fronts among academics and policymakers….

[Larry Summers and I warned]:

First, central banks are responsible and accountable for price stability… often acknowledged through… formal adoption of… inflation targeting…. Second, monetary policy should play the lead role in stabilizing inflation and employment, while fiscal policy plays a supporting role through… automatic stabilizers…. Fiscal policy should focus primarily on longer-run goals such as economic efficiency and equity….

In the post-financial crisis world, however, new realities pose significant challenges…. A variety of economic factors have pushed natural interest rates very low and they appear poised to stay that way…. Interest rates are going to stay lower than we’ve come to expect in the past…. Juxtaposed with pre-recession normal short-term interest rates of, say, 4 to 4½%, it may be jarring to see the underlying r-star guiding us towards a new normal of 3 to 3½%—or even lower…. Conventional monetary policy has less room to stimulate the economy during an economic downturn, owing to a lower bound on how low interest rates can go…. In this new normal, recessions will tend to be longer and deeper, recoveries slower, and the risks of unacceptably low inflation and the ultimate loss of the nominal anchor will be higher…. If the status quo endures, the future is likely to hold more of the same—with the possibility of even more severe challenges to maintaining price and economic stability.

To avoid this fate, central banks and governments should critically reassess the efficacy of their current approaches and carefully consider redesigning economic policy strategies to better cope with a low r-star environment…. Greater long-term investments in education, public and private capital, and research and development…. Countercyclical fiscal policy should be our equivalent of a first responder to recessions, working hand-in-hand with monetary policy…. Stronger, more predictable, systematic adjustments of fiscal policy that support the economy during recessions and recoveries…. Monetary policy frameworks should be critically reevaluated to identify potential improvements in the context of a low r-star…. A low inflation rate… is not as well-suited for a low r-star era…. The most direct attack on low r-star would be for central banks to pursue a somewhat higher inflation target…. Second, inflation targeting could be replaced by a flexible price-level or nominal GDP targeting framework….

We’ve come to the point on the path where central banks must share responsibilities. There are limits to what monetary policy can and, indeed, should do. The burden must also fall on fiscal and other policies to do their part to help create conditions conducive to economic stability…


Simon Wren-Lewis: Helicopter Money: Missing the Point:

I am tired of reading discussions of helicopter money (HM) that have the following structure:

  1. HM is like a money financed fiscal stimulus
  2. HM would threaten central bank independence
  3. So HM is a bad idea….

These discussions never seem to ask… why we have independent central banks (ICB) in the first place. And what they never seem to note, even in establishing (1), is that ICBs deny the possibility of a money financed fiscal stimulus (MFFS)…. Creating an ICB means that a MFFS is no longer possible… [because] it could only happen through ICB/government cooperation, which would negate independence…. Proponents of ICBs say… macro stabilisation can be done entirely by using changes in interest rates, so a MFFS is never going to be needed. Then we hit the Zero Lower Bound….

To then say no problem, governments can do a bond financed fiscal expansion is to completely forget why ICBs were favoured in the first place. Politicians are not good at macroeconomic stabilisation…. Demonstrating (1) does not, I repeat not, imply that ICBs do not need to do HM. Implying that it does is a bit like saying governments could set interest rates, so why do we need ICBs. Most macroeconomists would never dream of doing that, so why are they happy to use this argument with HM?

Which brings us to (2)… never… examined with the same rigour as (1)… just mentioning ‘fiscal dominance’ is enough to frighten the horses…. Imagine the set of all governments that would refuse a request from an ICB for recapitalisation during a boom when inflation was rising–governments of central bank nightmares. Now imagine the set of all governments that, in a boom with inflation rising, would happily take away the independence of the central bank to prevent it raising rates. I would suggest the two sets are identical…. HM does not seem to compromise independence at all. So please, no more elaborate demonstrations that HM is equivalent to a MFFS, as if that is an argument against HM…


Paul Krugman: Slow Learners:

Larry Summers has a very nice essay that takes off from a new paper by John Williams at the San Francisco Fed…. Williams is the highest-placed Fed official yet to suggest that maybe the inflation target should be higher. It’s not a new argument… but seeing it come from a senior official is news. Yet as Larry says, the paper is still weak and tentative even on monetary policy, to an extent that’s hard to understand…. Furthermore, there’s basically no break with orthodoxy on fiscal policy, despite the evident importance of the liquidity trap, evidence that multipliers are fairly large, and basically zero real borrowing costs. Yet Williams is at the cutting edge of policy rethinking at the Fed…. Mainstream thinking about macroeconomic policy has changed remarkably little, remarkably slowly.

You might say that it is always thus. But, you know, it isn’t…. Stagflation emerged as an issue in 1974, after the first oil shock, and pretty much ended with the Volcker double-dip recession of 1979-82–a recession whose end implication was that monetary policy continued to work in a fairly Keynesian way. So it was well under a decade of experience; yet it utterly transformed how everyone talked about macroeconomics.

Then came the 2008 crisis…. The sheer persistence both of depressed economies and of low inflation/interest rates should by now have led to a big rethinking. Depression economics redux has now gone on as long as stagflation did. Yet rethinking has been glacial at best. People who warned about the coming inflation in 2009 are warning about the coming inflation in 2016. Orthodox fears of budget deficits still dominate a lot of discourse. And the Fed still clings to an inflation target originally devised in the belief that the kind of thing that has happened to our economy would never happen.

I’m not entirely sure why learning has been so slow this time. Part of it, I suspect, is that the anti-Keynesian backlash of the 1970s had a lot of political power, and behind the scenes a lot of money, behind it–which influenced even academics, whether they realized it or not. And these days that same power and money is deployed against any rethinking. Whatever the explanation, however, it’s taking a painfully long time for serious policy discussion to arrive at a point that should have been obvious years ago.

Must-Read: Richard Mayhew: ObamaCare APTC Hacks

Must-Read: For a single carrier in a market, the obvious strategy to offer is the “narrow network, low price Silver as the #1 and a broad network Silver at a significantly higher premium as the #2 benchmark Silver” in order to pump Exchange subsidy money out of CMS, and then spend that pumped money to make everybody happy, no? There are ways to do that, no? The single carrier markets will see a lot of market power exercised, but won’t the main impact of it be to raise costs to CMS rather than to diminish the well-being of Exchange purchasers?

Just thinking aloud here…

Richard Mayhew: ObamaCare APTC Hacks:

There are other exchange strategies that don’t rely as much on manipulating… [Silver Plan price] structures…

Some carriers are not as price conscious.  Instead they are targeting risk-adjustment plays by offering people with high risk adjustment scoring conditions insurance where the gamble is the insurer can manage their care and outcomes to be better and cheaper than the combined sum of premiums and risk adjustment inflows. Others are still throwing mud against the wall.

I’m fascinated by the APTC hacking strategies because as major players pull out of the markets, more regions are seeing either only a single carrier offer plans or two carriers offer plans. Depending on how the plans are offered we could see consumers be either very happy or extremely pissed off. If carriers are offering a narrow network, low price Silver as the #1 and a broad network Silver at a significantly higher premium as the #2 benchmark Silver, people will be, on the whole, very happy. If carriers offer a narrow network HMO with miniscule benefit configuration tweaks as Silver #1 through #8 people will be extremely pissed off. The ACA story devolves into a story about the experience of individual counties at this point.

U.S. economic growth fundamentals for the 21st Century

What’s the difference between a policy that reduces economic growth and one that enhances it? When discussing labor and employment policies, those that support the long-term growth and stability of the U.S. economy are ones that make it possible for people to find and keep good jobs and then show up ready and able to put in their best work.

Alas, the workplace rules in place today that dictate workers’ time on the job largely assume incorrectly that a family includes a single breadwinner who works and a stay-at-home caregiver who does not. This outdated assumption about families with single breadwinners dates back to the prevailing views during the Depression, when the Fair Labor Standards Act set out a minimum wage, a standard workweek at 40 hours, and required employers to pay overtime to many of those who put in more hours per week.

These same assumptions also are embedded in the Social Security Act. Since its enactment in 1935, policymakers have put in place programs that support families when a breadwinner cannot work or is not expected to work due to old age, disability, or being involuntarily unemployed. But the law does not include the need for paid time off to care for children or the elderly.

This is not the world we live in today. Women now make up nearly half of all workers. Mothers are breadwinners, too, in both single-parent and dual-earner families. As late as 1960, most families up and down the income ladder had a full-time stay-at-home-caregiver. Today most do not. Now, in two-thirds of U.S. families, a mother is a breadwinner either on her own or in tandem with a spouse or partner. This is a remarkable change over the second half of the 20th century. In 1960, the share of families with a full-time, stay-at-home-caregiver was 57 percent in low-income families, 71 percent in middle-class families, and 79 percent in professional families. Today, those numbers are 22 percent, 28 percent, and 28 percent, respectively.

Women’s higher employment rates have been good—very good—for economic growth. According to estimates by myself with economists Eileen Applebaum and John Schmitt, between 1979 and 2013, the added hours of women meant that U.S. gross domestic product 11 percent higher than it would have been. This is roughly equivalent to what our nation spends on Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid, combined, in a single year. To encourage long-term growth, it is important to ensure that workplace policies reflect the needs of today’s working families.

Despite this economic boost provided by women in the workforce, as I describe in my book, “Finding Time: The Economics of Work-Life Conflict,” families up and down the income ladder are putting in these added hours without the support they need to make daily life manageable. All the “stress” that we hear about is in no small part due a U.S. labor market that doesn’t match the way families live and work today.

When working people have to constantly juggle work with childcare—and increasingly eldercare—and day-to-day activities such as grocery trips and doctor visits, it means a they’re stretched thin on each aspect, especially without the ability to rely on a stay-at-home caregiver. The result is less productivity on the job or lower labor force participation.

There are policies that can ease this day-to-day stress on employees, and boost productivity and family incomes—and the economy—in turn. These include policies for when a worker temporarily needs to be at home, instead of at work, to care for a family member. Policies such as paid sick days and paid medical and family leave have been proven to support employment through making it easier—and sometimes simply possible—for workers with care responsibilities to keep their jobs.

It also is important to recognize that having some control over one’s time can make all the difference as to whether a worker can navigate around work-life conflicts. Today, many workers have unpredictable schedules or put in long hours—while some continue to struggle with too few hours—either three of which can make paying for and scheduling childcare or eldercare virtually impossible. A cared-for workforce means a more productive workforce.

Similarly, because the cost of care is borne mostly by families, creating good jobs for the care workforce has been difficult to achieve. This directly affects the quality of care. Research shows that the quality of childcare—and eldercare—is directly related to the quality of the jobs in the care workforce. Yet, families cannot afford to pay for this all on their own, especially those with young kids who need to access care but may not be at the peak of their earnings potential.

All of these mismatches between today’s outdated labor market practices and effective policies that could make our labor force more efficient points to the conclusion that maintaining U.S. economic competitiveness into the 21st century requires policymakers to acknowledge these work-life conflicts and work to remedy them. Getting talented workers into good jobs and laboring at their highest productivity requires resolving work-life conflicts that constrain today’s labor supply, which in turn keeps down family incomes and slows growth in aggregate demand in the economy. A work-life agenda that matches the needs of family breadwinners today would go a long way toward supporting strong and stable economic growth.

Must-Reads: August 21, 2016


Should Reads: