Must-Read: Gene D’Avolio, Efi Gildor, and Andrei Shleifer (2001): Technology, Information Production, and Market Efficiency

Must-Read: Gene D’Avolio, Efi Gildor, and Andrei Shleifer (2001): Technology, Information Production, and Market Efficiency:

A recent study by Financial Executives International (FEI) and NYU graduate student Min Wu… associate[s] these [earnings] restatements with losses of market value of $31.2 billion in 2000, $24.2 billion in 1999, and $17.7 billion in 1998…

…The largest event involved Microstrategy (MSTR), whose stock fell by $11.9 billion over three days surrounding a revenue recognition based restatement of earnings. Two-thirds of all restatements are by Nasdaq firms. This is partly driven by the disproportionate number of restatements in the computer manufacturing and software industries. Arthur Andersen finds that these two segments accounted for 27 per- cent of all restatements from 1997 to 2000…

No, State Governments Have Not Been the Sacred Hearths of Human Liberty in America. Why Do You Ask?

Mcculloch vs maryland Google Search

The extremely-sharp Miles Kimball quotes Randy Barnett, who is… not so:

Randy Barnett: Growing up, I was like most Americans in my reverence for the Constitution… Until I took Constitutional Law at Harvard Law School.

The experience was completely disillusioning, but not because of the professor, Laurence Tribe, who was an engaging and open-minded teacher. No, what disillusioned me was reading the opinions of the U.S. Supreme Court. Throughout the semester, as we covered one constitutional clause after another, passages that sounded great to me were drained by the Court of their obviously power-constraining meanings. First was the Necessary and Proper Clause in McCulloch v. Maryland (1819)..

WTF!? To declare, given the ends that an authority shall aim at, that it has the powers “necessary and proper” to attain them is not “obviously power-constraining”. It turns the ends from being a pious hope to something capable of accomplishment.

Moreover, McCulloch vs. Maryland is in no sense an unleashing of the powers of the government. The decision, in fact, constrains government: it shrinks the powers that the government of the state of Maryland has. At most, it’s zero-sum. It sets the powers of the federal government high: the Second Bank of the United States can operate in Maryland. It sets the powers of the state government high: the state is prohibited from using its taxing power to make operation of the Second Bank of the United States impossible.

Sometimes government power should be at the local level; sometimes the state level; sometimes the national level; sometimes the global level. Circumstances alter cases. But to say that it is a rule or that there should be a strong presumption that governmental powers exercised at the state level create more freedom than powers exercised at the federal level is just weird.

Or, rather, it is just weird unless we look at the historical context. Then we see where Randy Barnett is coming from:

Historically, in America, to expand the powers of state governments relative to those of the federal government has not been the road to victory for human liberty. Rather, it has been the reverse. It has been the road to expanded slavery, to Jim Crow, and to regressive rent-extraction to local elites via the county courthouse and that statehouse.

A strong predisposition that states rather than feds should wield power has no proper place in libertarian thought. But it has a very strong place in American libertarian thought. Why? Because it is the keystone of the arch that has been the libertarian-racist alliance here in America since the 1950s. That alliance has done so much to bring shame to libertarian political philosophy and political philosophers. And it continues to wreak its damage today.

Posted in Uncategorized

Must-Read: Brad Setser: The ECB on the Slowdown in Global Trade

Must-Read: Brad Setser: The ECB on the Slowdown in Global Trade:

I have long thought that China was too big an economy for manufacturing exports to account for 35 percent of its GDP…

…especially when that high level of exports relative to GDP corresponded with a large overall surplus. An adjustment that returned China to “normal” thus almost certainly would be accompanied by some form of a slowdown in global trade…. And… China’s post-crisis growth has coincided with fairly steady falls in its imports of manufactures relative to its GDP…. There is plenty of evidence that components once imported are now increasingly made in China (see for example Chapter 1 of this IMF report). Global value chains got compressed…. And imports of manufactured goods for domestic use (measured as the difference between processing imports and all manufactured imports) also seem to be sliding….

The IMF’s analysis in the new WEO chapter on trade points in a similar direction. The Fund argues that the slowdown in global trade stems mostly from a slowdown in investment… [and] China’s imports recently have fallen by a bit faster than can be explained by its model…. A lot of the story on global trade reduces to a China story, both directly, and indirectly though China’s impact on commodities. The ECB’s statistical work maps well to a set of stylized facts about the evolution of China’s trade.

Must-Read: Larry Summers: Four Things the Fed Should Do Now

Must-Read: Larry Summers: Four Things the Fed Should Do Now:

The neutral rate is now close to zero and it may well remain under 2 percent for the foreseeable future…

With the economy growing at below 2 percent over the last year, total hours of work essentially flat for the last 6 months, and with long term inflation expectations declining there is no reason to think we are currently much below the neutral rate…. [The Fed] should acknowledge at least to itself that it has damaged its credibility by repeatedly  holding out the prospects of much more tightening than the market anticipated, being ignored by the market, and then having the market turn out to be right. It should recognize output and inflation and unemployment would all be closer to their target levels today and in their forecasts if rates had not been increased last December. It should move to bring its stated plans more in line with external expectations regarding how much tightening the economy can tolerate….

The Fed should make real the idea that its inflation target is symmetric…. It should be clear that until inflation expectations look to be rising above 2 percent there is no need to restrain the economy…. The Fed should make clear that it sees risk as asymmetric right now.  If the economy falls into recession there is a real risk of a Japan scenario…. There is no great risk if inflation drifts above two percent. It might, as I have noted, actually be desirable. And if not, policy can be tightened to prevent the economy from overheating as has occurred many times in the past.

Eric Rosengren, in explaining his dissent on the decision not to raise rates in September, argues that the Fed has historically had a hard time tapping the brakes and that if the Fed has to cool off an overheated economy a recession is likely to result. I am not sure what aspect of history he has in mind here…. On occasion… recession was the price of bringing it back to desired levels.  Rosengren’s case would be made by examples where so much extra slack was induced that the economy undershot on inflation. I am not aware of such instances…. It takes a tortured argument to believe that you can prevent a car from stopping by hitting the brakes…

Must-Reads: September 30, 2016


Should Reads:

[14,000-year-old campsite in Argentina adds to an archaeological mystery: http://arstechnica.com/science/2016/09/14000-year-old-campsite-in-argentina-adds-to-an-archaeological-mystery/

Weekend reading: “Working on the supply chain” edition

This is a weekly post we publish on Fridays with links to articles that touch on economic inequality and growth. The first section is a round-up of what Equitable Growth published this week and the second is the work we’re highlighting from elsewhere. We won’t be the first to share these articles, but we hope by taking a look back at the whole week, we can put them in context.

Equitable Growth round-up

Underemployment for recent U.S. college graduates was a very prevalent phenomenon in the wake of the Great Recession. But while it was a temporary for most grads, the trend raises some concerns about long-term trends in the U.S. labor market.

The issue of time spent outside of the (paid) workplace tends to be overlooked in debates around gender equality, but what happens at home has ripple effects throughout society, writes Bridget Ansel.

How much should policymakers tax capital? It’s a difficult question with lots of considerations we have to take into account before answering. A new paper provides a new framework for thinking about the optimal rate for U.S. capital taxation.

U.S. firms are increasingly outsourcing parts of their work to other firms. The growth of these supply chains is an underappreciated change in the U.S. economy and could have important implications for U.S. competitiveness and standards of living, according to a new report from Susan Helper and Timothy Krueger.

Would moving workers around the United States to maximize their chance of hiring significantly reduce unemployment? A new paper argues that, while it would have an impact, eliminating geographic mismatch in the U.S. labor market wouldn’t have a major impact on unemployment.

Links from around the web

One potential channel through which high levels inequality might affect economic growth is through reducing consumption. Larry Summers writes up a new International Monetary Fund working paper that shows a significant decline in consumption caused by higher inequality. [wonkblog]

A popular hypothesis for why productivity is on the decline is the shift away from manufacturing to the service sector in the United States? But maybe the service sector isn’t so much less productive than the manufacturing sector. Dietz Vollrath explains. [growth economics]

The U.S. population is aging and many workers are now entering the period of their working career when they won’t see much wage or earnings growth. This demographic shift can help explain the decline in overall U.S. wage growth, according to Robert Rich, Joseph Tracy, and Ellen Fu. [liberty street economics]

“To burst the illusion of safety in a particular financial asset is akin to shrinking the institutional money supply. But that is a tradeoff now considered worthwhile by regulators, a necessary price to pay for a stabler financial sector.” Cardiff Garcia writes on money market funds and financial regulation. [ft alphaville]

Long-run inflation expectations have been on the decline since 2014, around the time oil prices started to drop. Does this oil price trend explain all of the lower inflation expectations? Carola Binder describes her research pointing to additional reasons. [quantitative ease]

Friday figure

Figure from “Supply chains and equitable growth” by Susan Helper and Timothy Krueger

Must-Read: Simon Wren-Lewis: A General Theory of Austerity, Cynicism and Opportunism

Must-Read: Simon Wren-Lewis: A General Theory of Austerity, Cynicism and Opportunism:

Was austerity an unfortunate accident?

…For the major economies including the Eurozone as a whole, austerity could have been avoided completely by delaying fiscal consolidation by a few years…. There was no evidence that the financial markets had demanded the switch to austerity in 2010. Instead, the Eurozone crisis went beyond a crisis for the Greek government because of the ECB’s unwillingness (until 2012) to act as a sovereign lender of last resort. In other words, austerity at the global level was a huge and avoidable mistake. This naturally leads to the question of why that mistake was made…. The accident story might run as follows. The first unfortunate accident was Greece…. The second accident was that Greece’s situation occurred inside a Eurozone that was dominated by Germany…. While there is undoubtedly an important element of truth in both the unfortunate timing of the Greek debt crisis and the role of Germany in interpreting and reacting to it, there are three reasons why it cannot explain the dominance of austerity since 2010…. Within the Eurozone… there has been… little resistance to German views…. In the US and UK… the turn to austerity [as well]…. The damage done by austerity, and the special nature of the debt funding crisis in the Eurozone, were quite clear to most economists by 2014 at the latest…. Yet while the IMF’s own economists were prepared to make this admission, politicians (including those running the IMF) were not….

The idea that deficit concern was being used as a pretext to reduce the size of the state, which I will call the deficit deceit hypothesis, is based on two propositions:
1) Political parties on the right want a smaller state, but popular support for such a programme is, at best, mixed. 2) From 2010 there was strong popular support for reducing government deficits…. One strong piece of evidence in favour of deficit deceit is the form of austerity imposed. Republicans in the US called for spending cuts to reduce the deficit, while at the same time arguing elsewhere that taxes should be cut…. At first France appeared to be an exception, proposing to focus on tax increases to reduce deficits. European Commissioner Olli Rehn was not pleased…. An indication of the strength of popular support for cutting budget deficits came from the lack of opposition to these policies from the centre left….

Perhaps the most interesting argument in Wren-Lewis (2015b) is that the creation of independent central banks, coupled with a growing consensus that monetary policy and not fiscal policy should deal with macroeconomic stabilisation (Kirsanova et al, 2009), has helped reduce the extent to which policy makers and the media hear about the costs of fiscal consolidation in a liquidity trap…. The expertise in finance ministries. If governments have in effect contracted out the business of macroeconomic stabilisation to central banks, there is less need to retain macroeconomic expertise in these ministries. The second concerns the attitudes of senior figures in central banks to budget deficits. Mervyn King once remarked (King, 1995): “Central banks are often accused of being obsessed with inflation. This is untrue. If they are obsessed with anything, it is with fiscal policy.” This follows from a historic concern that governments will force central banks to monetise debt, which outside of a recession could lead to large increases in inflation….

The deficit deceit hypothesis is therefore a general theory of why austerity happens when we are at the ZLB. It reflects opportunism on the political right… [that] will only work… [if] popular concern about government deficits must be strong… a generalised fear about the behaviour of financial markets… knowledge about the harmful effects of fiscal consolidation at the ZLB… weak within political parties, the apparatus of government and the public at large…. Popular concern about government deficits will be much greater if these deficits are at ‘record levels’, which they inevitably were following the deepest global recession since WWII….

There are also some trends that have helped create the conditions for deficit deceit to work. The most obvious is the growing power of a neoliberal ideology that puts such stress on the desirability of a small state…. The importance of deficit deceit in explaining recent (and in some countries, continuing) austerity means that it could easily happen again following another major recession….

There was no good macroeconomic reason for austerity at the global level over the last five years, and austerity seen in periphery Eurozone countries could most probably have been significantly milder. As austerity could have been so easily avoided by delaying global fiscal consolidation by only a few years, a critical question becomes why this knowledge was not applied. While the unfortunate timing of the Greek debt crisis undoubtedly played a small part, it alone cannot explain austerity in the US and UK, and the weakness of the European left in failing to oppose austerity…. Austerity was the result of right-wing opportunism, exploiting instinctive popular concern about rising government debt in order to reduce the size of the state. This opportunism, and the fact that it was successful (in its own terms), reflects a failure to follow both economic theory and evidence. This failure was made possible in part because the task of macroeconomic stabilisation has increasingly been delegated to independent central banks, but these institutions did not actively warn of the costs of premature fiscal consolidation, and in some cases encouraged it.

Must-Read: John Maynard Keynes (1936): The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, Chapter 12

Must-Read: Is there anybody who can teach all of Hyman Minsky while standing on one foot? Yes: one person can:

John Maynard Keynes (1936): The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, Chapter 12:

So far we have had chiefly in mind the state of confidence of the speculator or speculative investor himself…

…and may have seemed to be tacitly assuming that, if he himself is satisfied with the prospects, he has unlimited command over money at the market rate of interest.

This is, of course, not the case. Thus we must also take account of the other facet of the state of confidence, namely, the confidence of the lending institutions towards those who seek to borrow from them, sometimes described as the state of credit.

A collapse in the price of equities, which has had disastrous reactions on the marginal efficiency of capital, may have been due to the weakening either of speculative confidence or of the state of credit. But whereas the weakening of either is enough to cause a collapse, recovery requires the revival of both. For whilst the weakening of credit is sufficient to bring about a collapse, its strengthening, though a necessary condition of recovery, is not a sufficient condition…

Must-Read: John Maynard Keynes (1937): The General Theory of Employment

Must-Read: John Maynard Keynes (1937): The General Theory of Employment:

Now a practical theory of the future based on these three principles has certain marked characteristics…

…In particular, being based on so flimsy a foundation, It is subject to sudden and violent changes. The practice of calmness and immobility, of certainty and security, suddenly breaks down. New fears and hopes will, without warning, take charge of human conduct. The forces of disillusion may suddenly impose a new conventional basis of valuation. All these pretty, polite techniques, made for a well-panelled Board Room and a nicely regulated market, are liable to collapse. At all times the vague panic fears and equally vague and unreasoned hopes are not really lulled, and lie but a little way below the surface.

Perhaps the reader feels that this general, philosophical disquisition on the behavior of mankind is somewhatremote from the economic theory under discussion.

But I think not.

Tho this is how we behave in the marketplace, the theory we devise in the study of how we behave in the market place should not itself submit to market-place idols. I accuse the classical economic theory of being itself one of these pretty, polite techniques which tries to deal with the present by abstracting from the fact that we know very little about the future.

I dare say that a classical economist would readily admit this. But, even so, I think he has overlooked the precise nature of the difference which his abstraction makes between theory and practice, and the character of the fallacies into which he is likely to be led.

This is particularly the case in his treatment of Money and Interest. And our first step must be to elucidate more clearly the functions of Money.

Money, it is well known, serves two principal purposes. By acting as a money of account it facilitates exchanges with-out its being necessary that it should ever itself come into the picture as a substantive object. In this respect it is a convenience which is devoid of significance or real influence. In the second place, It is a store of wealth. So we are told, with-out a smile on the face.

But in the world of the classical economy, what an insane use to which to put it! For it is a recognized characteristic of money as a store of wealth that it is barren; whereas practically every other form of storing wealth yields some interest or profit. Why should anyone outside a lunatic asylum wish to use money as a store of wealth?

Because, partly on reasonable and partly on instinctive grounds, our desire to hold Money as a store of wealth is a barometer of the degree of our distrust of our own calculations and conventions concerning the future. Even tho this feeling about Money is itself conventional or instinctive, it operates, so to speak, at a deeper level of our motivation. It takes charge at the moments when the higher, more precarious conventions have weakened. The possession of actual money lulls our disquietude; and the premium which we require to make us part with money is the measure of the degree of our disquietude.