Should-Read: Equitable Growth: Third Annual Class of Grantees

Should-Read: Equitable Growth: Third Annual Class of Grantees: “Research on how economic inequality affects macroeconomic growth and stability…

…Jess Benhabib, Alberto Bisin, and Mi Luo…. Gauti Eggertsson and Neil Mehrotra…. Adriana Kugler and Ammar Farooq…. Further research on the macroeconomy: Alexander Bartik… John Coglianese… Andrew Elrod…. How economic inequality affects the development of human capital…. Christopher Jencks and Beth Truesdale…. Marta Murray-Close and Joya Misra…. Sydnee Caldwell… Mariana Zerpa…. Research on how economic inequality affects the quantity and quality of innovation…. Kyle Herkenhoff… Heidi Williams… Patrick Kline… Neviana Petkova… and Owen Zidar…. Two doctoral grants will support further research on innovation: Xavier Jaravel… Hannah Rubinton…. Research on how levels and trends in economic inequality affect the quality of social and political institutions…. Manasi Deshpande… Tal Gross… and Jialan Wang… Jane Waldfogel and Ann Bartel… Maya Rossin-Slater… and Christopher Ruhm…. Joan Williams… Susan Lambert… and Saravanan Kesavan…. One doctoral grant will support further research on governance and institutions: Ellora Derenoncourt…

Should-Read: João Amador and Sónia Cabral: Networks of Value-Added Trade

Should-Read: João Amador and Sónia Cabral: Networks of Value-Added Trade: “Global Value Chains have become the paradigm…

…Bilateral gross trade flows no longer accurately represent interconnections among countries…. Examine… the profile of Germany, the US, China and Russia as suppliers of value added…. We took the World Input-Output Database (Timmer et al. 2015) and used network analysis…. Domestic and foreign value added are combined to produce exports…. In each year, the GVC is represented as a directed network of nodes (40 countries) and edges (value-added flows between them)…

Posted in Uncategorized

Should-Read: JEC: The Next New Macro

Should-Read: JEC: The Next New Macro: “The seeds of disaster… lay…

…in how easily New Classical-style models could be tweaked to get Keynesian behavior…. The mess in macro did not come about because some economists committed to a modelling style which turns out to yield little insight. The mess is a consequence of the… macro-mono-culture…. The fact is that, right now, we do not know the way forward, and no approach, no matter how promising (or how congenial to our pre-conceptions and policy preferences) should be allowed to dominate the field until it has proven itself empirically successful…. Why, then, did the entire discipline latch on to the New Classical approach? In a word: panic. Whatever the flaws in the New Classicals’ positive program, their negative critique of existing econometric practice was both true and devastating…

Must- and Should-Reads: January 17, 2017


Interesting Reads:

Must-Read: Guido Alfani: Europe’s Rich since 1300

Must-Read: Guido Alfani: Europe’s Rich since 1300: “Throughout this time, the only significant declines in inequality were the result of the Black Death and the World Wars…

…EINITE http://www.dondena.unibocconi.it/EINITE… has collected, systematically and with a uniform methodology, information about long-term trends in wealth inequality, and in the share of the richest, for many ancient Italian states as well as for a few other areas of Europe… from around 1300 to 1800…. Figure 1 shows the share of wealth of the top 10% between 1300 and 2010, using Piketty (2014) for the post-1800 period…. Remarkably, Piketty’s series for 1810-1910 shows the share of the richest growing at almost exactly the same pace as the I calculated for the series between 1550 and 1800….

Europe s rich since 1300 VOX CEPR s Policy Portal

In the seven centuries… we find only two phases of significant inequality decline. Both were triggered by catastrophic events: The Black Death…. Shocks occurred between 1915 and 1945 related to the two World Wars, as argued by Piketty 2014, pp. 368-370)…. The share of the richest 10% today is about the same as that in Europe (or at least, Italy) immediately before the Black Death…. The long-term perspective of recent research requires us to move beyond the characterisation of inequality time dynamics provided by Kuznets….

During the early modern period (from around 1600) the prevalence of the rich grew almost continuously until the onset of the Industrial Revolution. The rich made up no more than 5% of the overall population during the Middle Ages and the first part of the early modern period…

Europe s rich since 1300 VOX CEPR s Policy Portal

Must-Read: Kenneth Arrow et al.: Are We Consuming Too Much?

Must-Read: Kenneth Arrow et a.: (2004): Are We Consuming Too Much?: “We consider two criteria for the possible excessiveness (or insufficiency) of current consumption…

…One is an intertemporal utility-maximization criterion: actual current consumption is deemed excessive if it is higher than the level of current consumption on the consumption path that maximizes the present discounted value of utility. The other is a sustainability criterion, which requires that current consumption be consistent with non-declining living standards over time. We extend previous theoretical approaches by offering a formula for the sustainability criterion that accounts for population growth and technological change. In applying this formula, we find that some poor regions of the world are failing to meet the sustainability criterion: in these regions, genuine wealth per capita is falling as investments in human and manufactured capital are not sufficient to offset the depletion of natural capital.

Should-Read: Christoph Lakner and Branko Milanovic: Global Income Distribution: From the Fall of the Berlin Wall to the Great Recession

Should-Read: Christoph Lakner and Branko Milanovic (2013): Global Income Distribution: From the Fall of the Berlin Wall to the Great Recession: “The paper presents a newly compiled and improved database of national household surveys between 1988 and 2008…

…In 2008, the global Gini index is around 70.5 percent having declined by approximately 2 Gini points over this twenty year period. When it is adjusted for the likely under-reporting of top incomes in surveys by using the gap between national accounts consumption and survey means in combination with a Pareto-type imputation of the upper tail, the estimate is a much higher global Gini of almost 76 percent. With such an adjustment the downward trend in the Gini almost disappears.

Tracking the evolution of individual country-deciles shows the underlying elements that drive the changes in the global distribution: China has graduated from the bottom ranks, modifying the overall shape of the global income distribution in the process and creating an important global “median” class that has transformed a twin-peaked 1988 global distribution into an almost single-peaked one now. e “winners” were country-deciles that in 1988 were around the median of the global income distribution, 90 percent of whom in terms of population are from Asia. e “losers” were the country-deciles that in 1988 were around the 85th percentile of the global income distribution, almost 90 percent of whom in terms of population are from mature economies.

Digesting Income Inequality Mind the Post

Should-Read: Ken Rogoff: Big Danger at the Lower Bound

Should-Read: This first from Ken Rogoff is very sensible. But IMHO it fits awkwardly with the “debt supercycle” view. We are now, after all, a decade into repair of the debt supercycle after the crash. Why then is this still a big problem? It seems to me an implicit admission that there is something much more going on than a standard debt supercycle:

Ken Rogoff: Big Danger at the Lower Bound: “Given that the Fed may struggle just to get its base interest rate up to 2% over the coming year, there will be very little room to cut if a recession hits…

…The two best ideas for dealing with the zero bound on interest rates seem off-limits for the moment. The optimal approach would be to implement all of the various legal, tax, and institutional changes needed to take interest rates significantly negative, thereby eliminating the zero bound. This requires preventing people from responding by hoarding paper currency…. The other approach… would be to raise the target inflation rate from 2% to 4%….

If ideas like negative interest rates and higher inflation targets sound dangerously radical, well, radical is relative. Unless central banks figure out a convincing way to address their paralysis at the zero bound, there is likely to be a continuing barrage of outside-the-box proposals that are far more radical…. Of course, there is always fiscal policy to provide economic stimulus. But it is extremely undesirable for government spending to have to be as volatile as it would be if it had to cover for the ineffectiveness of monetary policy.

There may not be enough time before the next deep recession to lay the groundwork for effective negative-interest-rate policy or to phase in a higher inflation target. But that is no excuse for not starting to look hard at these options, especially if the alternatives are likely to be far more problematic.


Much more dubious is Ken Rogoff’s belief that the U.S. government should be borrowing longer-term and thus not augmenting but using up the private sector’s (limited) risk bearing capacity:

Ken Rogoff: America’s Looming Debt Decision: “Should the US government lock in today’s ultra-low borrowing costs by issuing longer-term debt?…

…Until now, the US Treasury and the Federal Reserve Board, acting in combination, have worked to keep down long-term government debt, in order to reduce interest rates for the private sector…. At this point, the average duration of US debt… is now under three years…. The tilt toward short-term borrowing as a way to try to stimulate the economy has made sense until now…. But the government should not operate like a bank or a hedge fund, loading up on short-term debt to fund long-term projects…. The potential fiscal costs of a fast upward shift in interest rates could be massive.

No one is saying that such a shift is likely or imminent, but the odds aren’t as trivial as some might like to believe…. A rise in borrowing rates could also come from self-inflicted damage. Suppose, for example, that US voters elect as their president an unpredictable and incompetent businessman, who views bankruptcy as just business as usual…. Mind you, lengthening borrowing maturities does not have to imply borrowing less…. There is a significant backlog of worthy projects, and real (inflation-adjusted) interest rates are low (though, properly measured, real rates may be significantly higher than official measures suggest, mainly because the government’s inability to account properly for the benefits of new goods causes it to overstate inflation). One hopes that the next president will create an infrastructure task force….

With control of the global reserve currency, the US has room to borrow; nonetheless, it should structure its borrowing wisely…. That is why the time has come for the US Treasury to consider borrowing at longer horizons than it has in recent years. Today, the longest maturity debt issued by the US government is the 30-year bond. Yet Spain has successfully issued 50-year debt at a very low rate, while Ireland, Belgium, and even Mexico have issued 100-year debt…

And one piece of this second seems to me to be incoherent: “Properly measured, real rates may be significantly higher than official measures suggest, mainly because the government’s inability to account properly for the benefits of new goods causes it to overstate inflation.” The right numeraire for economists to use in their calculations is not a unit of gold or a unit of commodities but a unit of marginal utility: the true real interest rate is the rate at which society can trade off utility today for utility in the future. Something like the commodity real interest rate minus the real income growth rate is the true appropriate measure of the societal cost of borrowing.

And that appropriate measure is unaffected by the kinds of measurement errors Rogoff is discussing.

The reach for negative interest rates or higher inflation targets suggests that the unwinding of the debt supercycle will take very long indeed–in which case how is it different from secular stagnation?

Must- and Should-Reads: January 16, 2017


Interesting Reads: