Nighttime Must-Read: Megan McArdle: Yes, You’re Rich, and It’s Time You Admit It

Megan McArdle:
Yes, You’re Rich, and It’s Time You Admit It:
“Jack Lew made a lot of money working for Citibank. So why…

…did he say last week that ‘My own compensation was never in the stratosphere’? Jack Lew is not the only person who says this sort of thing. The media is routinely filled with people making six- and seven-figure incomes who modestly report that they are very middle class, struggling, really, to make it from paycheck to paycheck. And if you live in a big coastal city like New York, Washington, Boston or San Francisco, you… can go to any private-school parents night or Ivy League alumni reunion to hear a veritable chorus of people remarking that they really don’t know how they keep body and soul together on just $350,000 per annum. Be warned, however, that it is not polite to point and laugh the way that you would on Twitter…

Nighttime Must-Read: Larry Mishel: American Wages Have Stagnated

Larry Mishel:
American Wages Have Stagnated:
“If most people believe…

…as I think they do, that if they’d leave their current job, they’d get a worse job, then exit does not give you much leverage. So, the single most important policy response right now should be to get to a vigorous full employment. That makes the decisions of the Federal Reserve board over the next few years the most consequential economic policy decisions to be made on wages and income inequality.

Nighttime Must-Read: Mary C. Daly and Bart Hobijn: Why Is Wage Growth So Slow?

Mary C. Daly and Bart Hobijn:
Why Is Wage Growth So Slow?:
“Despite considerable improvement in the labor market…

…growth in wages continues to be disappointing. One reason is that many firms were unable to reduce wages during the recession, and they must now work off a stockpile of pent-up wage cuts. This pattern is evident nationwide and explains the variation in wage growth across industries. Industries that were least able to cut wages during the downturn and therefore accrued the most pent-up cuts have experienced relatively slower wage growth during the recovery…

The U.S. Economy: Overview and Prospect: Notes for Orinda, CA, Rotary Club Talk

https://www.icloud.com/keynote/AwBUCAESEF4LXeNCpXwKfLDofdWn_dsaKeHcPNB0pmbKyTMjezpOIYcmM9nUzT-5JG8ExkbS3sc2Hn82UIJwtEaJMCUCAQEEIKrGQK6hn6DxBfu8VrkXsnOt10rY7yjVI4D3OAoTRNYE#2015-01-07–The_Economy%2C_Past_10%2C_Future_2%2C_10%2C_50_Year_Perspectives.key


Part I: Thinking About the Current Business Cycle

  • The circular flow of economic activity
  • Everyone’s income becomes their spending and investing, which is then someone else’s income
  • Except: When people want to hoard (or de-hoard) their cash
  • When people want to spend down their cash, (planned) spending is greater than (expected) income
    • Unexpected inflation
    • Job of the Federal Reserve to sell bonds and soak that excess cash up to rebalance the economy
  • When people want to hoard cash, (planned) spending is less than (expected) income
    • Unemployment and depression
    • Job of the Federal Reserve to buy bonds and so give the economy the cash it needs to make people comfortable spending and investing their incomes
  • Private sector cannot do this job: in a panic nothing banks can provide counts as “cash”; in a euphoria everything counts as “cash”
    • Take away the punchbowl before the party really gets going; but be sure there is a punchbowl

The Situation as of 10 Years Ago

Interest Rates

Graph 10 Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate FRED St Louis Fed
  • The Federal Reserve back then was trying to manage the economy: full employment and rough price stability

Salient Components of Spending

Economy Review and Prospect Base File and Edit Post Washington Center for Equitable Growth WordPress
  • Deviations as shares of potential production from recent business-cycle peak values
  • As of 2005 we were pretty optimistic about the near-term and medium-term future of the American economy
  • Worries about budget deficits and trade deficits, but not a source of immediate disaster
  • U.S. economy had fallen into recession in 2001 for two reasons:
    • People who had been investing in high-tech businesses decided to hoard their cash
    • Fall-off in demand for U.S. exports as people elsewhere decided they wanted to hoard more cash inside the U.S.
  • But recovery was in train
    • A housing boom
    • An export recovery as foreigners figured they had about enough assets in the United States

Employment-to-Adult-Population Ratio

Civilian Employment Population Ratio FRED St Louis Fed
  • Only big black spot: next to no recovery in employment as a share of the adult population, but that was expected to come in time…

Managing the Correction of Imbalances

Salient Components of Spending

Economy Review and Prospect Base File
  • 2005-2008: collapse of the housing bubble
  • Became clear that a lot of the housing investment had been based on people taking on risks that they did not understand–and when they learned what the risks were, they were unhappy
  • But from 2005-2008 the economy rebalanced–people who had been investing in financing construction shifted to financing exports, business investment instead

The Collapse

Salient Components of Spending

Economy Review and Prospect Base File
  • Then the financial crisis…
  • Should not have happened…
  • Became clear that not just the “frothier” parts of housing investment were made by people taking on risks that they did not understand, but that Wall Street had no control whatsoever over what its derivative positions were…
  • A collapse of trust–and an enormous demand for cash to hoard–as (planned) spending fell way below (expected) income
  • And then actual income fell below expected incomes because spending had collapsed

Employment-to-Adult-Population Ratio

Civilian Employment Population Ratio FRED St Louis Fed
  • The worst employment decline since the Great Depression

Interest Rates

Graph 10 Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate FRED St Louis Fed
  • Federal Reserve responds by flooding the economy with cash by buying short-term Treasury bills–but it doesn’t work: people are so eager to hoard that they take the cash, sock it into their portfolios, where the Treasury bills used to be, and still demand to hoard more…

The Flatlining

Interest Rates

Graph 10 Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate FRED St Louis Fed
  • “Quantitative Easing” does not return spending to normal…

Employment-to-Adult-Population Ratio

Civilian Employment Population Ratio FRED St Louis Fed
  • And the employment-to-adult-population ratio does not recover to normal either

Salient Components of Spending

Economy Review and Prospect Base File
  • Why not?
  • Housing finance not fixed–even very low interest rates and ample cash do not induce people to de-hoard that cash and start investing in construction again (except in a few places)
  • Businesses see that they have ample capacity and are not enthusiastic about spending their cash on capacity that would then sit idle for a while
  • Exports do bounce back, but there is a depression going on in most of our export markets as well, so that is limited help
  • And we hit the economy on the head with a brick by cutting way back on what the government purchases
  • Exactly the wrong thing to do
  • Why we do it is a mystery

Part II: The Next Two Years

Labor Force Participation and Employment-to-Adult Population

FRED Graph FRED St Louis Fed
  • The Federal Reserve is about to start “normalizing” policy
  • The question of trend labor-force participation
  • Federal Reserve believes (a) demography is shrinking desired hours, and (b) many of those who lost their jobs in 2008-9 and haven’t gotten good ones since are never going to come back
  • Hence the economy has nearly “recovered to normal”
    • But not because production and employment have risen from their depressed levels back to normal
    • Because the financial crisis, the collapse, and the flatlining have done permanent damage that has pushed “normal” down to nearly where we are today…

Inflation-Adjusted Price of Oil

Graph Crude Oil Prices West Texas Intermediate WTI Cushing Oklahoma FRED St Louis Fed
  • Only bright spot: Saudi Arabia’s loss of pricing power in the oil market–that will give a big boost to Americans’ incomes and spending
  • And it will entail a substantial regional shift within America of wealth from Texas-Oklahoma-North Dakota to California-New York-Florida-Illinois
  • Also: ObamaCare implementation

Part III: The Next Ten Years

Real GDP

Graph Real Gross Domestic Product 3 Decimal FRED St Louis Fed
  • We used to bounce-back from business-cycle downturns and return to normalcy

Real GDP

Graph Real Gross Domestic Product 3 Decimal FRED St Louis Fed
  • We are showing no signs of bouncing-back from this one
  • $6,000 per adult in potential production lost–that’s $1.2 trillion/year of real wealth that we could be making that we are not, and that it looks like we are never going to recoup.
  • But we are producing $80,000 per adult a year these days–twice what we were producing in the 1970s. $6,000 a year is very painful–7.5%. But that is only an eight-year delay in the course of economic growth, a “lost growth decade” only.
    • Data caveats: $80,000/year includes depreciation, benefits, imputed rent on your house, taxes taken out before the money hits your paycheck, and so forth–figure $50,000/year per working age adult of something that looks like “income”

Inequality: The Rise of the 1%

Screenshot 1 7 15 7 57 AM
  • Back in the 1970s–when we had $40,000/year productivity for your average working-age adult–the top 1% took 8%, the rest of the top 5% took 13%, the rest of the top 10% took 12%.
    • Top 1%: $320,000/year
    • 96-99%: $130,000/year
    • 91-95%: $96,000/year
    • Bottom 90%: $30,000/year
  • Today: $80000/year productivity
    • Top 1%: 24%: $1,920,000/year
    • 96-99%: 16%: $320,000/year
    • 91-95%: 12%: $192,000/year
    • Bottom 90%: $42,700/year

Inequality: The Rise of the 0.01%

Screenshot 1 7 15 8 08 AM
  • 1970s:
    • Top 0.01%: 1%: $4,000,000/year (12000 people)
    • Rest of top 1%: 7%: $280,000
  • Today:
    • Top 0.01%: 6%: $48,000,000/year (20000 people)
    • Rest of top 1%: 16%: $1,280,000/year
  • What are we getting for this rise in inequality? We are paying our top 1% and our top 0.01% very handsomely, yet…
  • Finance and health-care administration very nearly zero if not negative-sum…

Regional Factors

Current Dollars per Capita Gross State Product statistics states compared StateMaster

Current Dollars per Capita Gross State Product statistics states compared StateMaster
  • Normally Americans moved to opportunity–to where people were more productive…
  • Not anymore–the triumph of NIMBYism

Part IV: The Next Fifty Years

Long-Run Impact of the Downturn

Graph Real Gross Domestic Product 3 Decimal FRED St Louis Fed
  • $6000 per adult in potential production lost–that’s $1.2 trillion/year of real wealth that we could be making that we are not, and that it looks like we are never going to recoup.
  • Capitalize at 4%/year in real terms, that’s a $30 trillion hit in real wealth–$150000 per adult
  • But perform the same calculation as to how wealthy we and our descendants will be. At a 1.5%/year real growth rate of productivity and a 4%/year real discount rate, our total prospective wealth is $3.2 million per American adult–$640 trillion
    • Plus the wealth of future immigrants
    • $32 trillion is painful, but not crushing, in that scale

Long-Run Prosperity: The Math

  • No reason not to see a growth of 1.5%/year in measured real product per working-age adult over the next 50 years.
  • Economic growth as measured comes from making cheaper the things we currently make expensively, and there is enormous human ingenuity devoted to that…
  • $80,000/year x exp(1.5% x 50) = $170,000/year come 2065
    • Cf: Median household income in Orinda today is $160,000/year
  • An America that looks–in prosperity–like Orinda today

What Could Go Wrong?

  • Politics
  • War
  • Inequality
  • What will people do?
    • Backs
    • Fingers
    • Brains as cybernetic control mechanisms for managing machines
    • Brains as routine paper-shuffling control mechanisms
    • Smiles
    • Ideas
  • There will be jobs: nothing guarantees they will be well paid
  • “Peak horse”

Prime-Aged Male Employment

Graph Employment Rate Aged 25 54 Males for the United States© FRED St Louis Fed

Things to Read on the Evening of January 6, 2015

Must- and Shall-Reads:

 

  1. Henry Farrell:
    Social democrats in the twin-peaked world — Crooked Timber:
    “There’s plausibly a structural story behind the inability of conventional leftwing parties to challenge conventional orthodoxies…. They haven’t really relied on this constituency for a long time. Peter Mair’s Ruling the Void hasn’t gotten nearly the attention that it deserves…. Mair… makes a strong case that leftwing parties in Europe today have become profoundly disassociated from their voters… ordinary people withdrawing from political parties… elites of parties don’t rely on mass membership to provide resources…. European political parties rather than representing their constituents to the state, tend to represent the state and its imperatives to their constituents. This helps explain the extraordinary haplessness of mainstream leftwing parties faced with the politics of austerity…”

  2. Anonymous and Miles Kimball:
    How Big Is Economics’s Sexism Problem? This Article’s Co-Author Is Anonymous Because of It:
    “One indication of the career challenges women face in economics is the fact that one of us felt the need to remain anonymous…. Many male economists underestimate the headwinds women face in economics… at every stage of a woman’s career… many forces both large and small that add up to a huge overall damper on the number of women who make it to the higher ranks…. And even when women do reach these higher levels—despite the difficulty of getting their work published in male-dominated journals and in getting promoted even when they do get their work published—their wages remain lower…. Sendhil Mullainathan argues that discrimination often operates at an unconscious level…. Here are a few of the issues women in economics face that their male colleagues might not be aware of…”

  3. Joe Romm:
    2014 Was Hottest Year On Record Globally By Far, Reports Japan Meteorological Agency:
    “The Japan Meteorological Agency (JMA) has announced that 2014 was the hottest year… by far… [with] no ‘hiatus’ or ‘pause’ in warming. In fact, there has not even been a slowdown…. 1998 is in (a distant) second place–but 1998 was an outlier… boosted above the trendline by an unusual super-El Niño…. If you were wondering how 2014 could be the hottest year on record when it wasn’t particularly hot in the United States (if we ignore California and Alaska)… there’s like a whole planet out there…. Europe was the hottest it’s been in 500 years…. California had record-smashing heat, which helped create its ‘most severe drought in the last 1200 years.’ Australia broke heat records across the continent (for the second year running)…. Much of Siberia ‘defrosted in spring and early summer under temperatures more than 9°F (5°C) above its 1981 to 2010 average’… the second exceptionally hot summer in a row for the region…. The permafrost (soon to be renamed the permamelt) contains twice as much carbon as the entire atmosphere. If we don’t reverse emissions trends sharply and soon, then the carbon released from it this century alone could boost global warming as much as 1.5°F…”

  4. Paul Krugman:
    Not Invented Here Macroeconomics:
    “[Richard] Koo had a big and important idea…. As long as some part of the private sector has… levels of debt that now look excessive, the efforts of debtors to pay off their debts… [is] a persistent drag… hard to counter with monetary policy, because many players in the economy can’t or won’t spend more…. Deficit spending can play a useful role… by providing a favorable environment for debtors to deleverage…. This is a very useful insight…”

  5. Richard Florida:
    Is Life Better in America’s Red States?:
    “Blue states… are generally richer than red states. But red states, like Texas, Georgia and Utah, have done a better job over all of offering a higher standard of living relative to housing costs…. Red state economies based on energy extraction, agriculture and suburban sprawl may have lower wages, higher poverty rates and lower levels of education… [but] the American dream of a big house with a backyard and a couple of cars is much more achievable in low-tax Arizona than in deep-blue Massachusetts…”

  6. Jérémie Cohen-Setton:
    Permanent QE and helicopter money:
    “What’s at stake: QE… is believed to matter (beyond the portfolio channel) for inflation and growth… the associated monetary base growth needs to be permanent… the pros and cons of helicopter money… as compared with permanent QE…. David Beckworth writes that… [in] the Fed’s quantitative easing programs… the large expansion of the monetary base under QE is temporary… [but] for QE to have made a meaningful difference the associated monetary base growth needed to be permanent. This… is the standard view in modern macroeconomics… Woodford, Svensson, and Obstfeld among others)…”

  7. Eric Engen et al.:
    The Macroeconomic Effects of the Federal Reserve’s Unconventional Monetary Policies:
    “After reaching the effective lower bound for the federal funds rate in late 2008, the Federal Reserve turned to two unconventional policy tools—quantitative easing and increasingly explicit and forward‐ leaning guidance for the future path of the federal funds rate—in order to provide additional monetary policy accommodation. We use survey data from the Blue Chip Economic Indicators to infer changes in private‐sector perceptions of the implicit interest rate rule that the Federal Reserve would use following liftoff from the effective lower bound. Using our estimates of the changes over time in private expectations for the implicit policy rule, and estimates of the effects of the Federal Reserve’s quantitative easing programs on term premiums derived from other studies, we simulate the FRB/US model to assess the actual economic stimulus provided by unconventional policy since early 2009. Our analysis suggests that the net stimulus to real activity and inflation was limited by the gradual nature of the changes in policy expectations and term premium effects, as well as by a persistent belief on the part of the public that the pace of recovery would be much faster than proved to be the case. Our analysis implies that the peak unemployment effect—subtracting 1 1⁄4 percentage points from the unemployment rate relative to what would have occurred in the absence of the unconventional policy actions—does not occur until early 2015, while the peak inflation effect—adding 1⁄2 percentage point to the inflation rate—is not anticipated until early 2016…”

  8. Paul Krugman:
    About That French Time Bomb:
    “I’ve written often about the remarkable track record of U.S. debt-and-inflation doomsayers… now completely unwilling to admit that they were wrong, or even that their model of how the world works needs some revision. But… let’s look back at the bad-mouthing of another economy, which looks equally wrong-headed if not more so…. It was the Economist that declared, on its cover more than two years ago, that France was the time bomb at the heart of Europe. And of course the inflationistas were even more certain that France faced imminent doom; for example, John Mauldin proclaimed that France was in fact worse than Greece. Now that time bomb–which has actually had better economic growth since 2007 than Britain–can borrow at an interest rate of only 0.8 percent. It seems obvious to me that the bad-mouthing of France was and is essentially political. Of course France has big problems; who doesn’t? But the real sin of the French body politic is its refusal to buy into the notion that the welfare state must be sharply downsized if not dismantled; hence the continuing warnings that France is doomed, doomed I tell you. And this in turn reflects the larger issue of what calls for austerity are really about. Can we imagine a clearer demonstration that they’re not really about appeasing bond vigilantes?”

Should Be Aware of:

 

  1. Mark Mazower:
    Napoleon the Great by Andrew Roberts:
    “Hitler took the most powerful country in Europe and wrecked it for a generation, demonstrating in the process how not to run a continent. The one debt we owe Stalin is that he ensured Hitler’s defeat…. Napoleon–another case entirely. He took a country in the throes of acute fiscal crisis and social unrest and made it the dominant power in Europe; he oversaw the shattering of the old ruling order across the continent; he reformed the government; and he transformed the very idea of what politics could be and man could do. All of these achievements proved to be irreversible…”

  2. Jo Walton:
    Gods, Philosophers, and Robots:
    “The Just City is a fantasy novel about a group of classicists and philosophers from across all of time setting up Plato’s Republic on Atlantis, with the help of some Greek gods, ten thousand Greek-speaking ten-year-olds they bought in the slave markets of antiquity, and some construction robots from our near future. What could possibly go wrong?Now I get two different immediate reactions to this. The first is from people who say ‘That’s insane, and I want it now!’ The second is from people who say they know nothing about Plato or philosophy in a kind of apologetic way, as if anything that touches on these subjects in any way would require background reading and be kind of boring…”

Evening Must-Read: Henry Farrell: Social Democrats in the Twin-Peaked World

Henry Farrell:
Social democrats in the twin-peaked world — Crooked Timber:
“There’s plausibly a structural story…

behind the inability of conventional leftwing parties to challenge conventional orthodoxies…. They haven’t really relied on this constituency for a long time. Peter Mair’s Ruling the Void hasn’t gotten nearly the attention that it deserves…. Mair… makes a strong case that leftwing parties in Europe today have become profoundly disassociated from their voters… ordinary people withdrawing from political parties… elites of parties don’t rely on mass membership to provide resources…. European political parties rather than representing their constituents to the state, tend to represent the state and its imperatives to their constituents. This helps explain the extraordinary haplessness of mainstream leftwing parties faced with the politics of austerity…

I am skeptical of this explanation–largely because I remember similar haplessness from the left in Britain, Germany, and France during the Great Depression…

Yes, the Past Four Years Are Powerful Evidence for the Keynesian View of What Happens at the Zero Lower Bound. Why Do You Ask?: Daily Focus

He whom we all disagree with at our grave peril writes:

Paul Krugman:
The Record of Austerity – NYTimes.com:
“How many people, I wonder–even among economists who have eagerly taken sides in the austerity debate…

…have a sense of what the overall picture looks like since the great turn to austerity in 2010… [not] what happened in country X in year Y, which you imagine supports your position… [but] the overall shape…[?] Annual data on the growth of real GDP and of government purchases from Eurostat…. 33 countries for 4 years, 132 observations…. Does this picture make you think that Keynesian economics is nonsense?… The raw observations are consistent with the view that in depressed economies, cutting government spending hurts growth.

The Record of Austerity NYTimes com

Of course, the fit isn’t perfect. In fact, the R-squared is only 0.31. That’s because… stuff happens. And that is why we have statistics…. You can, if you like, try to argue that this relationship is spurious…. But one form of argument that is really illegitimate is to… pick out outliers… claiming that the… outliers–because stuff does, in fact, happen–disproves Keynesian logic. Unfortunately, you see a lot of that, including from economists who really should know better.”

If you assume that all of the correlation reflects a causal connection running from fiscal austerity to slower GDP growth, the associated multiplier μ is 2.3. This is an open-economy multiplier, and the typical country in Eurostat is very open indeed. An open-economy multiplier of 2.3 corresponds to the closed economy multiplier of 4.

What I want to add to Paul’s discussion here is what I see as the absurdity of the arithmetic underlying the reverse-causation argument:

Write “Δ” for “change”, “Y” for “GDP”, “μ” for the fiscal multiplier, “G” for “government purchases”, “ε” for “other things than government purchases that affect GDP”, “λ” for “reverse causation in which falling GDP leads to cuts in government purchases”, “η” for “other things besides GDP that affect government purchases”:

ΔY = μΔG + ε
ΔG = λΔY + η

Make the truly heroic assumption that ε and η are uncorrelated. Define the ratio σ of the variances of ε and η:

V(ε) = σV(η)

The estimated slope from a regression of ΔY on ΔG is then a weighted average of the true fiscal multiplier μ and the inverse of the reverse-causation effect of falling GDP on government spending:

s = ρ(μ) + (1-ρ)(1/λ)

with the weight ρ given by:

ρ = [1/(λ2σ + 1)]

In order to get a high estimated slope out of reverse causation, the value of the parameter λ has to be small–there has to be relatively little influence of falling GDP on government purchases. But if that is the case, then the weighted average that is the slope will put most of its weight on the true multiplier μ. A high estimated slope–on the order of 4 for the closed-economy case–can only be consistent with a small true multiplier μ for a truly absurdly large value of the variance ratio σ: the level of government purchases then has to be a function of GDP and of GDP alone for the arithmetic to work. And that is simply not the case.

See for yourself (always assuming I have not gotten the arithmetic of the spreadsheet wrong):

https://www.icloud.com/numbers/AwBUCAESEGxJW-Ptvft7ke7GVSyFCn0aKTG7eYgd1IpBO71mbm4oq9c5bcYNKyx-VjEFzhkmS3ajp0VWgpQotG6HMCUCAQEEID6VhAAglbqkxhmdoSv8fVGng7UI_KOxMSLYU7QtErMn#2015-01-06_Multipliers_and_Reverse_Causation–Krugman_2010-2013_Eurostat_Regression.numbers

2015 01 06 Multipliers and Reverse Causation Krugman 2010 2013 Eurostat Regression numbers

556 words

Reference points, loss aversion, and redistribution

Economists, policymakers, and the general public are all well aware that the United States has a much higher level of income inequality than other developed countries. But what sets it apart from other nations isn’t the distribution of income but rather the level of redistribution. With high levels of inequality, economists would expect the median U.S. voter to push for more redistribution as the top earners pull further away from those on the middle and bottom of the income ladder.

So why doesn’t the U.S. government redistribute more?

A paper presented at the just-concluded annual Allied Social Sciences Associations meeting in Boston can shed light on this puzzle. The paper, by Columbia University economists Jimmy Charité and Raymond Fisman and Princeton University economist Ilyana Kuziemko argues that preferences for redistribution are affected by what the authors call “reference points.”

One of the insights of behavioral economics is loss aversion. In neoclassical economics, the utility gained from an extra dollar should be the same (but in the opposite direction) as the utility lost by losing a dollar. But research by behavioral economists and psychologists finds that losing a dollar causes a lot more disutility than the utility gained by gaining a dollar. This effect is why it feels much worse to lose $5 than to find a five-dollar bill on the ground.

Charité, Fisman, and Kuziemko present data that indicates loss aversion may explain why U.S. voters don’t redistribute more. To get at this problem, they run an experiment where they present respondents with a hypothetical situation in which two individuals receive money based on a coin flip. One person is given $15 and the other $5. The respondents are then asked to redistribute money between those two hypothetical people.

But the respondents are split into two groups and read slightly different prompts. The first group is told that the two hypothetical people receiving the money will only know the final amount of money they receive, not the money based on the coin flip. If the respondents redistribute $5 then they know the person who initially got $15 will only know in the end that the total amount received is $10.

In contrast, the second group is told that the two hypothetical people are aware of the money they received from the coin flip before redistribution. So again, if the respondents redistribute $5 then one of the people would know they had $15 but ended up with $10.

The results of the experiment show that these reference points actually change the level of redistribution quite a bit. In the first group, the respondents eliminate 94 percent of the income gap. But the group that has reference points and knows the recipients are aware of the redistribution only eliminates 77 percent of the gap. The level of redistribution is decreased by about 20 percent once reference points are included.

Of course, consideration of reference points isn’t the only factor explaining preferences for redistribution. Individuals might think that people deserve to keep a large portion of the money if it is based on skill or merit. Indeed, when the authors changed the reason for the distribution of income from a coin flip to SAT scores, the amount of redistribution declines to 56 percent. The decline in redistribution due to reference points is then about half of the decline caused by the distinction between luck and merit.

What’s so interesting about Charité, Fisman, and Kuziemko’s paper is that it indicates that the general public’s preferences for redistribution might be different from what is assumed in the classic optimal taxation research. Their research isn’t the first to point this out, but it provides more proof that the average person might not be a strict utilitarian. This in turn means that the classical economic model that undermines a fair bit of the conversation about the proper level of progressive taxation might be based on some flawed assumptions. The importance of that fact shouldn’t be lost on economists and policymakers.

Is 1920-1921 Relevant and Worth Much Attention?

The estimable Miles Kimball emails that after http://www.wsj.com/articles/the-depression-that-was-fixed-by-doing-nothing-1420212315 he wonders whether 1920-1921 is not perhaps worthy of more attention.

I agree that it is a very interesting episode: it appears to be the only time in American history in which significant deflationary pressure did not produce a prolonged, deep, grinding slump. Certainly we see a prolonged, deep, grinding slump today; we saw one in the 1930s; and we think we see one back in the Jacksonian era with Jackson’s war on the Second Bank of the United States.

But I do not think it has any lessons at all for us today. It came just after the World War I inflation had boosted the price level and eroded the economy’s debt levels. Thus there was no chance of Fisherman debt-deflation or Koovian balance-sheet recession forces taking hold. And the fact that the run up in wages has been so recent meant that downward wage stickiness was effectively nil. Thus that nominal rigidity that turns a fall in nominal demand into a fall in real production and then to the flight of the Confidence Fairy in the face of general depression was simply absent.

David Frum has just had some smart things to say about this episode:

From David Frum: “The Real Story of How America Became an Economic Superpower”
http://www.theatlantic.com/international/archive/2014/12/the-real-story-of-how-america-became-an-economic-superpower/384034/?single_page=true:

Periodically, attempts have been made to rehabilitate the American leaders of the 1920s. The most recent version, James Grant’s The Forgotten Depression, 1921: The Crash That Cured Itself, was released just two days before The Deluge: Grant, an influential financial journalist and historian, holds views so old-fashioned that they have become almost retro-hip again. He believes in thrift, balanced budgets, and the gold standard; he abhors government debt and Keynesian economics. The Forgotten Depression is a polemic embedded within a narrative, an argument against the Obama stimulus joined to an account of the depression of 1920-21.

As Grant correctly observes, that depression was one of the sharpest and most painful in American history. Total industrial production may have dropped by 30 percent. Unemployment spiked at perhaps close to 12 percent (accurate joblessness statistics don’t exist for this period). Overall, prices plummeted at the steepest rate ever recorded—steeper than in 1929-33. Then, after 18 months of extremely hard times, the economy lurched into recovery. By 1923, the U.S. had returned to full employment.

Grant presents this story as a laissez-faire triumph. Wartime inflation was halted. Borrowing and spending gave way to saving and investing. Recovery then occurred naturally, without any need for government stimulus. ‘The hero of my narrative is the price mechanism, Adam Smith’s invisible hand,’ he notes. ‘In a market economy, prices coordinate human effort. They channel investment, saving and work. High prices encourage production but discourage consumption; low prices do the opposite. The depression of 1920-21 was marked by plunging prices, the malignity we call deflation. But prices and wages fell only so far. They stopped falling when they become low enough to entice consumers into shopping, investors into committing capital and employers into hiring. Through the agency of falling prices and wages, the American economy righted itself.’ Reader, draw your own comparisons!

Grant’s argument is not new. The libertarian economist Murray Rothbard argued a similar case in his 1963 book, America’s Great Depression. The Rothbardian story of the ‘good’ depression of 1920 has resurfaced from time to time in the years since, most spectacularly when Fox News star Glenn Beck seized upon it as proof that the Obama stimulus was wrong and dangerous. Grant tells the story with more verve and wit than most, and with a better eye for incident and character. But the central assumption of his version of events is the same one captured in Rothbard’s title half a century ago: that America’s economic history constitutes a story unto itself.

Widen the view, however, and the ‘forgotten depression’ takes on a broader meaning as one of the most ominous milestones on the world’s way to the Second World War. After World War II, Europe recovered largely as a result of American aid; the nation that had suffered least from the war contributed most to reconstruction. But after World War I, the money flowed the other way.

Take the case of France, which suffered more in material terms than any World War I belligerent except Belgium. Northeastern France, the country’s most industrialized region in 1914, had been ravaged by war and German occupation. Millions of men in their prime were dead or crippled. On top of everything, the country was deeply in debt, owing billions to the United States and billions more to Britain. France had been a lender during the conflict too, but most of its credits had been extended to Russia, which repudiated all its foreign debts after the Revolution of 1917. The French solution was to exact reparations from Germany.

Britain was willing to relax its demands on France. But it owed the United States even more than France did. Unless it collected from France—and from Italy and all the other smaller combatants as well—it could not hope to pay its American debts.

Americans, meanwhile, were preoccupied with the problem of German recovery. How could Germany achieve political stability if it had to pay so much to France and Belgium? The Americans pressed the French to relent when it came to Germany, but insisted that their own claims be paid in full by both France and Britain.

Germany, for its part, could only pay if it could export, and especially to the world’s biggest and richest consumer market, the United States. The depression of 1920 killed those export hopes. Most immediately, the economic crisis sliced American consumer demand precisely when Europe needed it most. True, World War I was not nearly as positive an experience for working Americans as World War II would be; between 1914 and 1918, for example, wages lagged behind prices. Still, millions of Americans had bought billions of dollars of small-denomination Liberty bonds. They had accumulated savings that could have been spent on imported products. Instead, many used their savings for food, rent, and mortgage interest during the hard times of 1920-21.

But the gravest harm done by the depression to postwar recovery lasted long past 1921. To appreciate that, you have to understand the reasons why U.S. monetary authorities plunged the country into depression in 1920.

Grant rightly points out that wars are usually followed by economic downturns. Such a downturn occurred in late 1918-early 1919. ‘Within four weeks of the … Armistice, the [U.S.] War Department had canceled $2.5 billion of its then outstanding $6 billion in contracts; for perspective, $2.5 billion represented 3.3 percent of the 1918 gross national product,’ he observes. Even this understates the shock, because it counts only Army contracts, not Navy ones. The postwar recession checked wartime inflation, and by March 1919, the U.S. economy was growing again.

As the economy revived, workers scrambled for wage increases to offset the price inflation they’d experienced during the war. Monetary authorities, worried that inflation would revive and accelerate, made the fateful decision to slam the credit brakes, hard. Unlike the 1918 recession, that of 1920 was deliberately engineered. There was nothing invisible about it. Nor did the depression ‘cure itself.’ U.S. officials cut interest rates and relaxed credit, and the economy predictably recovered—just as it did after the similarly inflation-crushing recessions of 1974-75 and 1981-82.

But 1920-21 was an inflation-stopper with a difference. In post-World War II America, anti-inflationists have been content to stop prices from rising. In 1920-21, monetary authorities actually sought to drive prices back to their pre-war levels. They did not wholly succeed, but they succeeded well enough. One price especially concerned them: In 1913, a dollar bought a little less than one-twentieth of an ounce of gold; by 1922, it comfortably did so again.

James Grant hails this accomplishment. Adam Tooze forces us to reckon with its consequences for the rest of the planet.

Every other World War I belligerent had quit the gold standard at the beginning of the war. As part of their war finance, they accepted that their currency would depreciate against gold. The currencies of the losers depreciated much more than the winners; among the winners, the currency of Italy depreciated more than that of France, and France more than that of Britain. Yet even the mighty pound lost almost one-fourth of its value against gold. At the end of the conflict, every national government had to decide whether to return to the gold standard and, if so, at what rate.

The American depression of 1920 made that decision all the more difficult. The war had vaulted the United States to a new status as the world’s leading creditor, the world’s largest owner of gold, and, by extension, the effective custodian of the international gold standard. When the U.S. opted for massive deflation, it thrust upon every country that wished to return to the gold standard (and what respectable country would not?) an agonizing dilemma. Return to gold at 1913 values, and you would have to match U.S. deflation with an even steeper deflation of your own, accepting increased unemployment along the way. Alternatively, you could re-peg your currency to gold at a diminished rate. But that amounted to an admission that your money had permanently lost value—and that your own people, who had trusted their government with loans in local money, would receive a weaker return on their bonds than American creditors who had lent in dollars.

Britain chose the former course; pretty much everybody else chose the latter.

The consequences of these choices fill much of the second half of The Deluge. For Europeans, they were uniformly grim, and worse…


From Barry Eichengreen, Golden Fetters:

Economic activity in the industrial countries spiralled downward from the early months of 1920 through the summer of 1921. In July the U.S. economy bottomed out, and by autumn expansion was again underway. No extended recession occurred to impress upon observers the dangers of the policies pursued. Consequently, leading lights within the Federal Reserve System embraced the policy of liquidation. They inadequately recognized the capacity of a policy driven by the imperatives of the gold standard to destabilize the economy. They did not understand the extent to which the pattern of international settlements had come to hinge on foreign lending by the United States. Although the 1920–21 slump revealed that the policy of liquidation could have powerful macroeconomic effects, the economy rebounded quickly and expanded strongly thereafter. Some observers drew the conclusion that the purging of excesses had been quite salutary and urged its repetition on the next occasion, 1928–29, when speculation was again viewed as excessive.

What they failed to appreciate was that a set of very special circumstances was responsible for the U.S. economy’s rapid recovery from the 1920–21 recession. An unusually good harvest in 1921 cushioned the economy’s decline, reducing the prices of the raw materials that served as inputs into a variety of U.S. industries. Even more basically, the policy environment differed fundamentally from that of 1929. With their exchange rates floating against the dollar in 1920–21, European countries were not compelled to follow the Fed in lockstep. Germany, entangled in the international dispute over reparations and unable to put its fiscal house in order, did not mimic the restrictive policies of the United States. The German economy continued to operate under intense demand pressure, causing the mark to depreciate but at the same time moderating deflationary tendencies worldwide. In 1929, having restored the gold standard, Germany would not enjoy the same independence. What was true for Germany was true as well for other countries with depreciating currencies, notably Poland and Austria, both of which managed to largely avoid the effects 1920–21 slump.

Other industrial countries, more successful in avoiding high inflation and more committed to restoring their prewar gold standard parities, felt more pressure to follow the United States. Still, with their exchange rates floating, they could do so at a distance. The United Kingdom was the principal country to capitalize on her freedom to maneuver, allowing sterling prices to fall more slowly than dollar prices through the first half of 1921. As a result, sterling depreciated against the dollar, before making up the lost ground after production had stabilized in the second half of 1921. Sweden similarly pursued less deflationary policies than the United States through the middle of 1921, allowing the krona to weaken against the dollar before reversing the trend once recovery had begun.

The European response had important implications for the United States. From the beginning of 1921 the Fed was on the receiving end of a massive gold inflow. Its reserve ratio rose rapidly, relaxing the constraint on discount policy. German, Austrian, and Polish inflation and the volatility of sterling propelled gold toward the United States. So did the relatively high pressure of demand under which the British and Swedish economies continued to operate. Thus, the refusal of Germany, Austria, Poland, Britain, and Sweden to fully match the restrictive policies implemented in the United States not only moderated the contraction of their own economies but allowed the Fed to reverse course earlier than it could have otherwise. The U.S. recession bottomed out quickly; economic growth resumed. The policy of liquidation, Federal Reserve officials concluded, had only salutary effects. What they failed to realize was that the success of the policy had been contingent on the foreign reaction, a reaction that was possible only because the gold standard had not yet been restored. The situation would be entirely different when recessionary tendencies once again became evident in 1929…

And:

The Fed was determined to eliminate redundant money and credit so that speculative excesses would not recur. The policy came to be known as “liquidation.” In December 1920, the Federal Reserve Board rejected the option of discount rate reductions on the grounds that they threatened to provoke renewed speculative excesses. The following February officials of the New York Fed warned that lower interest rates would provoke an orgy of “wild speculation.” In March the newly appointed Treasury Secretary Andrew Mellon began to lobby for lower rates, but members of the Federal Reserve Board and governors of the New York Fed again warned of the danger of provoking unhealthy stock market speculation. In April the Board rejected similar proposals for similar reasons.

The feeling grew in Washington that the New York Fed lay behind the resistance to reduce interest rates. Mellon and other political appointees intensified their pressure on Benjamin Strong, President of the New York Fed. By May Strong withdrew his resistance in the face of this pressure, and rates were finally reduced. A more immediate concern motivating the maintenance of high discount rates was continued preoccupation with the level of the gold reserve. Although the Fed’s gold cover ratio stopped falling in May, it recovered little through the end of the year. It is hardly surprising that the reserve banks failed to reduce their discount rates significantly until the cover ratio had risen more than marginally above the statutory minimum. If the public attempted to redeem the more than $3 billion of Federal Reserve notes in gold, convertibility would have had to be suspended.

Besides magnifying this risk, a low cover ratio could have other adverse consequences. Aspirations to elevate the dollar to key currency status would have been dealt a blow. Unless the stability of the dollar price of gold remained beyond question, foreign central banks would refuse to hold their exchange reserves in New York. Maintaining high discount rates was viewed as necessary to cement America’s role in the gold standard system. Subsequent observers, with benefit of hindsight, criticized as exaggerated these fears of a short‐run threat to convertibility and a long‐run challenge to the dollar’s key currency status.

But even officials who remained skeptical of the immediacy of the threat saw other reasons to support the policies designed to reduce prices and wages. For example, other countries had already announced their intention to restore the status quo ante. If they reduced wages and prices to 1913 levels while the United States did not, the competitive position of American industry would be eroded. In retrospect, this seems a curious preoccupation. American producers were in an exceptionally strong position relative to their European competitors. A higher level of prices in the United States might have produced gold losses in the short run, but it would have permitted the Europeans to pursue less deflationary policies, which itself would have minimized the Fed’s loss of reserves. The more expansionary posture internationally would benefit all countries. The insular approach of American monetary policymakers reflected their incomplete appreciation of the influence they now exercised over the stance of policy abroad.

Viewed from a longer‐run perspective, however, the American preoccupation with reducing prices was not entirely without logic. Officials within the Federal Reserve System justified it by referring to the danger of a global gold shortage. Little gold had been mined in the course of the war or in the immediate postwar years, and gold production had fallen steadily since 1915. Wartime disruptions to international markets could account for the initial decline in supply but not for the failure of gold production to recover subsequently. Disorganized conditions in Russia played a role, but the principal factor blamed for depressing mining activity was the rise in wage rates and other production costs relative to the fixed dollar price of gold.

Admittedly, gold no longer traded in London at the official price but at higher prices that reflected sterling’s depreciation against the dollar. But the London gold premium incorporated only depreciation of the British currency, not the American inflation. Heightening the danger created by the decline in the supply of newly mined gold was the prospect that the demand would expand rapidly as the world economy recovered. Once countries returned to the gold standard, the demand for yellow metal would rise further. The point was underscored by American and European gold losses in 1919–20 to other parts of the world. Various expedients were proposed, including subsidies for gold production, taxes on gold used for nonmonetary purposes, and reliance on foreign exchange to supplement the gold reserves of central banks. But the only lasting solution was to engineer a decline in price levels, which would increase the real value of existing gold reserves and, by raising real gold prices, enhance the incentive to augment them.

The American recession exerted a powerful influence over the rest of the world. During the boom, the United States had exported capital, fueling money and credit expansion in Europe. American capital exports in 1919–20 (principally trade credits channeled through London) exceeded the amount of lending the United States engaged in during any other two years of the interwar period. Despite the European clamor for U.S. goods, American import demands had been sufficiently strong that the United States had been a net exporter of gold. From the end of 1920, the process operated in reverse. American lending fell off, as shown in Figure 4.5. The United States began to attract gold from the rest of the world on a massive scale. Except insofar as they were willing to permit their currencies to depreciate, other countries were forced to initiate restrictive measures to offset this balance‐of‐payments shock. U.S. foreign lending and the gold and foreign exchange reserves of the Federal Reserve System fluctuated inversely throughout the 1920s, reserves rising when foreign lending fell and vice versa.