The Geography of ObamaCare Nullification: A Remarkable Conundrum of Political Economy

We all know this.

But it is highlighted by the work of the very sharp Carter Price and David Evans, who have the infographic of the month:

Carter C. Price and David Evans: Where do the beneficiaries of the Affordable Care Act Live?: “Beneficiaries of the Affordable Care Act… by state and county…

…access to expanded Medicaid… and how a ruling by the Supreme Court in… King vs. Burwell… would affect ACA coverage…

From the perspective of any individual state, both the Medicaid expansion funds and the health-exchange subsidy funs are free money:

The first provides federal reimbursement for new Medicaid enrollees’ covered health-care services, and reduces state-level funding burdens to the extent that state-level programs are superseded by Medicaid expansion (and every state has some such). Roughly half of the direct money flow shows up as better access to health care for the non-working poor and the working poor of states that expand Medicaid. The other half of the direct money flow shows up as hospitals, doctors, and nurses getting paid for things they currently do for free. And all of the direct flow shows up as higher incomes for those working for the health-care sector. And then there are the indirect flows: in the long run after migration of businesses, capital, and labor is completed, one extra dollar in federal money coming into a region leads to a six-dollar boost to regional economic product.

The second do the same–only for the working classes: both those who were not able to afford insurance in the malfunctioning pre-exchange small-group market, and those of the working classes who did somehow scrape up the money for insurance at the cost of great financial pressure on their budgets. Significant improvement in the health access and financial status of beneficiaries. Better income statements and balance sheets for hospitals, doctors, and nurses. And, of course, the same six-to-one long-run regional economic product multiplier.

The infographics are great–the only thing I would wish for would be for a third dimension for population density, or perhaps tracking population numbers rather than population percentages (but percentages are useful):

Where do the beneficiaries of the Affordable Care Act Live Washington Center for Equitable Growth

When we look at the Medicaid expansion map, we see graphically–literally graphically–the extraordinary unconcern of the Red State political establishments for the health and financial stability of their non-working poor and working poor, and for the financial prosperity of their health-care sectors. If you were a die-hard nullificationist in 2011 you might have argued that a Republican victory in 2012 would overturn the game board and that a Red State should not look itself into ObamaCare. But ObamaCare will be at most tweaked in 2017. And the states that failed to expand are now throwing away enough free money to make a difference on the statewide economic level between rapid and sluggish economic growth.

The only way I can find to understand the pattern of Medicaid expansion nullification is a truly extraordinary unconcern on the part of Red State politicians with their poor–whether working or non-working–and substantial insulation as a result of the rise of right-wing billionaires from financial pressures put on them by the doctors who used to be the financial fund-raising bedrock base of the Republican Party. Plus remarkable unconcern with the the health of their state-level economies. But even if they do not care about the well-being of their citizens, they should care about competing for the votes of the non-working and the working poor, shouldn’t they? Or do they just think that the poor are low-information voters, and that those who pull the lever for the Republicans will not be unhornswoggled by looking across the Missouri-Illinois or the Tennessee-Kentucky or the Mississippi-Arkansas or the Texas-New Mexico state line and thinking: “Hmmmm…”

The ineffectiveness of the voice of the doctors I just do not understand. It goes against all theories of rational-choice political economy, it does.

Where do the beneficiaries of the Affordable Care Act Live Washington Center for Equitable Growth

The picture of those at risk from a sadistic nullification opinion by John Roberts in King v. Burwell looks remarkably similar. Idaho and Nevada somehow established state-rune exchanges without expanding Medicaid, and so their working classes are insulated. And the working classes of Pennsylvania, Ohio, and Indiana are added to those at risk, as are those of Nebraska, North Dakota, and Wyoming.

Once again, the lack of power of the health lobby to move the Red-State Republican political establishments is astonishing. The lack of any sense on the part of the Red-State Republican political establishment that they are there to work for or in any sense represent the working classes of their states is astonishing

The Macroeconomic Catastrophe Through the Lens of the Employment-to-Population Ratio

I forgot to note Ben Zipperer’s post on the labor market and the BLS Employment Report last Friday. And if I had, I would have stressed what the employment numbers tell us about how extraordinarily far to go we have before even semi-complete recovery.

Ben Zipperer: Weak U.S. Employment Gains and Wage Growth: “126,000 more people employed in the United States in March compared to the prior month…

…weak employment growth… not accompanied by strong hourly wage gains…. Over the last three months, the US economy has added a monthly average of 197,000 jobs… these job gains have not been sufficient to generate substantial wage growth…. In March…h the employed share of the population aged 16-to-24 years dropping to 48.2 percent from 48.9 percent. Until March the employment situation for younger workers had generally improved… but employment rates for the young still remain at historic lows….

Last month the hourly pay for workers in the private sector grew at a 2.1 percent annual rate compared to last year, and at an annual rate of 2.8 percent over the past three months…. The contrast is even sharper when looking back over the past six months… nonsupervisory wages have grown at an annual rate of about 1.8 percent…. For workers to maintain or increase their share of income, nominal wages must grow at an annual rate of at least 3.5 percent…. Since 1990, nominal wage growth sustainably exceeded the 3.5 percent threshold only when the prime-age employment rate remained above 79 percent. The employment-to-population ratio for prime-age workers in the past month was 77.2 percent…

Graph Employment Rate Aged 25 54 Males for the United States© FRED St Louis Fed Graph Employment Rate Aged 25 54 Females for the United States© FRED St Louis Fed Graph Employment Rate Aged 15 24 Males for the United States© FRED St Louis Fed Graph Employment Rate Aged 15 24 Females for the United States© FRED St Louis Fed

Why Is the “Middle Class” Stressed?: An interesting New Hypothesis from Emmons and Noeth

There have long been a bunch of hypotheses about why the American “middle class” feels “stressed” in spite of constant real incomes and what appears to me increased utility over time as more expenditure shifts toward information goods where consumer surplus is a higher multiple of factor cost:

  1. Americans are used to seeing real incomes improve at 2%/year–doubling every generation–and they have not been getting that. Living little better than your predecessors a generation ago is an unpleasant shock.

  2. The things that have been becoming cheaper are not seen as things key to your “middle class” status, while the things becoming more expensive and difficult to obtain–a detached house in a good neighborhood with a short commute, health insurance, secure pensions, a good education for your children–are things that it used to be taken for granted a middle-class family could get.

  3. The widening gap between the middle class and the upper class.

Now come Emmons and Noeth with a new and very interesting hypothesis: that people who have done better than their parents with respect to education and family structure are no richer, and people who have matched their parents with respect to education and family structure are poorer. In other words, people who thought they were upwardly mobile are finding themselves with no higher real incomes. And people who thought they were sociologically stable are finding themselves poorer:

Michael Hiltzik: Why the middle class is doing even worse than you think – LA Times: “The numbers say that the middle class is doing OK…. Middle class families themselves say they’re being crushed under economic hobnail boots…

…William R. Emmons and Bryan J. Noeth… find… median [real] income… has been stable; but the middle class genuinely is falling behind that mark…. Economists… defin[e] the middle class as households with income roughly 50% higher and lower than the median…. $26,000 to $78,000.
Sociologists… define the middle class… demographically…. Households headed by someone aged at least 40… with near-average income and wealth, headed by a white or Asian with a high-school diploma, no more or less, or by a black or Hispanic with a two- or four-year college degree…. These households are sandwiched between “thrivers,” families with above-average income or wealth, headed by someone with a two- or four-year college degree “who is non-Hispanic white or Asian”; and “stragglers,” headed by someone without a high school degree or, if black or Hispanic, a high school diploma at most….

The real middle class (blue) has been sinking… upper-income “Thrivers” (orange) have been doing better relative to their benchmark, the 75th percentile of U.S. income, and low-income “Stragglers” (green) have been holding steady…. The median income of the demographically defined middle class… is 16% lower now than it was in 1989…. The sociologically defined middle-class family ranked at the 55th percentile of U.S. income earners in 1989; by 2013 it had fallen to the 45th percentile…

NewImage

Morning Must-Read: John Gruber: The Apple Watch

John Gruber: Daring Fireball: The Apple Watch: “Apple Watch is… the Bizarro iPhone… parallel and similar, but…the inverse, the opposite…

…Both were introduced as three things in one…. An iPod, a phone, and an ‘Internet communicator’…. A watch, a ‘new way to connect with each other’, and a health and fitness companion…. Loosely, the path of all consumer electronic categories is to evolve as ever more computer-y gadgets, until a tipping point occurs and they turn into ever more gadget-y genuine computers…. Apple seemingly tries to enter… just after that tipping point–when Moore’s Law and… engineering and manufacturing prowess allow them to produce a gadget-y computer that the computer-y gadgets from the established market leaders cannot compete with. That was the iPod. That was the iPhone.
That, they hope, is Apple Watch…

I See I Have Annoyed the Very Sharp David Glasner: Milton Friedman and the History of Economic Thought Edition

Over at Equitable Growth: Apropos of my The Monetarist Mistake over at Project Syndicate, the very sharp David Glasner is annoyed, and attempts to administer a smackdown. I think he misses:

David Glasner: Milton Friedman, Monetarism, and the Great and Little Depressions | Uneasy Money: “I find this criticism of Friedman and his followers just a bit annoying…

…Why? Well, there are a number of reasons, but I will focus on one: it perpetuates the myth that a purely monetary explanation of the Great Depression originated with Friedman.

And David then goes on to write a great deal of accurate, true, and insightful things about the history of economic thought, about the Great Depression, plus some insightful but I am not sure accurate and complete thoughts about the past decade:

It wasn’t Friedman who first propounded a purely monetary theory of the Great Depression. Nor did the few precursors, like Clark Warburton, that Friedman ever acknowledged. Ralph Hawtrey and Gustav Cassel did–10 years before the start of the Great Depression in 1919…. The Genoa Monetary Conference of 1922, inspired by the work of Hawtrey and Cassel…. The Genoa system worked moderately well until 1928 when the Bank of France, totally defying the Genoa Agreement, launched its insane policy of converting its monetary reserves into physical gold…. In late 1928 and 1929, the Fed, responding to domestic fears about a possible stock-market bubble, kept raising interest rates to levels not seen since the deflationary disaster of 1920-21. And sure enough, a 6.5% discount rate (just shy of the calamitous 7% rate set in 1920) reversed the flow of gold out of the US, and soon the US was accumulating gold almost as rapidly as the insane Bank of France was. This was exactly the scenario against which Hawtrey and Cassel had been warning since 1919…. For reasons I don’t really understand, Keynes was intent on explaining the downturn in terms of his own evolving theoretical vision of how the economy works, even though just about everything that was happening had already been foreseen by Hawtrey and Cassel.

More than a quarter of a century after the fact… along came Friedman, woefully ignorant of pre-Keynesian monetary theory, but determined to show that the Keynesian explanation for the Great Depression was wrong and unnecessary. So Friedman came up with his own explanation of the Great Depression that did not even begin until December 1930…. Rather than see the Great Depression as a global phenomenon caused by a massive increase in the world’s monetary demand for gold, Friedman portrayed it as a largely domestic phenomenon, though somehow linked to contemporaneous downturns elsewhere, for which the primary explanation was the Fed’s passivity in the face of contagious bank failures. Friedman… ignorantly disregarded the monetary theory of the Great Depression that had already been worked out by Hawtrey and Cassel and substituted in its place a simplistic, dumbed-down version of the quantity theory. So Friedman reinvented the wheel, but did a really miserable job of it….

The problem with Friedman is not, as Delong suggests, that he distracted us from the superior insights of Keynes and Minsky into the causes of the Great Depression. The problem is that Friedman botched the monetary theory, even though the monetary theory had already been worked out for him if only he had bothered to read it…. We do know that the key factor explaining recovery from the Great Depression was leaving the gold standard. And the most important example of the importance of leaving the gold standard is the remarkable explosion of output in the US beginning in April 1933…. Between April and July 1933, industrial production in the US increased by 70%, stock prices nearly doubled, employment rose by 25%, while wholesale prices rose by 14%. All that is directly attributable to FDR’s decision to take the US off gold, and devalue the dollar (see here). Unfortunately, in July 1933, FDR snatched defeat from the jaws of victory (or depression from the jaws of recovery) by starting the National Recovery Administration, whose stated goal was (OMG!) to raise prices by cartelizing industries and restricting output, while imposing a 30% increase in nominal wages. That was enough to bring the recovery to a virtual standstill….

You can’t prove that monetary policy is useless just by reminding us that Friedman liked to assume (as if it were a fact) that the demand for money is highly insensitive to changes in the rate of interest. The difference between the rapid recovery from the Great Depression when countries left the gold standard and the weak recovery from the Little Depression is that leaving the gold standard had an immediate effect on price-level expectations, while monetary expansion during the Little Depression was undertaken with explicit assurances by the monetary authorities that the 2% inflation target–in the upper direction, at any rate–was, and would forever more remain, sacred and inviolable.

Whew. A long quote. But I don’t have time today to cut it down to its essentials–and David is well worth reading.

But in response I say:

  1. David is, I think, correct in saying that Milton Friedman had the wrong monetary explanation of the Great Depression, and Hawtrey had the right one. But it doesn’t matter. Milton Friedman’s was the only explanation North Atlantic macroeconomics heard from 1970 to 2008. And it was the version North Atlantic macroeconomics believed, and so neglected Keynes and Minsky–and Hawtrey. Thus here, I say, is thus annoyed at me not for getting anything wrong but, rather, for reminding him of an unpleasant reality.

  2. David is, I think, also annoyed at me for failing to recognize that the Lesser Depression would have come to a quick end had the Federal Reserve and the ECB committed themselves at the end of 2008 to a permanent 5%/year inflation target, and for instead dinking around with Keynesian fiscal policy and Minskyite credit policy ideas. But the failure of Abenomics to make more of a difference keeps me from being as certain as David is. I certainly believe that Neville Chamberlain’s policy of returning the British price level to its pre-1930 level and Franklin Roosevelt’s abandonment of the gold standard were monetary régime changes that worked wonders. But I do not think that justifies ignoring Keynesian and Minskyite ideas of alternative ways of restoring macroeconomic balance–especially given the illegality of a 5%/year inflation target in both the United States and in the European Union.

Morning Must-Read: Bill Gurley: Investors Beware: Today’s $100M+ Late-stage Private Rounds Are Very Different from an IPO

Morning Must-Read: Bill Gurley: Investors Beware: Today’s $100M+ Late-stage Private Rounds Are Very Different from an IPO: “The first critical difference is that these late-stage private companies have not endured the immense scrutiny that is a part of every IPO process….

…Companies and their board of directors agonize over whether or not they are “ready” to go public. Auditors, bankers, three different sets of lawyers, and let us not forget the S.E.C., spend months and months making sure that every single number is correct, important risks are identified, the accounting is all buttoned up, and the proper controls are in place…. Late-stage private rounds have no such pageantry or process. There is typically just a single PowerPoint deck presentation…. Investors are assuming that the numbers they see in the fund-raising deck are the same as those they might see in an S-1. However, many of these private companies will wait up to twelve months after the end of a fiscal year to complete their audit…. Startups commonly highlight “gross revenue”…. A good banker in a normal IPO process would get this straightened out…. [And] the very act of dumping hundreds of millions of dollars into an immature private company can also have perverse effects on a company’s operating discipline…

How does job turnover affect U.S. workers’ wellbeing?

Climbing the income ladder by moving from job to job is incredibly important for workers’ success because job-hopping is the main source of wage and income growth for the broad workforce. But do people actually enjoy the experience of working in such a dynamic labor market? A new working paper from the National Bureau of Economic Research looks at how job turnover affects people’s self-reported wellbeing.

The research by Philippe Aghion of Harvard University, Ufuk Akcigit of the University of Pennsylvania, Angus Deaton of Princeton University, and Alexandra Roulet at Harvard, looks at how the destruction and creation of jobs (job churn, in economic parlance) affects how people report in the area their wellbeing. To measure wellbeing, the authors use survey data about people’s self-reported wellbeing. Specifically, they focus on questions about satisfaction in the present from the Behavioral Risk Factor Surveillance System, and in the future from the Gallup Healthways Wellbeing Index. The two data sets combined cover 2005 to 2011.

Theoretically, job churn could affect wellbeing in two different ways. Perhaps most intuitively, job destruction can be, well, destructive. When a worker loses a job or sees enough neighbors lose jobs then that’s a sign of risk and that will reduce reported wellbeing. But at the same time, job churn may also mean a higher rate of job creation. More job creation means more unemployed people are likely to get a job. Once employed, these individuals are more likely to enjoy the fruits of stronger economic growth, and consequently, higher wages, boosting a worker’s present overall wellbeing as well as expectations of future wellbeing.

Aghion, Akcigit, Deaton, and Roulet estimate the effects of job churn by looking at data from the 381 metropolitan statistical areas across the United States. The authors’ results broadly mesh with what you’d expect. If you control for the level of unemployment in particular metropolitan regions, the relationship between job churn and wellbeing is “unambiguously positive.” At any given rate of unemployment, more churn is associated with more wellbeing.

That being said, it is important to break the turnover down into job creation and job destruction to fully understand what is going on. Empirically, more job creation in a metropolitan statistical area is correlated with higher wellbeing and more job destruction is correlated with lower wellbeing. But the size of these effects can be very different depending upon other contexts within particular metropolitan regions.

Consider unemployment insurance. Some metro regions are in states where unemployment insurance is more generous than in other states. The authors look at how the effects of turnover might be different depending upon the level of unemployment insurance available within the state. They find that the positive effects of job creation on self-reported wellbeing aren’t affected by the size of an unemployment check. Yet they also find that the negative effects of job destruction are mitigated by the size of the weekly unemployment check. In fact, job destruction has a positive effect on wellbeing in those metropolitan statistical areas where better unemployment insurance compensation is available above the median.

So it appears that some of the downsides of job churn for workers’ wellbeing can be mitigated by policy action that makes job-hopping less daunting and thus ultimately more rewarding in terms of career advancement and income growth. In other words, dynamism and economic security don’t appear to be in tension.

Lunchtime Must-Read: Olivier Blanchard: Contours of Macroeconomic Policy in the Future

Lunchtime Must-Read: Olivier Blanchard: Contours of Macroeconomic Policy in the Future: ” Raghuram Rajan, Ken Rogoff, Larry Summers and I are organizing a third conference, ‘Rethinking Macro Policy III: Progress or Confusion?’…

…April 15-16 at the IMF. Much of the discussion… has centered (rightly) on… what measures to take during a financial or sovereign crisis, what to do at the zero lower bound, how to design quantitative easing, at what rate should fiscal consolidation take place?The focus of our conference will be instead on the architecture of policy when (hopefully) policy rates have become positive again, and most countries are growing and have stabilized debt-to-GDP ratios. In other words, how will/should macro policy look once the crisis is finally over?…

Much effort has gone toward improving our understanding and assessment of systemic risk. Questions:  Where do we stand?…. And have we made enough progress in reducing systemic risk?… State-dependent regulations are the new policy kids on the block…. We are still grappling with which macroprudential tools to develop, how to use them, and the reliability of their effects….

Even before the crisis started, there were sharply different views on whether central banks should have a single mandate (price stability) or a dual mandate (price stability and stable economic activity). The crisis has… led to the suggestion that central banks should have a triple mandate, with financial stability added to the first two…. The zero (or as we are now discovering, the slightly negative) lower bound on the interest rate set by central banks was thought to be a theoretical curiosum…. If reached, central banks could, through announcements of future monetary policy, increase expected inflation and achieve large negative interest rates.  We have learned that this was simply wishful thinking….

When the financial system froze, and monetary policy no longer worked, most advanced economies relied on fiscal policy to limit the decrease in demand, and in turn on output… [with] a dramatic increase in the debt- to-GDP ratio. Since then, the focus has been on the rate at which this ratio should be first stabilized and then decreased…. If we have truly entered a period of secular stagnation, with an excess of saving leading to a negative real rate, doesn’t it make sense for governments to run larger deficits and increase public investment? Most observers agree that the fiscal stimulus early in the crisis was instrumental in limiting the decrease in output. Questions:  Doesn’t this suggest that we should take more seriously the role of fiscal policy as a macro policy tool? Most countries allow for automatic stabilizers…. Could they be improved—and why has there been so little thinking about it?…

Morning Must-Read: Ben Bernanke: Should monetary policy take into account risks to financial stability?

Ben Bernanke: Should monetary policy take into account risks to financial stability?: “In light of our recent experience, threats to financial stability must be taken extremely seriously…

…However, as a means of addressing those threats, monetary policy is far from ideal…. It is a blunt tool… can only do so much… [if] diverted to the task of reducing risks to financial stability… not available to help the Fed attain… full employment and price stability…. It’s better to rely on targeted measures to promote financial stability, such as financial regulation and supervision, rather than on monetary policy…

Today’s Must-Must-Read: Ann Marie Mariciarlle: NIMBYism, the Supreme Court, and Health Care Professional Self-Regulation

Today’s Must-Must-Read: Ann Marie Marciarille: Teeth Whitening at the Supreme Court: The Antitrust Limits of Professional Sovereignty: “North Carolina’s Dental Board functioned more as a trade association with super powers granted to it by the state…

Like it or not, the dissent argues the delegation was valid and the Sherman Act does not sit to second guess the wisdom or even fairness of the delegation. Whatever you think of the dissent, Justice Alito is spot on when he notes that the majority opinion is potentially quite disruptive for state medical licensing boards.. long… under full sway of the regulated health professions themselves…. Self-licensing, ascendent since the late 19th century, was the outcome of political compromise and not solely the seemingly inevitable result  of deference to professional authority traced in today’s opinions…. We have almost no tradition of genuine state regulation of doctors, dentists, and optometrists other than the North Carolina Dental Board model or something like it. If we aim to take it over it will not be a taking it back, but a taking it on–an invention out of whole cloth.