Things to Read on the Evening of November 14, 2013

Must-Reads:

Should-Reads:

Things to Be Aware of:

Uwe Reinhardt Is Unhappy with the Idea That What Health-Care Financing Needs Is More Cost Sharing

Austin Frakt sends us to Uwe Reinhardt on health-insurance cost-sharing:

[T]he often advanced idea that American patients should have “more skin in the game” through higher cost sharing, inducing them to shop around for cost-effective health care, so far has been about as sensible as blindfolding shoppers entering a department store in the hope that inside they can and will then shop smartly for the merchandise they seek. So far the application of this idea in practice has been as silly as it has been cruel.

Continue reading “Uwe Reinhardt Is Unhappy with the Idea That What Health-Care Financing Needs Is More Cost Sharing”

Judge Denny Chin Approves of Google Books as It Is Currently Constituted…

Good to see. The plaintiffs here have done, I think, a bad thing by delaying and trying to further delay the evolution of the Universal Online Library of Humanity. It would be better if the Library of Congress had done it rather than Google, but the Bush Administration and the Congress dropped the ball. It would have been much better had the plaintiffs settled with Google–they would be better off, and all of us reader would be much better off, than they are now:

Judge Denny Chin: Google Summary Judgment:

In my view, Google Books provides significant public benefits. It advances the progress of the arts and sciences, while maintaining respectful consideration for the rights of authors and other creative individuals, and without adversely impacting the rights of copyright holders. It has become an invaluable research tool that permits students, teachers,librarians, and others to more efficiently identify and locate books. It has given scholars the ability, for the first time, to conduct full-text searches of tens of millions of books. It preserves books, in particular out-of-print and old books that have been forgotten in the bowels of libraries, and it gives them new life. It facilitates access to books for print-disabled and remote or underserved populations. It generates new audiences and creates new sources of income for authors and publishers. Indeed, all society benefits.

Continue reading “Judge Denny Chin Approves of Google Books as It Is Currently Constituted…”

Market, State, Bureaucracy: What We Need to Learn: Thursday Focus

As I like to say, we are moving into a twenty-first century in which we are highly likely to spend a greater share of our collective income on:

  1. pensions (for our societies are aging);
  2. education (for the technological world in which we maneuver as adults is only getting more complicated);
  3. health care (what else are we going to be spending money on? Taylor Swift videos? Car elevators?); and
  4. information and information-like goods (for the share of things we value that are produced under conditions of roughly constant returns to scale and that are both rival and excludible looks like it is dropping).

Historical experience teaches us that whenever we try to supply any of these four needs via an un- or a lightly-regulated market, it does not go so well. This suggests that we are likely to be happy in the twenty-first century only if we shift our collective economic cognition and organization to place somewhat less emphasis on the market and more on… something.

The problem is that we have–or, at least, from where I sit I think we have–very good ideas about the success and failure modes of markets (i.e., Friedrich Hayek (1947), Individualism and Economic Order; Kenneth Arrow (1969), “The Organization of Economic Activity: Issues Pertinent to the Choice of Market versus Non-market Allocation”). We know rather less about the success and failure modes of politics (i.e., James Buchanan and Gordon Tullock, The Calculus of Consent; Mancur Olson, The Logic of Collective Action; Josiah Ober, Democracy and Knowledge: Innovation and Learning in Classical Athens).

And, IMHO at least, we know very little about the success and failure modes of bureaucracy.

So I would like to call for people to think, and think hard, so that a generation hence we know as much about the success and failure modes of bureaucracy and politics as we do about markets–and, I hope at least, have evolved some more tweaks to make all three modes of social organization and cognition less subject to failure.

Alas, I have no special insight into how to start thinking about these matters. But Cosma Shalizi has the best diving board I have found:

Review of Edwin Hutchins, Cognition in the Wild: Human beings coordinate their actions to do things which would be hard or impossible for them individually. This is not a particularly recondite fact, and the recognition of it is ancient; it is in the fifth book of Lucretius’s De Rerum Natura, for instance…. The nineteenth century, and to a lesser degree this one, have witnessed a dramatic expansion in the numbers of us engaged in administration, bureaucracy, management, oversight–that is to say, in formally-organized tasks of collective cognition and control. We did not invent bureaucracy, the mainstay of the ancient empires, but we’re much, much better at it… corrupt, inefficient institutions which work poorly; every election, Piffleburg [WI]’s citizens mutter something like “what do we pay taxes for anyway?” Yet to run any one of these institutions at the level of honesty, efficiency and efficacy which makes Piffleburg grumble would have demanded the full powers and attention of even the ablest Roman propraetor or Tang magistrate. That all of those institutions, plus the ones not restricted to a single city, could be run at once, and while governed by a very ordinary slice of common humanity, would have seemed to such officials flatly impossible.

The immediate question this raises, of why we are so much better at collective endeavors than the ancients, can be answered fairly simply. To a first approximation, the answer is: brute force and massive literacy. We teach nearly everyone to read and write, and to do it, by historical standards, at a high level. This lets us staff large bureaucracies (by some estimates, over 40% of the US workforce does data-handling), which lets us run an industrial economy (the trains run on time), which makes us rich enough to afford to educate everyone and keep them in bureaucratic employment, with some surplus left over to expand the system.

This would do us no good if our ideas of administration were as shabby as those of our ancestors in the dark ages, but they’re not: we inherited those of the ancient empires, and have had quite a while to improve upon them (and improvements are made easier and faster by the large number of administrators and the high standard of literacy). Among the improvements are many techniques (standardized procedures, standardized parts, standardized credentials and jobs, explicit qualifications for jobs and goods, files, standardized categories) and devices (forms, punch cards, punch card tabulators, adding machines, card catalogs, and, recently, computers) for making the administration of people and things easier. (We’ve been over parts of this before, looking at James Beniger’s book on The Control Revolution and Ernest Gellner’s Nations and Nationalism.)

All this is in the realm of technique; when it comes to theory, we are quite at a loss. We can see, in a rough, common-sensical way, what makes us better at running things than the Romans were, but we don’t understand how either they or us pull off the trick at all. That is to say, we don’t really have a good theory about how collective action and cognition work, when and why they do, how they can be made to work better, why they fail, what they can and cannot accomplish, and so forth.

Intellectually, these are large, tempting problems; technologically, they have obvious relevance to the design of parallel and distributed computers; economically, they could mean real money, not just billions; and, in general, it’d be nice to know what it is we’ve gotten ourselves into.

Now, in a sense, this problem has been approached by many of the social sciences…. Much of the most interesting research on these problems has been done by economists. The great Friedrich Hayek (that is, Friedrich Hayek the profound social scientist, not to be confused with his evil twin, Friedrich Hayek the right-wing ideologue) was apparently the first to point out that markets perform a kind of collective cognition or calculation which would be beyond the scope of the individual actors in the markets. Since his time, the economists have devoted considerable thought to how the way a group is put together–its procedures, the distribution of power, resources, beliefs and preferences within it–effects the decisions it arrives at, the courses of action open to it. Some of this work, like Arrow’s Social Choice and Individual Values and Olson’s Logic of Collective Action–is now classical, and, under various names, it’s an active, thriving area of inquiry….

[But still] we know next to nothing about how collective cognition works, or when it works, or how to make it work better; we have some ideas about it, but at best they’ve the status of artisanal rules of thumb…

1113 words…

When Markets Attack!: Kevin Drum Snags One on Lawyers’ Starting Salaries

When 15 large law firms each believe that the stakes are very high in their hiring “the best” first-year associates–and also believe that they and their peers can successfully identify “the best” first-year associates, this is what happens:

Starting Salaries for Attorneys Are Pretty Weird Mother Jones

A very nice and impressive demonstration of market failure–the kind of thing to make George Akerlof’s heart go pit-a-pat. Not a situation in which the competitive market is doing very well as a societal computation and allocation mechanism, is it?

Continue reading “When Markets Attack!: Kevin Drum Snags One on Lawyers’ Starting Salaries”

People Should Read Ta-Nehisi Coates on “Conventional Views”, Richard Cohen, and the Washington Post

This is beyond the remit of the Washington Center for Equitable Growth. Nevertheless, every American who has given, still gives, or contemplates ever giving money to the Washington Post for any purpose needs to read Ta-Nehisi Coates:

Ta-Nehisi Coates: Richard Cohen in Context:

I read the entire column. I saw the preceding grafs where Cohen offers a rough history of the Dixiecrats and segregationists wing of America. And then I read this:

Today’s GOP is not racist, as Harry Belafonte alleged about the tea party, but it is deeply troubled—about the expansion of government, about immigration, about secularism, about the mainstreaming of what used to be the avant-garde. People with conventional views must repress a gag reflex when considering the mayor-elect of New York–a white man married to a black woman and with two biracial children. (Should I mention that Bill de Blasio’s wife, Chirlane McCray, used to be a lesbian?) This family represents the cultural changes that have enveloped parts—but not all—of America. To cultural conservatives, this doesn’t look like their country at all.

The problem here isn’t that we think Richard Cohen gags at the sight of an interracial couple and their children.

The problem is that Richard Cohen thinks being repulsed isn’t actually racist, but “conventional” or “culturally conservative.”

Obstructing the right of black humans and white humans to form families is a central feature of American racism. If retching at the thought of that right being exercised isn’t racism, then there is no racism. 

Context can not improve this. “Context” is not a safe word that makes all your other horse-shit statements disappear. And horse-shit is the context in which Richard Cohen has, for all these years, wallowed. It is horse-shit to claim that store owners are right to discriminate against black males. It is horse-shit to claim Trayvon Martin was wearing the uniform of criminals. It is horse-shit to subject your young female co-workers to “a hostile work environment.” It is horse-shit to expend precious newsprint lamenting the days when slovenly old dudes had their pick of 20-year-old women. It is horse-shit to defend a rapist on the run because you like “The Pianist”. And it is horse-shit for Katherine Weymouth, the Post’s publisher, to praise a column with the kind of factual error that would embarrass a j-school student.

Richard Cohen’s unfortunate career is the proper context to understand his column today and the wide outrage that’s greeted it. We are being told that Cohen finds it “hurtful” to be called racist. I am sorry that people on the Internet have hurt Richard Cohen’s feelings. I find it “hurtful” that Cohen endorses the police profiling my son. I find it eternally “hurtful” that the police, following that same logic, killed one of my friends. I find it hurtful to tell my students that, even in this modern age, vending horse-shit is still an esteemed and lucrative profession.

Things to Read on the Evening of November 13, 2013

Must-Reads:

Should-Reads:

Should Be Aware of:

The Role of a Central Bank and of a Central Banker: Cutting-Edge Economics from 188 Years Ago: Wednesday Focus

On the eve of Janet Yellen’s confirmation hearing for the post of Federal Reserve Chair, a correspondent who, I fear, does not wish me well directs me to George F. Will’s Sunday Washington Post column: The Enigma of Janet Yellen as Fed Chair. There is no “enigma” here. It is now nineteen years since her first senior policymaking job at the Federal Reserve. Her views on monetary policy, financial regulation, and the role of the Federal Reserve are well-known. And, as is also well-known, with Janet Yellen you get what you order.

The middle of Wills’s op-ed contains five paragraphs about how Fed Chair Arthur Burns and Will-supported President Richard Nixon behaved very badly indeed when in office, warping monetary policy away from its proper course in the interest of boosting Nixon’s already-high reelection prospects. It contains a hint that there is something wrong

about what [Janet Yellen] considers appropriate–and inappropriate–relations between a Fed chair and government’s political officers.

And then having dropped that hint, Will pulls back.

Continue reading “The Role of a Central Bank and of a Central Banker: Cutting-Edge Economics from 188 Years Ago: Wednesday Focus”