Must-read: Barry Eichengreen: “The Case for a Grand Bargain”

Must-Read: Barry Eichengreen: The Case for a Grand Bargain: “What would it take for all this to happen?…

…First, there would have to be a reassertion of non-ideological economic common sense in U.S. and German policy making circles. One doesn’t have to be a Keynesian to believe that record low interest rates in both countries create a once-in-a-lifetime opportunity for infrastructure spending or to acknowledge that there are aspects of public infrastructure in both countries desperately in need of repair.

Second, central banks in countries lacking fiscal space would have to do more. This means not just talking down the exchange rate as a way of enhancing competitiveness but taking steps to encourage domestic spending, for example ramping up domestic [financial] security purchases still further, and ignoring domestic opposition.

Third, emerging markets and Southern European countries would have to make a credible commitment to structural reform. The need is there, quite independent of international coordination. But without this commitment, international coordination is off the table.

Skeptics will say that I am a dreamer for imagining this grand bargain. But the alternative to this dream is an ongoing economic nightmare.

Must-read: Simon Wren-Lewis: “The Financial Crisis, Austerity and the Shift from the Centre”

Must-Read: Simon Wren-Lewis: The Financial Crisis, Austerity and the Shift from the Centre: “Think of two separate one dimensional continuums…

…one economic, with neoliberal at one end and statist at the other, and the other something like identity. Identity can take many forms. It can be national identity (nationalism at one end and internationalism at the other), or race, or religion, or culture, or class. Identity politics is stronger on the right…. For the political right identity in terms of class can work happily with neoliberalism, but identity in terms of the nation state, culture and perhaps race less so…. When neoliberalism is discredited, this potential contradiction on the right becomes more evident… [as] politicians on the right use identity politics to deflect attention from the consequences of neoliberalism…. Identity has always been strong on the right, so it is a little misleading to see it as only something that the right uses in an instrumental way….

None of this detracts from the basic point that Quiggin makes: the apparent drift from the political centre ground is a consequence, for both left and right, of the financial crisis…. One interesting question for me is how much the current situation has been magnified by austerity. If a larger fiscal stimulus had been put in place in 2009, and we had not shifted to austerity in 2010, would the political fragmentation we are now seeing have still occurred? If the answer is no, to what extent was austerity an inevitable political consequence of the financial crisis, or did it owe much more to opportunism by neoliberals on the right, using popular concern about the deficit as a means by which to achieve a smaller state? Why did we have austerity in this recession and not in earlier recessions? I think these are questions a lot more people on the right as well as the left should be asking.

Watching as the Federal Reserve juggles priceless eggs in variable gravity…

Is it necessary to say that we hold Ben Bernanke, Mervyn King, Mark Carney, Janet Yellen, Stan Fischer, Lael Brainard, and company to the highest of high standards–demand from them constant triple aerial somersaults on the trapeze–because we have the greatest respect for and confidence in them? It probably is…

Back in 1992 Larry Summers and I wrote that pushing the target inflation rate from 5% down to 2% was a very dubious and hazardous enterprise because the zero-lower bound was potentially a big deal: “The relaxation of monetary policy seen over the past three years in the United States would have been arithmetically impossible had inflation and nominal interest rates both been three percentage points lower in 1989. Thus a more vigorous policy of reducing inflation to zero in the mid-1980s might have led to a recent recession much more severe than we have in fact seen…”

This does seem, in retrospect, to have been quite possibly the smartest and most foresightful thing I have ever written. Future historians will, I think, have a very difficult time explaining how the cult of 2%/year inflation targeting got itself established in the 1990s. And they will, I think, have an even harder time explaining why the first monetary policymaker reaction to 2008-2012 was not to endorse Olivier Blanchard et al.’s call for a higher, 4%/year, inflation target in the coded terms of IMF speak:

The great moderation (Gali and Gambetti 2009) lulled macroeconomists and policymakers alike in the belief that we knew how to conduct macroeconomic policy. The crisis clearly forces us to question that assessment….

The crisis has shown that large adverse shocks do happen. Should policymakers aim for a higher target inflation rate in normal times, in order to increase the room for monetary policy to react to such shocks? Are the net costs of inflation much higher at, say, 4% than at 2%, the current target range? Is it more difficult to anchor expectations at 4% than at 2%? Achieving low inflation through central bank independence has been a historic accomplishment. Thus, answering these questions implies carefully revisiting the benefits and costs of inflation.

A related question is whether, when the inflation rate becomes very low, policymakers should err on the side of a more lax monetary policy, so as to minimize the likelihood of deflation, even if this means incurring the risk of higher inflation in the event of an unexpectedly strong pickup in demand. This issue, which was on the mind of the Fed in the early 2000s, is one we must return to…

But instead we got a very different reaction. Sudeep Reddy reported on it back in 2009:

Sudeep Reddy (2009): Sen. Vitter Presents End-of-Term Exam For Bernanke: “Earlier this month, Real Time Economics presented questions from several economists…

…for the confirmation hearing of Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke…. Sen. David Vitter (R., La.) submitted them in writing and received the responses from Bernanke….

D. Brad Delong, University of California at Berkeley and blogger: Why haven’t you adopted a 3% per year inflation target?

[Bernanke:] The public’s understanding of the Federal Reserve’s commitment to price stability helps to anchor inflation expectations and enhances the effectiveness of monetary policy, thereby contributing to stability in both prices and economic activity. Indeed, the longer-run inflation expectations of households and businesses have remained very stable over recent years. The Federal Reserve has not followed the suggestion of some that it pursue a monetary policy strategy aimed at pushing up longer-run inflation expectations.

In theory, such an approach could reduce real interest rates and so stimulate spending and output. However, that theoretical argument ignores the risk that such a policy could cause the public to lose confidence in the central bank’s willingness to resist further upward shifts in inflation, and so undermine the effectiveness of monetary policy going forward.

The anchoring of inflation expectations is a hard-won success that has been achieved over the course of three decades, and this stability cannot be taken for granted. Therefore, the Federal Reserve’s policy actions as well as its communications have been aimed at keeping inflation expectations firmly anchored.

This sounds like nothing so much as the explanations offered in the 1920s and 1930s for returning to and sticking with the gold standard at pre-WWI parities, and the explanations offered at the start of the 1990s by British Tories for sticking to the fixed parities of the then-Exchange Rate Mechanism. The short answer is that real useful positive credibility is not built by attempts to stick to policies that are in the long run destructive–and hence both incredible and stupid. As we learn more about the economy and as the structure of the economy changes, the optimal long-run policy strategy changes as well. Credibility arising from a commitment that the Federal Reserve will seek to follow an optimal long-run policy framework and to accurately convey its intentions but will revise that framework in light of knowledge and events is worth gaining and maintaining. Credibility arising from a commitment to stick, come hell or high water, to a number that Alan Greenspan essentially pulled out of the air with next to no substantive analytical backing in terms of optimal-control analysis is not.

Now, however, we have another answer from Janet Yellen: that the zero lower bound is not, in fact, such a big deal:

Janet Yellen: The Outlook, Uncertainty, and Monetary Policy: “One must be careful, however, not to overstate the asymmetries affecting monetary policy at the moment…

…Even if the federal funds rate were to return to near zero, the FOMC would still have considerable scope to provide additional accommodation. In particular, we could use the approaches that we and other central banks successfully employed in the wake of the financial crisis to put additional downward pressure on long-term interest rates and so support the economy–specifically, forward guidance about the future path of the federal funds rate and increases in the size or duration of our holdings of long-term securities.10 While these tools may entail some risks and costs that do not apply to the federal funds rate, we used them effectively to strengthen the recovery from the Great Recession, and we would do so again if needed.

Over on the Twitter Machine, the very-sharp Tim Duy–I take it from his picture that there is ample snowpack for the ski resorts in the Cascade Range–is impressed by how different the tone of this speech is with the get-ready-for-liftoff speeches of last fall:

And Dario Perkins and Mark Grady have chimed in in support: “suddenly she’s realised the rest of the world matters!…” and “lots of common messages, but emphasis v[ery] diff[erent] on the risks. And no mention of lags or falling behind the curve at all…”

I, by contrast, am still struck by the gap that remains between where she seems to be and where I am.

For there is a natural next set of questions to ask anyone who says that the zero lower bound and the liquidity trap are not big deals. That set is:

  • Then why isn’t nominal GDP on its pre-2008 trend growth path?

  • Why is the five-year ahead five-year market inflation outlook so pessimistic?

  • Why hasn’t the Federal Reserve pushed interest rates low enough so that investment as a whole counterbalances the collapse in government purchases we have seen since 2010?

Gross Domestic Product FRED St Louis Fed Graph 5 Year 5 Year Forward Inflation Expectation Rate FRED St Louis Fed FRED Graph FRED St Louis Fed

I cannot help but be struck by the difference between what I see as the attitude of the current Federal Reserve, anxious not to do anything to endanger its “credibility”, and the Greenspan Fed of the late 1990s, which assumed that it had credibility and that because it had credibility it was free to experiment with policies that seemed likely to be optimal in the moment precisely because markets understood its long-term objective function and trusted it, and hence would not take short-run policy moves as indicative of long-run policy instability. There is a sense in which credibility is like a gold reserve: It is there to be drawn on and used in emergencies. The gold standard collapsed into the Great Depression in the 1930s in large part because both the Bank of France and the Federal Reserve believed that their gold reserves should never decline, but always either stay stable of increase.

It was Mark Twain who said that although history does not repeat itself, it does rhyme. The extent to which this is true was brought home to me recently by Barry Eichengreen’s excellent Hall of Mirrors

I tell you, I have a brand new set of lectures to write for a large monetary-policy module in American Economic History…

Must-read: Janet Yellen: “The Outlook, Uncertainty, and Monetary Policy”

Must-Read: Back in 1992 Larry Summers and I wrote that pushing the target inflation rate from 5% down to 2% was a very dubious and hazardous enterprise because the zero-lower bound was potentially a big deal: “The relaxation of monetary policy seen over the past three years in the United States would have been arithmetically impossible had inflation and nominal interest rates both been three percentage points lower in 1989. Thus a more vigorous policy of reducing inflation to zero in the mid-1980s might have led to a recent recession much more severe than we have in fact seen…”

Now we have an answer from Janet Yellen: that the zero lower bound is not, in fact, such a big deal:

Janet Yellen: The Outlook, Uncertainty, and Monetary Policy: “One must be careful, however, not to overstate the asymmetries affecting monetary policy at the moment…

…Even if the federal funds rate were to return to near zero, the FOMC would still have considerable scope to provide additional accommodation. In particular, we could use the approaches that we and other central banks successfully employed in the wake of the financial crisis to put additional downward pressure on long-term interest rates and so support the economy–specifically, forward guidance about the future path of the federal funds rate and increases in the size or duration of our holdings of long-term securities.10 While these tools may entail some risks and costs that do not apply to the federal funds rate, we used them effectively to strengthen the recovery from the Great Recession, and we would do so again if needed.

The natural next question to ask then is: Then why isn’t nominal GDP on its pre-2008 trend growth path? Why is the five-year ahead five-year market inflation outlook so pessimistic? Why hasn’t the Federal Reserve pushed interest rates low enough so that investment as a whole counterbalances the collapse in government purchases we have seen since 2010?

Gross Domestic Product FRED St Louis Fed Graph 5 Year 5 Year Forward Inflation Expectation Rate FRED St Louis Fed FRED Graph FRED St Louis Fed

Must-Read: Matthew Yglesias: “Brian D. McKenzie’s ‘Political Perceptions in the Obama Era

Must-Read: Racial animosity, myths of betrayal, and fear of poverty and economic insecurity all combined together in a cocktail–but at least it’s an ethos!

Matthew Yglesias: “Brian D. McKenzie’s ‘Political Perceptions in the Obama Era: Diverse Opinions of the Great Recession and its Aftermath among Whites, Latinos and Blacks’…

…The Kaiser Family Foundation and the Washington Post working with some scholars from Harvard to look at race and the recession… included one question asking whether Obama has done ‘too much’ in terms of ‘ looking out for the economic interests of African Americans’ and another one asking which racial groups had been hardest hit by the recession. The results….

Numerous whites overlook the economic evidence that blacks were substantially harmed on multiple fronts during the recession and instead believe this group was unfairly aided by a sitting black president. These perceptual biases shape whites’ political opinions and are associated with feelings of financial frustration and higher levels of blame toward the government…. Interestingly, while many whites believe that African Americans are the beneficiaries of favorable economic policies from the Obama administration, blacks themselves do not feel they have been uniquely assisted financially (Harris 2012; Harris and Lieberman 2013).

This ties together white nationalist themes, economic anxiety themes, and populist anti-establishment themes nicely–a large bloc of white voters believes they are suffering economically because their elected representatives in Washington betrayed their interests in order to help nonwhites….

Following Mitt Romney’s defeat in 2012, the leadership of the Republican Party decided that they wanted to go in the exact opposite direction… the GOP would present itself as a modern, cosmopolitan, forward-thinking vehicle for right-of-center economic policy. Conservatism would be an ideology for everyone, not just for white people terrified that all their money was going to be spent on Obamaphones and hip-hop barbecues…. This sent… the wrong message to an important element of the GOP base… that their own party’s leaders were planning to betray them….

Resentful white people perceive themselves to be in a zero-sum clash for resources and opportunities with African Americans and Latinos, and want candidates who will champion their interests rather than throw them overboard in pursuit of a broader electoral coalition.

Must-read: Wolfgang Munchau: “The Errors Behind Europe’s Many Crises”

Must-Read: Wolfgang Munchau: The Errors Behind Europe’s Many Crises: “The EU was wrong to construct a single currency without a proper banking union…

…wrong to create a passport-free travel zone without a common border police force and immigration policy. [And] I would add EU enlargement… the haste with which it was pursued. The cardinal mistake of our time was the decision to muddle through the eurozone crisis. Europe’s political leadership failed to generate the public support for what was needed: creating a political and economic union. Instead, the European Council did the minimum necessary…. There are four channels through which that policy contributed to the broader instability….

First… the EU has the capacity only to deal with one big crisis at a time…. Second… the conflation, real or imaginary, of two more crises. The Greek economy continues to contract… refugees have been trapped in Greece… since Macedonia closed the border…. There are the fake connections. Poland has used last week’s Brussels bombings as a pretext for questioning a commitment to accept 7,000 refugees… an interaction between the terrorist attacks and the prospect of British exit…. Third… the output of several eurozone countries has yet to return to pre-crisis levels. Security… was among the areas most affected by austerity…. The widening income gap between rich and poor — and north and south….

Fourth… a generalised loss of trust and political capital…. Populist parties on the left and the right are exploiting the union’s failures…. The combination of these four channels frustrates perfectly good ideas for further projects aimed at European integration–those that would benefit everybody, such as central agencies to co-ordinate the fight against terrorism and to deal with the influx of refugees. If the EU had not messed up the previous crises, people would look at a European immigration policy or an antiterrorism task force with a more open mind. But would you trust with your own security somebody who cannot even contain a medium-sized financial crisis?…

Economic history has shown… that efforts to muddle through financial crises never work…. For the EU it was a catastrophic policy error… an economic depression… destroyed public confidence in the EU and in the very idea of European integration.

Must-read: Ed Balls: “Echoes of the 1930s must focus finance ministers’ minds”

Must-Read: Ed Balls: Echoes of the 1930s must focus finance ministers’ minds: “The lesson of the global financial crisis of 2009 is that…

…when the G20 gets going, it can act in a decisive and co-ordinated way. However, we should not have to wait for the crisis to hit before our financial leaders take the action needed to deal with it…. One problem is focus. Back in 2009, the whole world was alive to the risk of global depression. Not so today. Europe is focused on Brexit and the refugee crisis; America is in pre-election paralysis; meanwhile Asian countries are trying to convince everyone there is no need for panic…. Stagnating growth, fragile investor confidence, fears of competitive devaluation spreading mistrust, isolationist politicians flourishing in the polls–the echoes of the 1930s should be enough to focus minds on making the case for co-operation, open markets and finding new policies to deliver more inclusive economic growth…. Listen to the OECD and IMF on fiscal activism. Countries with room for manoeuvre should boost growth through infrastructure spending. That includes the US, Germany and, yes, Britain too. Medium-term fiscal consolidation is vital. But a slide in growth will make things worse. And the cost of funding these investments is very low.

Must-read: Wolfgang Munchau: “European Central Bank Must Be Much Bolder”

Must-Read: Wolfgang Munchau: European Central Bank Must Be Much Bolder: “The European Central Bank’s monetary policy has been off-track for a very long time…

…And lately, the [core inflation] rate has fallen again. Is there something the ECB can do?… The ECB should hold an open debate about policy alternatives, starting with a realisation that quantitative easing has failed. The ECB acted late, and did not do enough…. The programmes in the US and the UK started when market interest rates were higher than today. The European programme came when rates were already low…. The policy alternatives… [are] a ‘helicopter drop’…. The ECB would print and distribute money to citizens directly. If it were to distribute, say, €3,000bn or about €10,000 per citizen over five years, that would take care of the inflation problem nicely. It would provide an immediate demand boost, and drive up investment as suppliers expanded their capacity to meet this extra demand. The policy would bypass governments and the financial sector. The financial markets would hate it. There is nothing in it for them. But who cares?…

Must-read: Danny Yagan: “The Enduring Employment Impact of Your Great Recession”

Must-Read: Danny Yagan: The Enduring Employment Impact of Your Great Recession: “In the cross section, employment rates diverged across U.S. local areas 2007-2009…

…and–in contrast to history–have barely converged [since]…. I… use administrative data to compare two million workers with very similar pre-2007 human capital: those who in 2006 earned the same amount from the same retail firm, at establishments located in different local areas. I find that, conditional on 2006 firm-x-wages fixed effects, living in 2007 in a below-median 2007-2009-fluctuation area caused those workers to have a 1.3%-lower 2014 employment rate…. Location has affected long-term employment and exacerbated within-skill income inequality. The enduring employment impact is not explained by more layoffs, more disability insurance enrollment, or reduced migration. Instead, the employment outcomes of cross-area movers are consistent with severe-fluctuation areas continuing to depress their residents’ employment. Impacts are correlated with housing busts but not manufacturing busts, possibly reconciling current experience with history. If recent trends continue, employment rates are estimated to converge in the 2020s–adding up to a relative lost decade for half the country.