Must-read: Tamim Bayoumi and Joseph E. Gagnon: “Time to Be Bold, Mr. Kuroda”

Must-Read: Tamim Bayoumi and Joseph E. Gagnon: Time to Be Bold, Mr. Kuroda: “The surprise decision by the Bank of Japan (BOJ) last Thursday to leave policies essentially unchanged…

…while downgrading the growth and inflation forecasts has unnerved markets…. Markets needed a surprise, but this one was in the wrong direction. What is required is a bold initiative rather than renewed paralysis…. Strong, decisive policy action is needed—and soon—to convince markets the BOJ is still determined to achieve 2 percent inflation. With 10-year government bond yields now below zero, the most effective option is to ramp up purchases of other assets. Currently, the BOJ is buying about 0.5 percent of outstanding equities per year. Raising the rate of purchase to 10 percent would herald a major break with the past, pushing up equity prices and encouraging consumption and investment through higher household wealth and lower cost of capital.

Must-read: Michael Heise: “The Case Against Helicopter Money”

Must-Read: Michael Heise does not seem to understand that central banks’ comprehensive assets include the ability to tax banks by raising reserve requirements:

Michael Heise: The Case Against Helicopter Money: “Helicopter drops would arrive in the form of lump-sum payments to households or consumption vouchers for everybody, funded exclusively by central banks…

…This… would reduce the central bank’s equity capital…. Proponents defend this approach by claiming that central banks are subject to special accounting rules that could be adjusted as needed…. Proponents… today include… Ben Bernanke and Adair Turner….

Distributing largesse… would have dangerous systemic consequences…. Policymakers would be tempted to… [avoid] difficult structural reforms… [and] would raise expectations… that central banks and governments would always step in to smooth out credit bubbles and mitigate their consequences…. Add to that the impact of the depletion of valuation reserves and the risk of negative equity–developments that could undermine the credibility of central banks and thus of currencies–and it seems clear that helicopter drops should, at least for now, remain firmly in the realm of academic debate.

Live at Project Syndicate: “Rescue Helicopters for Stranded Economies”

Live at Project Syndicate: Rescue Helicopters for Stranded Economies: BERKELEY – For countries where nominal interest rates are at or near zero, fiscal stimulus should be a no-brainer…. Some point to the risk that, once the economy recovers and interest rates rise, governments will fail to make the appropriate adjustments to fiscal policy. But… governments that wish to pursue bad policies will do so no matter what decisions are made today…. Aversion to fiscal expansion reflects raw ideology, not pragmatic considerations…. This debate is no longer an intellectual discussion–if it ever was. As a result, a flanking move might be required. It is time for central banks to assume responsibility and implement ‘helicopter money’… **Read MOAR at Project Syndicate

Must-read: David Glasner: “What’s Wrong with Monetarism?”

Must-Read: An excellent read from the very sharp David Glasner. I, however, disagree with the conclusion: the standard reaction of most economists to empirical failure is to save the phenomena and add another epicycle. Why not do that in this case too? Why not, as someone claimed to me that John Taylor once said, stabilize nominal GDP by passing a law mandating the Federal Reserve keep velocity-adjusted money growing at a constant rate?

David Glasner: What’s Wrong with Monetarism?: “DeLong balanced his enthusiasm for Friedman with a bow toward Keynes…

…noting the influence of Keynes on both classic and political monetarism, arguing that, unlike earlier adherents of the quantity theory, Friedman believed that a passive monetary policy was not the appropriate policy stance during the Great Depression; Friedman famously held the Fed responsible for the depth and duration of what he called the Great Contraction… in sharp contrast to hard-core laissez-faire opponents of Fed policy, who regarded even the mild and largely ineffectual steps taken by the Fed… as illegitimate interventionism to obstruct the salutary liquidation of bad investments, thereby postponing the necessary reallocation of real resources to more valuable uses…. But both agreed that there was no structural reason why stimulus would necessarily counterproductive; both rejected the idea that only if the increased output generated during the recovery was of a particular composition would recovery be sustainable. Indeed, that’s why Friedman has always been regarded with suspicion by laissez-faire dogmatists who correctly judged him to be soft in his criticism of Keynesian doctrines….

Friedman parried such attacks… [saying that] the point of a gold standard… was that it makes it costly to increase the quantity of money. That might once have been true, but advances in banking technology eventually made it easy for banks to increase the quantity of money without any increase in the quantity of gold… True, eventuaally the inflation would have to be reversed to maintain the gold standard, but that simply made alternative periods of boom and bust inevitable…. If the point of a gold standard is to prevent the quantity of money from growing excessively, then, why not just eliminate the middleman, and simply establish a monetary rule constraining the growth in the quantity of money? That was why Friedman believed that his k-percent rule… trumped the gold standard….

For at least a decade and a half after his refutation of the structural Phillips Curve, demonstrating its dangers as a guide to policy making, Friedman continued treating the money multiplier as if it were a deep structural variable, leading to the Monetarist forecasting debacle of the 1980s…. So once the k-percent rule collapsed under an avalanche of contradictory evidence, the Monetarist alternative to the gold standard that Friedman had persuasively, though fallaciously, argued was, on strictly libertarian grounds, preferable to the gold standard, the gold standard once again became the default position of laissez faire dogmatists…. So while I agree with DeLong and Krugman (and for that matter with his many laissez-faire dogmatist critics) that Friedman had Keynesian inclinations which, depending on his audience, he sometimes emphasized, and sometimes suppressed, the most important reason that he was unable to retain his hold on right-wing monetary-economics thinking is that his key monetary-policy proposal–the k-percent rule–was empirically demolished in a failure even more embarrassing than the stagflation failure of Keynesian economics. With the k-percent rule no longer available as an alternative, what’s a right-wing ideologue to do? Anyone for nominal gross domestic product level targeting (or NGDPLT for short)?

Memo to self: Monetary policy since 1985

FRED Graph FRED St Louis Fed

Major Federal Reserve Policy Moves since 1985:

The Federal Reserve overshoots and overtightens. But the effect on the economy is diminished because more-responsible fiscal policy leads to a fall in the term and risk premiums:

Preview of Pounding Nails in Nevada

The Federal Reserve eases monetary policy to fight the recession and jobless recovery caused by its previous overshoot:

Preview of Pounding Nails in Nevada

The Federal Reserve tightens to–successfully–try to keep inflation from rising; the first bond market “conundrum” as the endogenous duration of mortgage-backed securities produces a much tighter-than-expected gearing between the short-term safe nominal interest rate i and the long-term risky real interest rate r:

Preview of Pounding Nails in Nevada

The Federal Reserve loosens during the international financial crisis of 1998:

Preview of Pounding Nails in Nevada

The Federal Reserve tightens to try to prevent “overheating” in the late stages of the dot-com boom:

Preview of Pounding Nails in Nevada

The Federal Reserve loosens to fight the recession brought on by the collapse of the dot-com boom:

Preview of Pounding Nails in Nevada

The Federal Reserve keeps policy stimulative and delays its interest-rate tightening cycle given the weakness of the recovery; the bond market first does not and then does credit the Federal Reserve’s statements:

Preview of Pounding Nails in Nevada

The Federal Reserve eases as the magnitude of the subprime-driven financial crisis becomes apparent; but the collapse in financial market trust and the financial crisis come anyway:

Preview of Pounding Nails in Nevada

With the recovery inadequate, the Federal Reserve decides to extend the period of emergency stimulative extraordinary monetary policy–but the long-term risky real interest rate r sticks at 3%, and does not go any lower:

Preview of Pounding Nails in Nevada

With the unemployment rate now in the range associated with full employment, the Federal Reserve decides that it is time to “normalize” interest rates:

Preview of Pounding Nails in Nevada

Inflation Control:

The Federal Reserve has overdone it on inflation control–successfully kept inflation from getting “too high”, and in fact pushed inflation “too low”:

Graph Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers All Items Less Food and Energy FRED St Louis Fed

Full Employment:

Before 2008, macroeconomic stabilization performance on full employment was quite good. 2008-2010 was a disaster. How we evaluate what follows depends on whether we look at unemployment or employment:

Graph Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers All Items Less Food and Energy FRED St Louis Fed Graph Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers All Items Less Food and Energy FRED St Louis Fed

Structural Adjustment: “Pounding Nails in Nevada…”

Was a recession in 2009 any sense “needed” to move people out of construction employment as the housing boom collapsed? Was a rise in unemployment a necessary first step in rebalancing the late-2000s economy?

No: Look at the key components of aggregate demand:

FRED Graph FRED St Louis Fed

As of November 2008, when John Cochrane gave his “we should have a recession… people who spend their lives pounding nails in Nevada need something else to do…” keynote address to the 2008 CRSP Forum, residential investment had already fallen by 3.5%-points of GDP and was within 0.5%-points of what had been its nadir. The recession came after the move of labor out of construction had been all but completely finished:

FRED Graph FRED St Louis Fed

*If you were going to say “we should have a recession” on the grounds that a recession was a necessary part of the structural adjustment required to climb down from overinvetment in housing, the moment to have said that was 2005. And those who said that then were wrong: we did not read a recession in order to move those “pounding nails in Nevada” into other sectors while keeping them employed…

Regress in macroeconomic knowledge over the past 83 years

Today, in 2016, Raghu Rajan thinks helicopter drops are “a step too far into the dark…”

His predecessor 83 years ago at the University of Chicago, Jacob Viner, thought they were one of the obvious technocratic steps to take, along with further raising the monetary base (i.e., in his day going off of the gold standard) even with short-term safe nominal interest rates at the zero lower bound (as they also were in his day).

Here’s Raghu:

Raghuram Rajan 2016): “If you read the writings of economists…

…it is not clear what’s keeping us still so slow, seven or eight years after the crisis. Ken Rogoff would say it is still the debt overhang and the deleveraging. [Robert] Gordon and others might say it is low productivity and still others may say it is the poorly understood consequences of population aging. But what do we do? And here I think there is more of a consensus that monetary policy pretty much has run its course. There are still guys who are looking for helicopter drops of money but I think that is a step sort of too far into the dark, where I am not sure there is a political consensus to do that in the major economies, if it comes to that…

Here’s Jacob:

Jacob Viner (1933): Balanced Deflation, Inflation, or More Deflation: “If going off the gold standard were as simple a matter for us…

…as for England and Canada, I would not only advocate it, but if [it]… did not suffice to lower substantially the internal purchasing power of the dollar I would recommend its accompaniment by increased government expenditures financed by the printing press or by loans…. England and… the other countries which went off the gold standard in 1931… [made] too restrained use of the freedom which the departure from the gold standard gave them them…. The countries that went off the gold standard have nevertheless weathered the economic storm much better…

We all agree that economies today are “so slow” and inflation pressures are by and large absent. What does Raghu think he knows today that Jacob did not–what have we learned in the past 83 years–that has turned helicopter drops from an obvious technocratic step to take to “a step too far into the dark”? What did Jacob think he knew that Raghu does not–what doctrines, true, false, or uncertain–because we have forgotten them?

Anyone? Anyone? Bueller?

Must-read: Olivier Blanchard: The US Phillips Curve: Back to the 60s?

Must-Read: Olivier Blanchard says that he and Paul Krugman differ not at all on the analytics but, rather, substantially on “tone”…

It looks as though the center of the Federal Reserve is working today as if the slope of the Phillips-Curve relationship is still what it was in the years around 1980, and that the gearing of expected inflation to recent-past inflation is still what it was in the years around 1980.

Why this is so is a mystery.

Olivier Blanchard: The US Phillips Curve: Back to the 60s?: “The US Phillips curve is alive…

…(I wish I could say “alive and well,” but it would be an overstatement: the relation has never been very tight.) Inflation expectations, however, have become steadily more anchored, leading to a relation between the unemployment rate and the level… rather than the change in in inflation… [that] resembles more the Phillips curve of the 1960s than the accelerationist Phillips curve of the later period. The slope of the Phillips curve… has substantially declined…. The standard error of the residual… is large…. Each of the last three conclusions presents challenges for the conduct of monetary policy…

Www piie com publications pb pb16 1 pdf Www piie com publications pb pb16 1 pdf Www piie com publications pb pb16 1 pdf

We Are so S—ed. Econ 1-Level Edition

As I told my undergraduates yesterday:

Y = μ[co + Io + NX] + μG – μIrr

where:

  • Y is real GDP
  • μ = 1/(1-cy) is the Keynesian multiplier
  • co is consumer confidence
  • cy is the marginal propensity to consume
  • C = co + cyY is the consumption function–how households’ spending on consumption goods and services varies with consumer confidence, with their income which is equal to real GDP Y, and with the marginal propensity to consume
  • Io is businesses’ and banks’ “animal spirits”–their confidence in enterprise
  • r is “the” long-term risky real interest rate r
  • Ir is the sensitivity of business investment to r
  • NX is foreigners’ net demand for our exports
  • And G is government purchases.

And as I am going to tell them next Monday, real GDP Y will be equal to potential output Y* whenever “the” interest rate r is equal to the Wicksellian neutral rate r*, which by simple algebra is:

r* = [co + Io + NX]/Ir + G/Ir – Y*/μIr

If interest rates are low and inflation is not rising it is not because monetary policy is too easy, but because r* is low–and r* can be low because:

  • consumers are terrified (co low)
  • investors’ animal spirits are depressed (Io low)
  • foreigners’ demand for our exports inadequate (NX low)
  • or fiscal policy too contractionary (G low)

for the economy’s productive potential Y*.

The central bank’s task in the long run is to try to do what it can to stabilize psychology and so reduce fluctuations in r. the central bank’s task in the short run is to adjust the short-term safe nominal interest rate it controls i in such a way as to match the market rate of interest r to r. For only then will Say’s Law, false in theory, be true in practice:

Martin Wolf: Negative Rates Not Central Banks’ Fault: “It is hard to understand the obsession with limiting public debt when it is as cheap as it is today…

…Almost nine years after the west’s financial crisis started, interest rates remain ultra-low. Indeed, a quarter of the world economy now suffers negative interest rates. This condition is as worrying as the policies themselves are unpopular. Larry Fink, chief executive of BlackRock, the asset manager, argues that low rates prevent savers from getting the returns they need for retirement. As a result, they are forced to divert money from current spending into savings. Wolfgang Schäuble, Germany’s finance minister, has even put much of the blame for the rise of Alternative für Deutschland, a nationalist party, and on policies introduced by the European Central Bank. ‘Save the savers’ is an understandable complaint by an asset manager or finance minister of a creditor nation. But this does not mean the objection makes sense. The world economy is suffering from a glut of savings relative to investment opportunities. The monetary authorities are helping to ensure that interest rates are consistent with this fact….

The savings glut (or investment dearth, if one prefers) is the result of developments both before and after the crisis…. Some will object that the decline in real interest rates is solely the result of monetary policy, not real forces. This is wrong. Monetary policy does indeed determine short-term nominal rates and influences longer-term ones. But the objective of price stability means that policy is aimed at balancing aggregate demand with potential supply. The central banks have merely discovered that ultra-low rates are needed to achieve this objective…. We must regard ultra-low rates as symptoms of our disease, not its cause….

[But is] the monetary treatment employed… the best one[?]…. Given the nature of banking institutions, negative rates are unlikely to be passed on to depositors and… so are likely to damage the banks…. There is a limit to how negative rates can go without limiting the convertibility of deposits into cash…. And this policy might do more damage than good. Even supporters agree there are limits…. [Does] this mean monetary policy is exhausted? Not at all. Monetary policy’s ability to raise inflation is essentially unlimited. The danger is rather that calibrating monetary policy is more difficult the more extreme it becomes. For this reason, fiscal policy should have come into play more aggressively….

The best policies would be a combination of raising potential supply and sustaining aggregate demand. Important elements would be structural reforms and aggressive monetary and fiscal expansion…. Monetary policy cannot be for the benefit of creditors alone. A policy that stabilises the eurozone must help the debtors, too. Furthermore, the overreliance on monetary policy is a result of choices, particularly over fiscal policy, on which Germany has strongly insisted. It is also the result of excess savings, to which Germany has substantially contributed…

One way of looking at it is that two things went wrong in 2008-9:

  • Asset prices collapsed.
  • And so spending collapsed and unemployment rose.

The collapse in asset prices impoverished the plutocracy. The collapse in spending and the rise in unemployment impoverished the working class. Central banks responded by reducing interest rates. That restored asset prices, so making the plutocracy whole. But while that helped, that did not do enough to restore the working class.

Then the plutocracy had a complaint: although their asset values and their wealth had been restored, the return on their assets and so their incomes had not be. And so they called for austerity: cut government spending so that governments can then cut our taxes and so restore our incomes as well as our wealth.

But, of course, cutting government spending further impoverished the working class, and put still more downward pressure on the Wicksellian neutral interest rate r* consistent with full employment and potential output.

And here we sit.

Must-read: Duncan Black: “Time to Increase Interest Rates!”

Must-Read: And Duncan Black comes up with a very good phrase to describe what we think the Federal Reserve is doing based on what we think is its misspecified and erroneous view of the inflation process: “taking away the punchbowl before the DJ even shows up to the party”:

Duncan Black: Time To Increase Interest Rates!: “As I’ve said, I don’t think small upticks in interest rates by the Fed…

…will really destroy the economy. They just signal that the Fed will never let wages (for most of us) rise ever again. They’re taking away the punchbowl before the DJ even shows up to the party. Killing inflation is easy and you don’t have to pre-kill it. The best argument for Fed actions is that they need to increase rates so that they’ll be able to decrease them again if the economy sours. There’s a bit of an obvious problem with this reasoning. Exciting days at the dog track probably do get their attention. Wonder why that is.

Must-watch: Joe Gagnon et al.: Event: “Macroeconomic Policy Options for the World Today”

Must-Watch: Joe Gagnon et al.: Event: Macroeconomic Policy Options for the World Today: “Joseph E. Gagnon… Jay Shambaugh… Patrick Honohan… Carlo Cottarelli…

…The Peterson Institute will hold an event on April 12, 2016, to discuss the capacity and prospects for macroeconomic stimulus ahead of the spring meetings of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank… possible monetary policy options for major central banks… the Obama administration’s perspective on the fiscal space globally and potential stimulus policies…