The Rebalancing Challenge in Europe Today: The Honest Broker for the Week of February 1, 2015

NewImage

The Rebalancing Challenge###

J. Bradford DeLong :: U.C. Berkeley

OëNB Conference on European Economic Integration :: Vienna :: November 24-25, 2014

https://www.icloud.com/pages/AwBUCAESEHBN_GdfxLmukcgoyRX8ocAaKQdtWwIUBlPWhv0VX8vnODUjfjWOIbeFuUiF3QHyfCeMY9RUd2SgjBXFMCUCAQEEIKm3f8UIYBcEElisfxX1c6APGaWyaYQnStJfTZ2VtGVZ#2015-01-28b–DeLong_Rebalancing_Challenge_in_Europe.pages

There is an important purpose of an opening keynote talk like this one. Its task is to start from first principles and then give a large-scale bird’s-eye overview to what is to come. We have panels to come on monetary policy, balance-sheet adjustment and growth, inequality and its role in generating internal macroeconomic imbalances, external macroeconomic rebalancing, and banking sector regulation. They all presuppose that Europe, and within it the regions of Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe that we focus on here, need not just higher aggregate demand in the short-term but more. They need large-scale sectoral rebalancing. And that sectoral rebalancing needs to be rapid. Why? Because these economies will not grow smoothly without deep structural reforms–in these reforms need to be not just at the bottom but at the top, reforms of institutions, governance structures, and regulatory practices and mandates need to be carried out as well.

NewImageNote that the need, while urgent in Central Europe, Eastern Europe, and Southeastern Europe, is not by any means more urgent here then in the other regions of Europe.

So why is more than higher aggregate demand right now what is needed? And which of the many things that go under the labels of “rebalancing” and “structural adjustment” are most needed? And why?

If in the next half-hour I can answer these questions convincingly then there will be an intellectual framework into which the rest of the conference’s pieces will fit naturally, and we will all go back to our day jobs with a firmer grasp of the rebalancing challenge in Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe.

Thus let me try to place the rest of today in its proper perspectives.

NewImage

The first perspective to take is the very long-run perspective.

Let me note three dates: September 12, 1683; June 18, 1815; and November 19, 1942.

September 12, 1683 was, of course, the end of the Turkish imperial project. It was the date of the last truly mass slaughter right here. On that day the defending armies commanded by Ernst Rüdiger von Starhemberg, reinforced by the relieving forces of King John III Sobieski of Poland, defeated and forced the retreat down the Danube Valley of the armies commanded by Grand Vizier Merzifonlu Kara Mustafa Pasha.1 That was the last time that this segment, at least, of the Danube Valley saw the chaos, destruction, and death of large-scale long-lasting war. If von Starhemberg and Mustafa Pasha could see Southeastern Europe now, while they might mourn the loss of power of the dynasties they served, they would both be very pleased at the state of the people who live her–and both be very grateful that the peoples and states are, for the most part, not still locked in what looked then like an eternal region-encompassing destructive war of intolerant, militant faiths.

June 18, 1815 was, of course, the end of the French revolutonary-imperial project with the final defeat at Waterloo in Belgium of the army of the French Emperor Napoleon I Bonaparte by British, Dutch, and German forces under the command of the Irish-born Arthur Wellesley, Duke of Wellington. We all do owe a great deal to the implementation and then transmission of the good ideals of the Enlightenment by the French Revolution. We owe less than zero to the habit of deadly ideological purges introduced by the Convention in Paris and in the Vendee. And the practice of introducing and maintaining those ideals by every four years having a French army come through, burning as it went and living off the land, leaving famine in its wake, is something we can live without.2 If either Metternich or Talleyrand could see right now that we are now longer engaged in the military destruction of the struggle for French dominance over Europe that consumed the sixteenth, seventeenth, and eighteenth centuries and that seemed to them to be perpetual, they would be pleased.

And November 19, 1942 was, of course, the end of the Nazi imperial project with the initial breakthrough of the Soviet Union’s Red Army at Stalingrad on the Volga.3 It was followed by two-and-a-half more years of fire, blood, and death, and then a process of reconstruction that hang in the balance in Western Europe for a decade and is still not complete in Eastern Europe. Nevertheless, if those whose job it was to start rebuilding in 1945, if the Adenauers and de Gaulles could see us now, they would be very pleased. Right now the European project is a success. And we could not have said that on September 12, 1683; on June 18, 1815; or on November 19, 1942.

In fact, we can take a much longer perspective in which the post-World War II project of European community, unification, and peace has been a success. It was not far from here that the tribes of the Kimbri and the Teutones who had left their previous homes somewhere in or near Jutland crossed the Danube River into Noricum in 113 BC.

Was it 111 BC that the Kimbri and the Teutones, having moved down from Jutland to what is now Austria and crossed the Danube, decided they would rather cross the Rhine into the land of feta and olives in the Rhone Valley rather than eat Sauerkraut and sausage–or, back then, probably auroch jerky–in Noricum, near what is now Salzburg? So they went. And so they looted, burned, ravaged, killed, and ruled until a decade later they were broken at the battles of Aquae Sextiae and Vercellae by the new-model Roman Republican army commanded by Gaius Marius C. f. seven times consul.4 Ever since then, by my count, it is every thirty-seven years that a hostile army crosses the Rhine going one way or the other bringing fire and sword. The original Swiss–the Helvetii. Julius Caesar. All of those who claimed to be Julius Caesar’s adoptive descendants. The Visigoths heading for Andalusia. Louis XIV commanding his armies to make sure that nothing grows in the Rhinish Palatinate so that his armies attacking Holland have a secure right flank. And, last, Remagen bridge in 1945. Every thirty-seven years, with increasing destructiveness as time passes.

NewImage

Thirty-seven years after 1945 carries us to 1982. Thirty-seven years after 1982 will carry us to 2019. By 2019 we will have missed two of our appointments with slaughter. Even with Stalin’s legacy, the difficulties of post-Cold War transition, everything that has happened in the republics of the Former Yugoslavia, and the current struggle over austerity and adjustment between the northern and southern pieces of the Eurozone, things have gone very well indeed recently.

Yet, I believe, most think that we desperately need political union in Europe as insurance to keep the bad old days from 111 BC to 1945 from coming again. We do not want Europe to once again fall victim to the tragedy of great power politics5. That means that politicians find some way to union–so that differences are thrashed out in conference rooms in Brussels and Strasbourg rather than in the streets with Molotov cocktails, submachine guns, armed drones, and worse. That is the necessity.

NewImage

This does not mean that we should minimize Europe’s current problems, just note that the problems are not as large as the achievements. The problems facing us are many. A very quick list consists of five. There are two major political problems:

  • Incorporating ex-superpowers into the common European home–a problem Europe has faced over and over again since 1600, first with Spain, then with France after 1815, then with Germany after 1870, and now with Great Russia.
  • Building institutions for continental governance in our late-Westphalian nationalist age.

And there are three major economic problems and opportunities:

  • Grasping rather than letting drop the enormous fruits of continent-scale economic integration that nearly all studies of economies of scale and economic integration say are there.
  • Accelerating the painfully and disappointingly slow convergence of both east and south to northwest European standards. Looking at the Asian Pacific Rim reveals that if we can get the institutions, the trade patterns, and integration more than half-right we can look forward to a régime of convergence in which living standards and productivity levels in a region converge halfway to the standards of that region’s core in a generation. We can do it. We have done it elsewhere in the past. We should be doing it now in Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe. And, frustratingly, we are not: it is more the slow-boring-of-hard-boards than it is the thirty-glorious-years.
  • Successfully resolving and recovering from the shock of 2008 and its aftereffects. This is, mostly, what concerns us today. The other four problems are, mostly, in the background right now.

And the need is to do all of this in a global context that is not terribly supportive.

NewImage

The global context of 2008 is a world that was characterized either by a global savings glut6 or a global investment shortfall, depending on which blade of the scissors is your favorite to focus on. That imbalance in turn produced either what one might call a global overleveraging: the gap between desired global savings at global full employment and planned global investment at global full employment was filled-in by credit creation to create funding for long-term investment projects that was not backed by savings commitments to long-run patient capital.7 One might, alternatively, call it a global shortage of risk tolerance: the gap between desired global savings at global full employment and planned global investment at global full employment was filled-in by promising savers that they were not bearing large amounts of systemic business-cycle risk when they in fact were.8 These are alternative ways of labeling the same underlying economic failure of expectations to be consistent that focus on somewhat different things–the apocryphal tale of the five wise men and the elephant comes to mind.9

We had a world in which there was no global hegemon, in a Keynes-Kindleberger sense, in Washington, willing to take responsibility for managing the level of global aggregate demand, even if the consequences for the domestic United States were potentially unfortunate.10 If in the 1950s and 1960s the U.S. under Bretton Woods had made a durable commitment to serve as the world’s importer of last resort, its falling into the same role during what some called Bretton Woods II was contingent and evanescent.11

Moreover, we had a world in which there was no alternative local continental-scale orchestra-conductor focused on balancing effective demand to potential supply over the European continent as a whole. Instead, there were many countries, some of them very large, most of them focused inward, none of them thinking that responsibility needed to be taken. That, it was thought, ws the business of the European Central Bank, which had the proper monetarist tools to do the job of managing continent-wide demand. But what if those tools proved insufficient? The ECB did not have the power, and nobody had the power to do banking regulatory or fiscal policy in Europe on the proper continent-wide scale.12

NewImage

Plus there was little sense in the years before 2008 of what a North Atlantic-wide Keynes-Kindleberger international economic hegemon would actually do. Such are used to dealing with problems of excessive aggregate demand, de-anchoring inflation expectations, and upward price spirals on the one hand; or with problems of liquidity shortage on the other. But we did not have a liquidity shortage–certainly not after the start of 2009. The monetarist playbook for how the Great Depression ought to have been handled was taken down from the shelf, dusted off, and applied.13 As a result the North Atlantic economy floated on an absolute sea of liquidity from the start of 2009 to the present day: so much has there been not-a-shortage-of-cash that central bank deposit velocity has fallen to low levels that I, at least, never thought I would ever see.

NewImage

We have, instead, since the middle of 2008 had another kind of deficiency in the macroeconomy: aggregate demand has fallen below potential supply because there has been an excess demand for and a shortage of safe assets in the North Atlantic economy. That has been a consequence of an excess of risky assets, of an excess of nonperforming loans, of the transformation of assets formerly seen as safe into risky status. These problems are more sophisticated and less tractable to monetary interventions. Open-market operations that simply swap one interest-paying, or potentially interest-paying government liability with duration for a non-interest paying government liability with zero duration have next to no effect on the supply-and-demand for safe assets as a class.14

If we view the big shock of 2008 as a collapse on the demand side of risk tolerance and on the supply side as the recognition that very large classes of assets sold as safe were in fact not safe, one driven by events in the United States, then we would think that this collapse is both good and bad. It is good in that savers are no longer easily fooled: people who are in fact bearing systemic business cycle and other forms of risk are now aware that they are doing so, and if full employment is reattained it will not be under the shadow of expectations that are inconsistent and cannot be fulfilled. Creditors will not let debtors borrow and borrow and borrow until not only their solvency but the creditors’ solvency is at risk as well. It is bad because attaining anything close to full employment in a capitalist market economy requires that savers bear risk. The provision of risk-bearing capacity is an important factor of production that only those who have current wealth–are savers–can provide. And right now they are not doing so on a sufficient scale.

I was told this morning (November 24, 2014) that the ten-year Spanish government-bond nominal interest rate is now less than 2%/year. Whatever we think of those of you and of our friends who invest in Spanish government bonds, 2%/year nominal for ten years in euros does seem a little low given the existence of a great deal of value in the world today in the form of potentially-storable commodities, and given the existence of political uncertainties–black swans–over the net decade that are not things we can today quantify or even imagine. Compare a sub-1%/year German 10-year nominal bond rate to the 6%/year real earnings yield on a diversified portfolio of equities of European non-financial operating companies. With a 2%/year inflation target, 6+2-1 = 7. 7%/year is a huge premium return to get on equity investments in a diversified portfolio of corporations rather than government bonds subject to inflation risk–especially when one reflects that this is not a duration risk, for dividends plus stock buybacks today make up a very healthy cash payout, and the covariance of interest rates and corporate profits further reduces the effective duration of equities.15

NewImage

That suggests that the collapse of risk tolerance has gone much, much too far. Right now we are in a world in which savers do not view the risks and opportunities of the world with clear eyes, but rather with eyes that perceive through a distorted negative bubble. Financial markets thus seem to be failing on a very large scale to successfully mobilize the risk tolerance of economies. This is doubly unfortunate. To undertake new enterprise or to invest to produce economic growth requires that someone peer through the veil of time and ignorance. That means that somebody must provide the risk-bearing capacity, must be willing to eat the losses if something goes wrong.

Back in 2008 we thought–I thought–I gave many speeches about how we were experiencing a shock that boosted demand for safe liquid savings vehicles, and that this shock was going to trigger a sharp downturn in the North Atlantic economies. But, I thought and said, the downturn would be short. At first, I thought it was going to just be a liquidity squeeze–and we knew how to deal with liquidity squeezes by using open-market operations to boost the money supply. Then it became clear that it was more than a liquidity squeeze. Yet even though it was not a liquidity crisis–even though taking down, dusting off, and applying the monetarist depression-fighting playbook would not be sufficient–the examples of the Great Depression and of Japan since 1990 would provide a guide for what not to do. So, I believed and I said, the North Atlantic would quickly resolve insolvent institutions and write down unpayable debts. The recession would be sharp. But recovery would be rapid. And afterwards the global economy would have been reknit into much the same pattern it was in before 2008.

This was wrong.

We have not reknit the global economy into the same pattern. We have not restored the long-run growth path that the North Atlantic was on before 2007. After a liquidity squeeze is brought to an end, asset prices return to normal, the sea becomes calm again, and, broadly, patterns of the societal division of labor that were profitable before the squeeze are profitable again. Hence all that needs to be done to reattain full employment is to reknit the same division of labor.

Not true this time.

NewImage

This time, because there has been no recovery of risk tolerance–whether because of incomplete deleveraging, or the inability to reattain levels of risk tolerance that turned out ex post to be absurd but that nevertheless those engaged in enterprise required and expected, or for other reasons. Since there has been no recovery of risk tolerance, the previous division of labor across Europe cannot be profitably and sustainably reknit. There must be “structural adjustment” before anything like full employment can be reattained.16

Now nobody thinks that there ought to be a full recovery of risk tolerance to its levels in the days when a simple demonstration involving mark-to-model finance would convince a rating agency that a security deserved AAA, with which it could then be marketed at a spread of less than 25 basis points over the debt of credit-worthy sovereigns like Germany.

The pre-2008 European convergence equilibrium employed peripheral labor in Eastern, South Eastern, and Southern Europe in extremely risky long-duration enterprises: bets on the value of long-lived construction, bets that governments would resolve unresolvable public finance problems, bets that human capital would emerge to make profitable enterprises that would use new infrastructure. All of these bets seemed reasonable because risk tolerance was high. And perhaps most of them were reasonable–in the context of permanently-high risk tolerance. Hence the strong demand pushed relative real wages in peripheral Europe high relative to the regions’ relative productivity at producing tradable goods.17

All this came to an end in 2008.

NewImage

Now, in order to properly rebalance–even though rebalancing has been ongoing for six years–peripheral workers in Europe must either boost their productivity in making tradable goods or find something safe to do, must find something that does not require the mobilization of any substantial amount of European core risk tolerance in order to make the financing work, or must accept large real wages declines. These are the options. If it were not for the existence of the eurozone, all or nearly all peripheral European economies would choose the third: real wage reduction via depreciation of the currency. But for many that is not an option, or not a good option, or not seen right now as the best of the bad options. Peripheral depreciation for countries not in the eurozone and peripheral internal deflation for countries that are may in the end be the road chosen, in spite of all the economic pain and chaos it is generating now and will generate in the future. Euro-core inflation–“structural adjustment” in the northern core rather than in the periphery–is another possibility. Real “structural reforms” that successfully and substantially boost productivity in making tradable goods would be an option, if that unicorn could be found.

The problem is that “structural reform” too often stands as a placeholder for all good things that would increase an economy’s productivity. The danger is that when commitments to “structural reform” are not accompanied by any political economy strategy to successfully disrupt the current stakeholders blocking reforms in order to confiscate their current rents.

Attempting to restore financial-market risk tolerance–but, we hope, not to go-go levels–is another possible strategy. A 7%/year gap between the returns to properly-diversified real European equity baskets and the returns to lending money to the German government could be greatly lessened without, in my judgment, running any risk of a new round of bubble finance. There is using the governments’ powers to tax to mobilize the risk-bearing capacity of Europeans continent-wide–but if taxpayers are bearing the risk they deserve the returns of enterprise as well, and history had not been kind to those who think that governments’ interventions in industry can take the form of a very large and high-return investment portfolio. Better, probably, for the government to boost the supply of safe assets via deferring the taxation to ultimately amortize expenditures it ought to be undertaking anyway than to involve governments on a larger scale as venture capitalists and industrial financiers.

NewImage

This would be the case even were there not the additional problem that the risk-bearing capacity of taxpayers is mostly in the core of Europe, while the need for additional demand right now is mostly on the periphery. In the United States we do not track economic flows between states as Europe tracks flows between nations. We do not assign our national debt to individual states. We do not have to worry about this. In the United States back in 1991-2 after the collapse of the Savings and Loan bubble the United States central government transferred to Texas a sum equal to 25% of a year’s Texas GDP–an amazing no-strings bailout–without there being any complaint or worry about fiscal transfers or about encouraging a feckless culture of moral hazard in rattlesnake country. Part of it was that we did not notice. Part of it was that the senior senator from Texas was in the key position of being Chair of the Senate Finance Committee. Europe cannot do the equivalent, or anything close, without political upset.

Or else?

If structural reform and demand management are not both successfully performed, the alternative for Europe is then a long and uneven depression. Such might produce political pressures to set European economic integration into reverse. That, however, is a low-probability scenario. The higher-probability scenario in the event of the failure of structural reform and demand management is for European union and the euro to be held together by, year after year, just enough fiscal transfers and debt relief from the core to keep the grinding pain of deflation in the euro periphery from becoming so great as to trigger reversal. This would, in the end, be a much more expensive strategy for the core’s than taxpayers than one of biting the bullet and immediate resolution and debt writedown.

NewImage

What can we say about the roads toward structural adjustment–toward an economic configuration that could sustain continent-wide full employment without relying on unreasonable expectations of risk and return?

For some countries, exchange rate policy is possible. Exchange-rate policy is very effective medicine. It is a very good way of improving competitiveness and sharing social burdens. The problem is that it is such only as long as inflation expectations are anchored in domestic nominal terms. When they are not–especially when inflation expectations become anchored to inflation in import prices–relying on exchange rate depreciation is worse than useless. It is a medicine that is effective until resistance develops, and the fear is that alongside resistance there will also develop addiction to this mechanism. Hence it should be resorted to gingerly, lest overuse lead to high inflation and to even more intractable structural problems.

NewImage

Nevertheless, if the largest global financial shock in a century is not a time to resort to it for those countries that can, when would the proper time to resort to it be?

But how can we know whether tolerance has developed? That is a question. I do not have an answer.

Within the eurozone, internal devaluation is not a possibility. External devaluation–chiefly vis-a-vis the dollar, hoping that the United States will once again be willing to take on the role of importer of last resort–is a possibility. However, it does not resolve Europe’s internal structural problems. What it does do is make life very pleasant for the export powerhouse that is Germany. And while life is pleasant for Germany, perhaps its politicians can be induced to make concessions and provide funding and take policy steps that do resolve Europe’s internal structural problems.

NewImage

There is the possibility of replacing the missing private risk-tolerance for large-scale loan guarantees, asset purchases, or public spending to create demand for products that enterprises in peripheral regions can produce. That requires that European politicians know and understand and be willing to use the debt capacity of Europe’s core for the benefit of primarily the periphery but of the eurozone as a whole. There is “structural reform”, and the knotty question of whether structural reform is harder when unemployment is high or when it is low. Those in Frankfurt and Berlin are sure that structural reform can be accomplished only when unemployment is high and politicians feel a sense of crisis in their bones. Those in Washington are sure that structural reform can be accomplished only when unemployment is low and politicians can assemble fleshpots of resources to be distributed to assemble majority political coalitions. I avoid taking a stand on this issue by saying that I am just an economist. I do, however, note that the fact that at most one of these can be true does not mean that at least one of these is true.

And, as noted above, inflation in the European core and deflation in the European periphery round out the list. We have not had much of the first. We have had a lot of the second. A 2%/year inflation rate for the eurozone as a whole with a 0%/year inflation rate in the eurozone’s poorer half does mean 4%/year inflation in the eurozone’s richer half. I do not see how anything good could come out of a monetary target that turns into a mandate that inflation in the European core must always be less than 2%/year. Whether all who staff the ECB fully understand this is not clear.

But among all these possibilities, why choose? These all seem to me to be not substitutes but complements.

NewImage

Yet the political economy of today in Europe seems curious: these are all, overwhelming, posed as either-or substitutes, as mutually-exclusive alternatives. And I hear the same thing in the United States as well. Yet I have never understood this. I have always thought that the best and obvious strategy is to attempt them all–and to be willing to, pragmatically, reverse course on those that appear to turn out to have implementation costs greater than their potential benefits.

I have been waiting for five years for somebody to tell me why what seems obvious and best to me is not obvious and best.

And I am still waiting.


5720 words

The rise of big business and wage inequality

The potential explanations for the rise in income inequality are myriad. Inequality might be the caused by increasing demand for skilled labor, globalization, the weakening of labor market institutions, or some combination of all of the above. These theories, more or less, focus on changes in workers over time. But changes in the size of employers over time can also be an important source of rising income and wage inequality. A new National Bureau of Economics Research working paper argues that the increasing size of employers can help explain the rise in wage inequality.

Firms on average in the United States are getting bigger. The underlying reason for this shift toward bigness isn’t clear yet, but we have evidence in a decline in the start-up rate in the United States. For workers, this trend may be a positive one. Research shows that employees at larger employers receive a wage premium compared to those working at smaller firms. Consider a recent paper that looked at wages at retail stores. Workers at large box retailers make more than similar workers at smaller mom-and-pop retailers.

The new paper looks at the distribution of wages as a firm increases in size. The authors, Holger Mueller of New York University, Paige Ouimet of the University of North Carolina, and Elena Simintzi of the University of British Columbia, use a proprietary data set on wages inside firms in the United Kingdom. They divide workers within a firm into 9 groups by skill level, which also corresponds with wage levels inside the firm.

What they find is that inequality, measured by wage ratios, increase as the firm grows in size, but this trend is driven entirely by an increasing gap between wages at the top compared to those at the middle of the distribution. The ratio of middle wages to bottom wages actually doesn’t increase as the firm size does.

As the authors point out, this trend in intra-firm inequality matches up quite well with what is happening in the larger labor markets of the United Kingdom and the United States. The most recent rise in inequality in these two nations is largely the story of the top pulling away from the middle and bottom, not the bottom failing behind. And that’s exactly what happens to firms as they grow larger according to Mueller, Ouimet and Simintzi’s results. So it makes sense that the trends would match up as more workers are employed at large businesses.

The authors also point out that the ratio between the middle and the bottom of wage earners in these increasingly larger firms stays constant not because they are growing at relatively the same rate. Rather wages for these less well-compensated workers don’t appear to increase with firm size. In other words, workers at the bottom and the middle don’t make more at larger businesses. This result means that the wage-premium for working at a large employer is driven mostly by wage increases for those at the top.

One important caveat is that Mueller, Ouiment and Simintzi look at wage trends within firms while many of the studies on the wage premium are based on the size of establishments. The difference, for example, is this: Looking at a restaurant chain means looking at a firm as a whole compared to each individual franchise, which is called an establishment.

And of course, they look at data from the United Kingdom. Whether these results would be replicated with U.S. data remains to be seen. So research that tried to better understand this dynamic in the United States would be quite illuminating. Outside of their specific findings, Mueller, Ouimet and Simintzi’s paper is another reminder that looking at the dynamics of firms and workers together can help shed light on deeper trends, such as wage inequality, in our economy.

Over at Project Syndicate: What Failed in 2008?

Over at Project Syndicate:

For a while the best book on the macroeconomic catastrophe that struck the North Atlantic starting in 2007 was Gary Gorton’s Slapped by the Invisible Hand. Them for a while the best book was Alan Blinder’s After the Music Stopped. Now these have been superseded by two: the extremely-observant sensible Tory Martin Wolf’s The Shifts and the Shocks; and my friend, patron, teacher, and (until the last reshuffle) office neighbor Barry Eichengreen ‘s Hall of Mirrors. Read and grasp the messages of both of these, and you are in the top 0.001% of the world in terms of understanding what has happened to us–and what the likely scenarios are for what comes next.

Consider, first, Martin Wolf’s The Shifts and the Shocks. Its spine is a masterful cataloguing of all the major shifts we have seen that set the stage for the disaster that hit the North Atlantic in 2007-9:

  1. The huge rise in the wealth of the global 0.01% and 0.1%, with its consequent pressures for overleverage and demand volatility
  2. The global savings glut, with more of the same pressures.
  3. The “insouciance” toward the resulting risks generated by the intellectual victory of the rational-expectations and efficient-markets hypotheses.
  4. The resulting deregulation, that made it easy to sell assets perceived to be safe that were not in fact so and to greatly multiply the systemic risk in the system beyond any central banker’s imagining.
  5. The resulting policy-making climate, with the three-fold hubris of: (1) underestimating tail risks, (2) settling on a 2%/year inflation target that did not provide sufficient systemic risk sea-room, and (3) the greater hubris of the creation of the euro.
  6. The continuation in which it apparently made sense in 2008 and since to do what was necessary but no more than necessary to handle the immediate crisis

In the context of these shifts, Martin Wolf sees immediate need in the short-run for policies to solve the immediate crisis: more spending, especially investment spending, by reserve-currency issuing sovereigns; more issue of high-quality debt to resolve the safe asset shortage by reserve-currency issuing sovereigns; and reserve-currency issuing central banks that monetize enough of this debt to raise the trend inflation rate from 2%/year to 3%/year or 4%/year. The argument seems, to me at least, to be convincing and unassailable.

But that is not all. Wolf’s book calls as well for medium run policies: (1) Either “break up… or… create a minimum set of institutions and policies” to make the euro work. And (2) the obvious but undone regulatory measures to greatly diminish leverage and the use of debt. And last come Wolf’s recommendations for the long-run: policies for more equal wealth; better economics less in thrall to rational-expectations and efficient-market ideologues; “more global regulation… and more freedom for individual countries to craft their own responses”. These seem to me to be obvious requirements on the situation.

But 2005-2014 did not create the pressures to do what Wolf and I see as the obvious things. Why not? And here is where Eichengreen’s Hall of Mirrors is most useful.

It tells the story of a historical process with five stages. The first is the intellectual victory within sensible economics of monetarist over old Keynesian and Minskyite interpretations of the Great Depression. The second is the resulting ability and willingness of governments to pull the monetarist policy package–what Milton Friedman had promised would have stopped the Great Depression in its tracks and erased its effects–off of the shelf and apply it in 2008-2009. The third is the very incomplete but also very real partial effectiveness of that package, for the monetarist interpretation of the Great Depression was, to put it baldy, wrong and radically incomplete. But it did enough good that a full-fledged repetition of the Great Depression was avoided.

And that led to the fourth stage: the declaration by governments of victory–of green shoots–of the successful resolution of a crisis–of a need to turn policies toward more important “structural” issues involving the necessity for “austerity” in the size of government. This fourth stage has been followed by the fifth in which we are now embedded: First, a very partial barely-a-recovery, one that is turning into a new normal in which the North Atlantic will turn out to have thrown away a full ten percent of all of what was its potential future wealth. Second, the failure to undertake the financial regulatory and economic governance reforms needed to diminish the chances of a repeat of the disaster in which we are still embedded.

Thus, Eichengreen concludes, partial success turns out to be global failure: immediate pain of a proportional magnitude equal to that of the Great Depression was avoided, but the potential for economic growth and successful macroeconomic stabilization in the North Atlantic going forward will be (because of failure to learn the lessons of 2000-2010 and make the obvious reforms) less post-2015 than it was post-1945, back when the lessons of 1925-1935 had been learned and the obvious reforms had been made.

Wolf sets out what we ought to have done. Eichengreen provides the narrative of the historical process which has led us not to do it.


889 words

The Macroeconomic Situation and Macroeconomic Policy: Insiders and Outsiders: Focus

Somebody Is Inside an Echo Chamber. But Who?

Paul Krugman fears that somebody is trapped inside an echo chamber, hearing only things that confirm what they already believe:

Disagreement… over US monetary policy… [between those] very worried that the Fed may be gearing up to raise rates too soon… [and the] sanguine… seems to depend on one thing: whether the economist in question is currently in a policy position…. We don’t have access to different facts; we don’t, in any fundamental sense, have different economic models…

But how can we tell which side has lost contact with the reality out there?

Well, I think–as does Paul–that it is the “insiders” who are being optimistic and unrealistic in their plans to start raising short-term safe interest rates from zero in June 2015 and then, if past tightenings are any guide, raise them to what they regard as a full-employment growth-along-the-potential-path level of 5%/year or so by the end of 2017. One reason is that I do not see a strong world and a weak dollar that would produce a stronger export boom relative to potential, do not see a recovery of relative government purchases to normal levels, cannot envision much stronger business investment without support from other strong components of demand, cannot see the restructuring of housing market finance that would produce even a normal pace of housing construction, cannot see where else durable demand expansion could come from, and fear adverse shocks.

FRED Graph FRED St Louis Fed

But I do not think we have to decide. I think that even if we are uncertain whether the optimistic “insiders” or the pessimistic “outsiders” are correct, elementary prudent optimal-control theory tells us that we should act as if the “outsiders” are right.

But I have gotten ahead of myself:

Tim Duy says:

Tim Duy: Policy Divergence: “The Federal Reserve stands…

…in stark contrast with its… counterparts…. The ECB… quantitative easing, the Bank of England… more dovish… Denmark joined the Swiss in cutting rates… the Bank of Canada…. How long can the Fed continue to stand against this tide?… The Fed should of course be cautious…. But how does the Fed communicate such caution?

The challenge I see for the Fed is that they will want to hold the statement fairly steady…. Such a steady hand, however, may be viewed as hawkish, which is also a message the Fed does not want to send…. Bullard wants to ignore the market-based inflation metrics that would have in the past told him to hold off on any tightening. He really, really wants to liftoff from the zero bound, the sooner the better. I don’t think this level of immediacy is felt by other FOMC members, but I do think they are hoping and praying the data gives them enough to move by mid-year…

And:

Tim Duy: While We Wait For Yet Another FOMC Statement: “The Fed recognizes that hiking rates prematurely…

…to ‘give them room’ in the next recession is of course self-defeating. They are not going to invite a recession simply to prove they have the tools to deal with another recession. The reasons the Fed wants to normalize policy are, I fear, a bit more mundane: (1) They believe the economy is approaching a more normal environment with solid GDP growth and near-NAIRU unemployment. They do not believe such an environment is consistent with zero rates. (2) They believe that monetary policy operates with long and variable lags. Consequently, they need to act before inflation hits 2% if they do not want to overshoot their target. And they in fact have no intention of overshooting their target. (3) They do not believe in the secular stagnation story. They do not believe that the estimate of the neutral Fed Funds rate should be revised sharply downward. Hence 25bp, or 50bp, or even 100bp still represents loose monetary policy by their definition. I am currently of the opinion that there is a reasonable chance the Fed is wrong on the third point, and that they have less room to maneuver than they believe.

Paul Krugman says:

Paul Krugman: Insiders, Outsiders, and U.S. Monetary Policy: “even smart, flexible people can fall prey…

…to incestuous amplification…. I worry that this is what is happening to the insiders. On the whole, it seems less likely for the outsiders, although it’s true that the Keynesian econoblogs form what amounts to a tight ongoing discussion group that could be doing some amplification of its own…

And:

Unusually, Olivier [Blanchard] and I… have a… disagreement… over US monetary policy…. I’m very worried that the Fed may be gearing up to raise rates too soon; he’s sanguine… part of a wider split… [that] seems to depend on one thing: whether the economist in question is currently in a policy position. Larry [Summers]… sounds exactly like me:

Deflation and secular stagnation are the threats of our time. The risks are enormously asymmetric…. The Fed should not be fighting against inflation until it sees the whites of its eyes….

We don’t have access to different facts; we don’t, in any fundamental sense, have different economic models…. If you ask me, there’s a worrying complacency among the insiders right now, and I would urge them to consider the potential consequences…

So how would we tell whether, right now, it is the outsiders are overstating the dangers to premature tightening, or it is the insiders who are understating the dangers to premature tightening here in the United States?

To answer this question, I think we need to consider five points–the first about our decision procedure, the second about the level of spending consistent with full employment, the third about the degree of uncertainty and variability, the fourth about the vulnerabilities of the economy to spending deviations above and below the projected current-policy path, and the fifth about the effectiveness of our optimal-control levers in different scenarios.

The first point is that if it turns out that we cannot tell–that we have to split the difference–then the considerations that rule are the asymmetries in the situation.

The second point is that no one right now has a good and convincing read on what, exactly, the level of spending consistent with full employment at the currently-projected price level is. Uncertainty is rife: if there was ever a time for considering not just the central tendency of the forecast but the risks on either side and taking optimal control appropriately valuing these risks seriously, it is right now.

The third point is that we are not just uncertain about what the proper full-employment path for demand is, we have much more than the usual amount of uncertainty about nearly all other dimensions of the structure of the economy. To suppose that any of the emergent properties that are policy multipliers can be estimated from data collected during “normal” times is to make an enormous leap of faith.

The fourth point is that downside risks to the forecast greatly exceed upside opportunities. The inflation rate is so low that marginal deviations from the target on the upside have little cost. The employment-to-population ratio is so low that marginal deviations of it on the downside from its projected current-policy path are very costly.

And the fifth point is that, while the Federal Reserve has powerful levers to restrict demand if spending shoots above the desired policy path, its levers to expand demand if spending falls below have been demonstrated over the past six years to be relatively weak.

Thus, if it turns out that we cannot tell–and we cannot tell–then it is not correct that we should split the difference. The considerations that rule are then the asymmetries in the situation. It is, right now, much worse to undershoot than to overshoot full-employment demand: the one causes extra and pointless unemployment, the second disappoints the rentier, and we live in a poor world in which the first is more of a policy error than the second. It is, right now, true that entral banks have a very easy time restricting aggregate demand via contractionary policy but–at and near the zero lower bound, at least–a hell of a time boosting aggregate demand via expansionary policy.

These asymmetries mean that, as far as policy is concerned, the “outsiders” win any tie and win any near-tie: the “insiders” should govern what policy should be only if there is not just a preponderance of the but clear and convincing evidence on their side.

Yet the Federal Reserve appears to have decided:

  • that those who think that the economy is near full employment and is in a durable recovery have by far the better of the argument as to what the central tendency projected current-policy demand path is.
  • that it is appropriate to make policy via certainty-equivalance.

Given the inability of the Federal Reserve to attain traction at the ZLB, its current frame of mind–which appears to be doing certainty-equivalence policy–makes no sense to me. Certainty-equivalence is appropriate only with a symmetric loss function and a symmetric ability to compensate for deviations on either side of the target. We do not have either of those.

Has there been an explanation of why the Federal Reserve’s policy is appropriate, given the uncertainties, given the asymmetry of the loss function, and given the asymmetry of the control levers, that I have missed? If so, where is it?


1644 words

Macroeconomics: Listening to Reality: A Note from Twitter I Want to Save

.@MikePMoffatt: Things like this have raised and greatly sharpened my estimate of current ZLB fiscal multiplier: http://delong.typepad.com/sdj/2015/01/over-at-equitable-growth-yes-the-past-four-years-are-powerful-evidence-for-the-keynesian-view-of-what-happens-at-the-zero-l.html

Since 2007, reality has spoken. Since 2007, reality has raised my estimate of the U.S. fiscal multiplier from 1.5 to 2.5, and sharpened it. Since 2007, reality has raised my estimate of the U.S. debt capacity from 75% of a year’s GDP to >150%. Since 2007, reality has left my very fuzzy estimate that the effects of QE are small unchanged.

Now Scott Sumner says 2013-14 a huge surprise that should have shifted my estimates again, substantially. And I really do not see why…


.@cellsatwork There’s an extended substantive pre-response [by Krugman to Sumner]:

  • .

    Sumner doesn’t seem to have read any of it…

The federal budget, interest rates, and savings gluts

The U.S. Congressional Budget Office yesterday released its updated Budget and Economic Outlook for the period between 2015 and 2025. As usually happens when CBO releases a document about the federal budget, most of the conversation focuses on the levels of spending and taxation the agency projects will happen in the future, particularly the difference between the level of spending and the level of taxation, better known as the budget deficit.

Perhaps a more interesting conversation would be about what CBO projects about the future path of interest rates, something that caught the eye of Matthew C. Klein at FT Alphaville. Despite CBO heralding increased budget deficits due to rising health care costs and an aging population, Klein sees that the projections of higher deficits are almost entirely about higher interest payments on debt the U.S. government already owes. In other words, the projections of a larger budget deficit are contingent on the path of future interest rates.

Specifically, CBO projects that the interest rate on a 10-year Treasury note will be 4.6 percent starting in 2020. For context, the 10-year interest rate in June 2007, before the damaged inflicted by the bursting of the housing bubble became apparent, was about 5 percent. And today the interest rate is about 1.8 percent.

Of course, very low rates today are a sign of concerns about economic growth outside of the United States, particularly in the European economies that use the euro. But how much higher can we expect long-term interest rates to rise? CBO projects that the 10-year rate will jump to 3.0 percent in 2015. There is cause to question such a quick pick-up in rates.

First, according to CBO’s own projections the overall growth rate of the economy is supposed to be below its potential growth rate for most of the 10-year window. Only in 2017 and 2018 does GDP reach its potential growth rate according to CBO. The rest of the time it’s below that rate.

Secondly, there are broader forces that inhibit rising long-term interest rates. The last time the U.S. Federal Reserve tried to raise interest rates, in 2004 there was no appreciable increase in the long-term rates. That phenomenon in part led then Fed Governor Ben Bernanke to coin the term “global savings glut” almost 10 years ago. The idea posits that the amount of savings in the global economy has increased so much that it has outpaced demand and interest rates across the world are held down. And while the source of the glut may be changing, it appears to still be around.

Of course, when talking about U.S. interest rates the decisions of the Federal Reserve have to be considered. Its policy-setting arm, the Federal Open Markets Committee, is currently meeting, but is not expected to start raising interest rates. Or at least not yet. But those moves should only affect short-term rates. As for the long-run, we all, including CBO, will just have to wait.

Morning Must-Read: Tim Duy: While We Wait For Yet Another FOMC Statement

Given the inability of the Federal Reserve to attain traction at the ZLB, its current frame of mind–which appears to be doing certainty-equivalence policy–makes no sense to me. Certainty-equivalence is appropriate only with a symmetric loss function and a symmetric ability to compensate for deviations on either side of the target. We do not have either of those.

Has there been an explanation of why the Federal Reserve’s policy is appropriate given the asymmetry of the loss function and the asymmetry of the control levers that I have missed? If so, where is it?

Tim Duy: While We Wait For Yet Another FOMC Statement: “The Fed recognizes that hiking rates prematurely…

…to ‘give them room’ in the next recession is of course self-defeating. They are not going to invite a recession simply to prove they have the tools to deal with another recession. The reasons the Fed wants to normalize policy are, I fear, a bit more mundane: (1) They believe the economy is approaching a more normal environment with solid GDP growth and near-NAIRU unemployment. They do not believe such an environment is consistent with zero rates. (2) They believe that monetary policy operates with long and variable lags. Consequently, they need to act before inflation hits 2% if they do not want to overshoot their target. And they in fact have no intention of overshooting their target. (3) They do not believe in the secular stagnation story. They do not believe that the estimate of the neutral Fed Funds rate should be revised sharply downward. Hence 25bp, or 50bp, or even 100bp still represents loose monetary policy by their definition. I am currently of the opinion that there is a reasonable chance the Fed is wrong on the third point, and that they have less room to maneuver than they believe.

Things to Read on the Afternoon of January 27, 2015

Must- and Shall-Reads:

  • Heather Boushey: On “Capital in the Twenty-First Century”: “We… have lived through an era where the presumption is that our society marches always towards greater equality or less discrimination, even if slowly. But if Thomas is right… this era could be at an end… Downton Abbey… no other way for Grantham’s three daughters to maintain their standard of living other than marrying well. So, the show’s first season focuses on whether the eldest daughters would concede to marry her cousin Matthew. If Thomas is right, then once again, the rules over inheritances will make all the difference for the potential for women’s equality…. In 2014, only one-in-ten U.S. billionaires were women (11.4 percent) and the female share of self-made billionaires is only 3.1 percent…”
  1. Simon Wren-Lewis: Post Recession Lessons: “I regard 2010 as a fateful year for the advanced economies… the year that the US, UK and Eurozone switched from fiscal stimulus to fiscal contraction… this policy switch is directly responsible for the weak recovery in all three countries/zones. A huge amount of resources have been needlessly wasted as a result, and much misery prolonged. This post is… about… taking that as given and asking what should we conclude…. To answer that question, what happened in Greece (in 2010, not two days ago) may be critical…. Let me paint a relatively optimistic picture of the recent past. Greece had to default because previous governments had been profligate and had hidden that fact from everyone…. Recessions… tend to be when things like that get exposed. If Greece had been a country with its own exchange rate, then it would have been a footnote… fiscal stimulus that had begun in all three countries/zones in 2009 would have continued (or at least not been reversed), and the recovery would have been robust. Instead Greece was part of the Eurozone…. Policy makers in other union countries prevaricated…. So the Greek crisis became a Eurozone periphery crisis…. This led to panic not just in the Eurozone but in all the advanced economies. Stimulus turned to austerity. By the time some in organisations like the IMF began to realise that this shift to austerity had been a mistake, it was too late. The recovery had been anemic…”
  2. W. Arthur Lewis:
  3. Stephanie Lo and Kenneth Rogoff: Secular Stagnation, Debt Overhang, and Other Rationales for Sluggish Growth, Six Years on: “There is considerable controversy over why sluggish economic growth persists across many advanced economies six years after the onset of the financial crisis. Theories include a secular deficiency in aggregate demand, slowing innovation, adverse demographics, lingering policy uncertainty, post-crisis political fractionalisation, debt overhang, insufficient fiscal stimulus, excessive financial regulation, and some mix of all of the above. This paper surveys the alternative viewpoints. We argue that until significant pockets of private, external and public debt overhang further abate, the potential role of other headwinds to economic growth will be difficult to quantify.”
  4. Dean Baker: Did Cutting the Duration of Unemployment Benefits Lead to Faster Job Growth in 2014?: “Hagedorn, Manovskii, and Mitman…. The LAUS data are largely model driven… little direct data for many counties. The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) generates employment estimates for these counties from a variety of variables…. The same sort of test can readily be constructed at the state level using the CES data… a much larger survey… of employers… [with] considerably less noise… measuring the number of jobs in the same states as we are measuring changes in benefit duration. Following HMM, I divided the states into a long duration group… and short duration group…. While HMM found the long duration group had a sharper uptick in job growth, the CES data show the opposite…”

Should Be Aware of:

 

  1. Greg Sargent: Republican State Officials Cast Doubts on Anti-Obamacare Lawsuit: “Several state officials who were directly involved at the highest levels… all of them Republicans or appointees of GOP governors… [say] that at no point in the decision-making process… was the possible loss of subsidies even considered as a factor. None of these officials… read the statute as the challengers do. Cindi Jones…. This week, a number of states will file a brief siding with the government, arguing that nothing in the ACA indicated opting for the federal exchange would cost them subsidies. They will argue… that the challengers’ interpretation raises serious constitutional questions: The states were never given clear warning that the failure to set up exchanges could bring them serious harm…. John Watkins…. Sandy Praeger…. Linda Sheppard…”
  2. Ogged: Have We Talked About Number Needed to Treat?: “Nice summary here. Longer Wired article here. NNT site here. Table of NNTs for common stuff here. Elegant little Wikipedia table here. Amazing how little effect so many established therapies have.”

Afternoon Must-Read: Heather Boushey: On “Capital in the Twenty-First Century”

Heather Boushey: On “Capital in the Twenty-First Century”: “We… have lived through an era…

…where the presumption is that our society marches always towards greater equality or less discrimination, even if slowly. But if Thomas is right… this era could be at an end… Downton Abbey… no other way for Grantham’s three daughters to maintain their standard of living other than marrying well. So, the show’s first season focuses on whether the eldest daughters would concede to marry her cousin Matthew. If Thomas is right, then once again, the rules over inheritances will make all the difference for the potential for women’s equality…. In 2014, only one-in-ten U.S. billionaires were women (11.4 percent) and the female share of self-made billionaires is only 3.1 percent…

This reminds me of what I wrote back in 2002:

Back before the industrial revolution bequests were a major component of acquired wealth. With a society-wide total capital-output ratio of 3:1 and a
generation length of 25 years, roughly 12 percent of a year’s output will change hands and pass down through the generations through inheritance every year…. My guess is that every year bequests turned over to the receiving cohort were equal to between 16 and 24 percent of annual output. This is more than ten times the contribution of net investment to wealth. Contrast the dominance of inheritance over net investment before the industrial revolution with the situation today…. Net investment… [of] between 12 percent and 16 percent of total output…. This balance between [net] accumulation and bequests is in sharp contrast
to the more than 1:10 ratio of the pre-Industrial Revolution past…

If one imagines that creative destruction shifts an extra 7% of so of today’s output from losers to winners each year, then the ratio of accumulation to bequests today is not 1:1 but rather 3:2–an even more striking contrast with the pre-industrial past.

And Thomas Piketty thinks we are likely to go back there, so that choosing the right parents and marrying well will once again be of overwhelming importance in upward (or avoiding downward) mobility…

Afternoon Must-Read: Simon Wren-Lewis: Post-Recession Lessons

A generation or two ago, the push for central-bank independence was all about harnessing central banks’ credibility as inflation fighters in a context in which it was feared that elected legislators would lean overboard on the excessive spending side.

Today, Simon Wren-Lewis calls for transferring not just monetary policy but fiscal policy stabilization authority over to central banks, on the grounds that their technocratic chops are much better for fiscal policy then relying on elected legislators who are the prisoners of ordoliberal ideologies, the belief the governments like households need to balance their budgets, and of the austerity-loving 0.1%.

What could possibly go wrong?

Simon Wren-Lewis: Post Recession Lessons: “I regard 2010 as a fateful year for the advanced economies…

…the year that the US, UK and Eurozone switched from fiscal stimulus to fiscal contraction… this policy switch is directly responsible for the weak recovery in all three countries/zones. A huge amount of resources have been needlessly wasted as a result, and much misery prolonged. This post is… about… taking that as given and asking what should we conclude…. To answer that question, what happened in Greece (in 2010, not two days ago) may be critical…. Let me paint a relatively optimistic picture of the recent past. Greece had to default because previous governments had been profligate and had hidden that fact from everyone…. Recessions… tend to be when things like that get exposed. If Greece had been a country with its own exchange rate, then it would have been a footnote… fiscal stimulus that had begun in all three countries/zones in 2009 would have continued (or at least not been reversed), and the recovery would have been robust. Instead Greece was part of the Eurozone…. Policy makers in other union countries prevaricated…. So the Greek crisis became a Eurozone periphery crisis…. This led to panic not just in the Eurozone but in all the advanced economies. Stimulus turned to austerity. By the time some in organisations like the IMF began to realise that this shift to austerity had been a mistake, it was too late. The recovery had been anemic.

Why is that an optimistic account? Because it is basically a story of bad luck…. Now for the pessimistic version. The political right in all three countries/zones was always set against fiscal stimulus…. Without Greece, we still would have had a Conservative led government taking power in the UK in 2010, and we still would have had Republicans blocking stimulus moves and then forcing fiscal austerity. The right’s strength in the media, together with the ‘commonsense’ idea that governments like individuals need to tighten their belts in bad times… [meant] austerity was bound to prevail…. Greece may have just voted against austerity, but there is every chance that in the UK the Conservatives will retain power this year on an austerity platform and the Republicans are just the presidency away from complete control in the US. If the pessimistic account is right, then it has important implications for macroeconomics. Although it may be true that fiscal stimulus is capable of assisting monetary policy when interest rates are at the ZLB, the political economy of the situation will mean it may well not happen….

When some economists over the last few years began to push the idea of helicopter money, I was initially rather sceptical… helicopter money when you have inflation targets is identical to tax cuts plus Quantitative Easing (QE), so why not just argue for an expansionary fiscal policy?… However, if the pessimistic account is correct, then arguing with politicians for better fiscal policy is quite likely to be a waste of time…. A more robust response is to argue for institutional changes so that politicians find it much more difficult to embark on austerity at the ZLB…. Central banks have QE, but helicopter money would be a much more effective instrument. To put it another way, central bank independence was all about taking macroeconomic stabilisation away from politicians, because politicians were not very good at it. The last five years have demonstrated how bad at it they can be…