Must-Read: Claudia Sahm: Telling Macro Stories with Micro

Must-Read: Claudia Sahm: Telling Macro Stories with Micro:

Economists are avid storytellers…

A good story paper in economics, according to David Romer, has three characteristics: a viewpoint, a lever, and a result…. Blog or media coverage… focuses on the result…. Economists… spend more time on the lever, the how-did-they-get-the-result part…. The viewpoint matters… but it usually holds across many papers.

Best to focus the new stuff. Except when the viewpoint comes under scrutiny, then the stories can really change…. One long-standing viewpoint in economics is that changes in the macro-economy can largely be understood by studying changes in macro aggregates. Ironically, this viewpoint even survived macro’s push to micro foundations with a “representative agent” stepping in as the missing link between aggregate data and micro theory…. An ever-growing body of research and commentary is helping to identify times when differences at the micro level are relevant for macro outcomes….

In the past nine years, have seen models that condition on aggregate measures of income, wealth, interest rates, sentiment, and credit conditions do a pretty good job explaining the changes in aggregate consumer spending…. Adding micro heterogeneity to macro models is one in a long list of possible improvements. Adding a more realistic financial sector, exploring non-linearities, relaxing rational expectations, and extracting a better signal from noisy aggregate data are all in the queue too…. I suspect the Representative Agent is not getting voted off macro island any time soon….

Economics is not supposed to be about economists, but sometimes our stories can feel that way, especially to non economists. And to be fair, the viewpoints that economists bring to their work do have an impact on the results, if nothing else by what we choose to study…

Must-Read: Brad Setser: What To Do When Countries With Fiscal Space Won’t Use It?

Must-Read: Brad Setser: What To Do When Countries With Fiscal Space Won’t Use It?:

Fiscal policy alone doesn’t determine the current account….

And, well, a significant share of many countries’ current account is now coming from investment income earned abroad, and that can fluctuate in strange ways. But there is a potential adding-up issue if all the large surplus economies in East Asia deliver on their planned fiscal consolidations. The first order impact of fiscal consolidation in all three should be a bigger external surplus in all three. By forecasting that away, the IMF runs the risk of understating the drag fiscal consolidation in East Asia might pose to global demand.

Must-Read: Heidi Shierholz: The Myth of Job Polarization

Must-Read: Heidi Shierholz: The Myth of Job Polarization:

In the first few years of the recovery, growth was very strong in very low-wage jobs that pay $10 per hour or less. This is typical…

…in the early phase of a recovery, when jobs are being added but the labor market still has a lot of slack, there tends to be disproportionate growth in low-wage jobs. The strong growth in low-wage jobs was offset by weak growth in middle-wage jobs…. Since 2013 the pattern has shifted. There has been a notable decline in the number of workers in very low-wage jobs…. The last few years saw disproportionate gains in middle- and high-wage jobs. In particular, there has been extremely strong growth in jobs with wages between $12 and $18 per hour. Jobs in the $19-$35 range saw growth that was roughly in line with what would have been expected given the overall level of job growth. And there was strong growth in jobs that paid more than $35 per hour…. As the labor market has strengthened, the pattern of very strong growth in low-wage jobs and weak growth in middle-wage jobs in the first few years of the recovery has shifted…

Weekend reading: “Read this in 3D” edition

This is a weekly post we publish on Fridays with links to articles that touch on economic inequality and growth. The first section is a round-up of what Equitable Growth published this week and the second is the work we’re highlighting from elsewhere. We won’t be the first to share these articles, but we hope by taking a look back at the whole week, we can put them in context.

Equitable Growth round-up

Many workers in the United States who are paid by the hour are increasingly subject to unpredictable schedules. A new report from Heather Boushey and Bridget Ansel argues that these schedules have economic consequences for individuals, firms, and the broader U.S. economy. The coauthors break down the report in a blog post here.

On Tuesday, Equitable Growth released its latest round of working papers with the research covering trends in inequality, the creation of a data set of historical state and local minimum wages, and the impact of the Great Recession in Detroit.

Kavya Vaghul writes on the new research on the impact of the latest recession on the financial well-being of low and moderate income households in the Detroit area. These households were struggling before and the recession only made things worse.

Researchers and policymakers examining inequality often focus solely on income even though wealth and consumption inequality occasionally have their time in the spotlight. But how about looking at how the three trends interact? Two of our new working papers do just that.

In recent years, corporate profits have increased relative to the gross domestic product of the U.S. economy. But U.S. corporate tax revenue as a share of GDP hasn’t increased. Is the corporate income tax so flawed we should scrap it? Or does it need a big overhaul?

Links from around the web

Larry Summers continues his series outlining his disappointment with the proceedings at the Jackson Hole conference last month. “On balance, I think the Fed’s complacency about its current toolbox is unwarranted.” [larrysummers.com]

Speaking of the Federal Reserve, Tim Duy writes on the possibility of the central bank continuing to push the unemployment rate lower. “The Fed seems to place almost zero weight on the probability that the natural rate of unemployment is significantly below their estimates.” [fed watch]

One potential future prospect for the labor markets of high-income countries is that the majority of workers will end up in “make-work” jobs that have very low productivity. But is that already happening? Matt Klein looks at the data and finds that since 1990, 96 percent of net job growth has happened in industries where productivity growth is low or hard to measure. [ft alphaville]

Some jobs are likely to vanish and employment in these occupations is not evenly distributed across the United States. Emily Badger looks at a new report that tries to understand which parts of the country are most likely to see jobs disappear in the long run. [wonkblog]

In economic circles, a now famous graph of global income growth since 1988 shows strong growth for the middle and the top of the income distribution. But how would that graph look for smaller locations such as, say, the 50 states?  Quoctrung Bui makes those graphs and writes them up. [the upshot]

Friday figure

Smeeding income/wealth mobility
Whether it's wealth or income, those at the top and the bottom are very likely to stay there
Chance an individual starting in a quintile ends up in each quintile later in life.

Figure from “Inequality of income, wealth, or consumption? How about all three?” by Nick Bunker

The U.S. corporate income tax in a time of high profits

Apple Inc. made news yesterday when it announced the newest model of the iPhone and a number of other updates to its other products. The company was also in the news late last month, but the subject was instead about its profits. The European Commission ruled that a tax arrangement between Apple and Ireland violated European Union rules and that the Cupertino, CA-based technology company owed Ireland €13 billion, about $14.5 billion, in back taxes.

The Apple incident is just an extreme example of how far some countries will go to get corporate profits booked within their borders. Apple may eventually have to pay more taxes to Ireland—legal challenges could drag on for years. Yet the company still has more than $215 billion in cash sitting overseas as a means of reducing their tax liability —even if the company’s CEO seems ready to move the cash to the United States.

Apple is far from alone in shifting its profits overseas, as Reed College economist Kimberly Clausing pointed out in a report for Equitable Growth earlier this year. As corporate profits have risen over the past 30 years, corporate tax revenue as fallen as a share of GDP and offshoring is a major contributor to this trend.. (See Figure 1.)

Figure 1

Looking at this graph, it seems as if policymakers might be better off scrapping the U.S. corporate income tax and trying to tax profits some other way. Some analysts have called for shifting the tax burden off of corporations and onto the shareholders of those firms. But more and more U.S. stocks are not taxable due to the rise of tax-advantaged retirement plans and more foreign ownership of U.S. stocks.

These trends and many other reasons are why policymakers interested in taxing corporate profits should focus on reforming the corporate income tax, not scrapping it. On Monday, Equitable Growth will publish a new report by Clausing that makes the argument for the “indispensable corporate tax.” Check back next week to see what reforms could help.

Must-Read: Tim Duy: Is Pushing Unemployment Lower A Risky Strategy?

Must-Read: Tim Duy thinks, I believe correctly, that the Fed is confusing its own past policy errors with economic laws:

Tim Duy: Is Pushing Unemployment Lower A Risky Strategy?:

Fed hawks are pushing for a rate hike sooner than later in an effort to prevent the economy from “overhearing”…

…argued to set the stage for the next recession…. John Williams:

History teaches us that an economy that runs too hot for too long can generate imbalances, potentially leading to excessive inflation, asset market bubbles, and ultimately economic correction and recession. A gradual process of raising rates reduces the risks of such an outcome…. If we wait too long to remove monetary accommodation, we hazard allowing imbalances to grow, requiring us to play catch-up, and not leaving much room to maneuver. Not to mention, a sudden reversal of policy could be disruptive and slow the economy in unintended ways….

William Dudley….

A particular risk of late and fast is that the unemployment rate could significantly undershoot the level consistent with price stability. If this occurred, then inflation would likely rise above our objective. At that point, history shows it is very difficult to push the unemployment rate back up just a little bit in order to contain inflation pressures. Looking at the post-war period, whenever the unemployment rate has increased by more than 0.3 to 0.4 percentage points, the economy has always ended up in a full-blown recession…. This is an outcome to avoid….

I don’t know that there is a law of economics where the unemployment can never be nudged up a few fractions of a percentage point. But I do think there is a policy mechanism…. Rhe Fed tends to overemphasize the importance of lagging data such as inflation and wages and discount the lags in their own policy process. Essentially, the Fed ignores the warning signs of recession, ultimately over tightening…. For instance, an inverted yield curve traditionally indicates substantially tight monetary conditions. Yet even after the yield curve inverted at the end of January 2000, the Fed continued tightening through May of that year, adding an additional 100bp to the fed funds rate. The yield curve began to invert in January of 2006; the Fed added another 100bp of tightening in the first half of that year. This isn’t an economic mechanism…. This is a policy error….

Bottom Line: The Fed thinks the costs of undershooting their estimate of the natural rate of unemployment outweigh the benefits. I am skeptical they are doing the calculus right on this one. I would be more convinced they had it right if I sensed that placed greater weight on the possibility that they are too pessimistic about the natural rate. I would be more convinced if they were already at their inflation target. And I would be more convinced if their analysis of why tightening cycles end in recessions was a bit more introspective. Was it destiny or repeated policy error? But none of these things seem to be true.

Must-Reads: September 7, 2016


Should Reads:

Must-Read: Lawrence Summers: The Fed’s Complacency About Its Current Toolbox Is Unwarranted

Must-Read: Larry Summers is right: forward guidance and large-scale QE are unlikely to be powerful enough tools for the Fed to deal with the next recession. This is especially true given the Fed’s current policy posture. Large-scale QE is, I believe, primarily useful as a signal of forward guidance. And the Federal Reserve’s current eagerness to tighten monetary policy without any visible signals of an overheating high pressure economy is greatly undermining its ability to credibly engage in forward guidance in the future:

Lawrence Summers: The Fed’s Complacency About Its Current Toolbox Is Unwarranted:

I was disappointed in what came out of Jackson Hole for three reasons…

The Fed should have signaled a desire to exceed its two percent inflation target during periods of protracted recovery and low unemployment…. Even apart from the desirability of allowing inflation to rise above two percent in a happy economic scenario GDP, labor market and inflation expectations data all make a compelling case against a rate increase….

My second reason for disappointment… was that Chair Yellen… was too complacent to conclude that:

even if average interest rates remain lower than in the past, I believe that monetary policy will, under most conditions, be able to respond effectively.

This statement may rank with Ben Bernanke’s unfortunate observation that subprime problems would be easily contained. Rather I believe that countering the next recession is the major monetary policy challenge before the Fed…. It is more than 50 percent likely that we will have a recession in the next 3 years. Countering recessions requires 400 or 500 basis points of monetary easing. We are very unlikely to have anything like that much room for easing when the next recession comes.

Chair Yellen, relying… on… David Reifschneider using the FRBUS model, comes to the relatively serene conclusion that by using forward guidance and QE… the Fed will likely able to respond adequately to the next recession with its existing tool kit.  I think this conclusion is unlikely to be right…. There is an important methodological point here: distrust conclusions reached primarily on the basis of model results.  Models are estimated or parameterized on the basis of historical data.  They can be expected to go wrong whenever the world changes in important ways.  Alan Greenspan was importantly right when he ignored models and maintained easy policy in the mid 1990s because of other more anecdotal evidence that convinced him that productivity growth had accelerated. I believe a similar skeptical attitude towards model results is appropriate today….

I wonder what credibility Fed forward guidance is likely to have given the utter disconnect over many years between Fed and market views regarding future rate and the track record so far of the Fed being wrong and the market being right…. Even if unconventional policy could be highly efficacious in moving long term rates and even if QE induced moves in long rates were potent, there is the question of how much room there is to bring down long rates. Reifschneider… shows that with a big recession rates would likely approach -6 percent, or even -9 percent, but for the zero lower bound.  I find the idea that forward guidance and QE could do the anything like the work of 600, let alone 900, basis points of rate cutting close to absurd…

Brookings Productivity Festival on Friday

Real Gross Domestic Product FRED St Louis Fed

The current discussion of “slow growth in measured productivity” here in the U.S. seems to suffer from a great deal of confusion. From my perspective, there are six things going on:

  1. Since the 1920s, the rise of non-Smithian information goods…
  2. Since 1973, the productivity slowdown…
  3. Since 1995, the semiconductor-driven infotech speedup…
  4. Since 2004, Moore’s Law hitting the wall…
  5. Since 2008, what we will soon be calling “The Longer Depression”…
  6. And, remember, policy changes to speed productivity growth may well be nearly orthogonal to all of the above save (5)…

To talk about the cause of “slow growth in measured productivity” as if it is just one, not five, things causes confusion. To identify one or a small number of causes of a single thing that is “slow growth in measured productivity” causes great confusion. And then to insist that the best policy move is to undo that one or small number of thing causes even greater confusion…

The productivity puzzle: How can we speed up the growth of the economy? Friday, September 9, 2016, 9:30 – 11:00 am, Falk Auditorium: The Brookings Institution:

After nearly a decade of strong productivity growth starting in the mid-1990s, productivity growth has slowed down over the most recent decade. Output per hour worked in the U.S. business sector has grown at only 1.3 percent per year from 2004 to 2015, and growth was even slower from 2010 to 2015 at just 0.5 percent a year. These rates are only half or less of the pace of growth achieved in the past.

The United States is not alone in facing this problem, as all of the major advanced economies have also seen slow productivity growth. This slow growth has been a major cause of weak overall GDP growth, stagnation in real wages and household incomes, and it strongly impacts government revenues and the deficit.

On September 9, 2016 the Initiative on Business and Public Policy and the Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy at Brookings will host a forum on the policy implications of the growth slowdown. Senior Fellow Martin Baily will present an overview paper on the causes of the slowdown, followed by a panel discussion on the most effective policies to enhance productivity performance. After the panel discussion, panelists will take questions from the audience. The event will be webcast live.

Join the conversation on Twitter at #Productivity

Welcome: Louise Seiner

Paper: Martin Baily

Panel: Moderator: David Wessel

  • Jonathan Baker
  • Robert Barro
  • J. Bradford DeLong
  • Bronwyn Hall