Must-Read: Nick Bunker: How Intensely are U.S. Employers Looking for Workers?

Must-Read: Nick Bunker: How Intensely are U.S. Employers Looking for Workers?:

How intensely are U S employers looking for workers Equitable Growth

Recruitment intensity might have something to do with the overall health of the labor market….

Intensity drops during recessions and starts to move upward as the economy heals…. Think of it this way: If there are a lot more unemployed workers per job than companies are trying to fill then firms don’t have to work that hard to find good talent. But as the labor market improves, employers have to work harder to fill positions. This increasing desire to recruit workers amid improving economic conditions also leads to companies poaching workers from other firms. Hiring workers from other firms is how the job ladder works…. It’s another way to think about how a tight labor market and why periods of full employment can boost wage growth for workers. Making employers put a little bit more effort into finding workers might not be a bad thing.

Must-Read: JEC: Houdini’s Straightjacket

Must-Read: JEC: Houdini’s Straightjacket:

Escape artistry… probably wouldn’t be anyone’s first choice as a model for the conduct of social science.  Yet, bizarrely, it has become the prevailing paradigm in macroeconomics….

How so? Consider the macroeconomist.  She constructs a rigorously micro-founded model, grounded purely in representative agents solving intertemporal dynamic optimization problems in a context of strict rational expectations.  Then, in a dazzling display of mathematical sophistication, theoretical acuity, and showmanship (some things never change), she derives results and policy implications that are exactly what the IS-LM model has been telling us all along. Crowd–such as it is–goes wild. And let’s be clear:  not even the most enthusiastic players of the macroeconomics game imagine that representative agents or rational expectations are, in any sense, empirical realities. They are conventions, “rules of the game”…. arbitrary difficulties we impose on ourselves in order to demonstrate our superior cleverness in being able to escape them. They are, in a word, Houdini’s straightjacket….

[This] modelling approach made arriving at sound policy recommendations unnecessarily difficult. For example, George Evans at the University of Oregon writes:

[T]he profession as a whole seemed to many of us slow to appreciate the implications of the NK model for policy during and following the financial crisis… because many macro economists using NK models in 2007-8 did not fully appreciate the Keynesian mechanisms present in the model.

Now, if after thirty years of study economists failed to “fully appreciate the Keynesian mechanisms present in the model,” one might wonder exactly what such models have to recommend themselves. What is the advantage of an intellectually demanding and mathematically complex modelling approach that makes it harder to actually get the job done? The answer, I suspect, is that “intellectually demanding and mathematically complex” has become an end in itself…. Which is fine as long as the goal is entertainment…

Who pays U.S. taxes on inheritances?

This photo shows the Internal Revenue Service headquarters building in Washington.

Greg Mankiw, a Harvard University economist and Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers for President George W. Bush, argues in a piece for The Upshot of the New York Times that the U.S. estate tax is a suboptimal way to tax wealth. Mankiw’s concern is that the tax violates “horizontal equity” by placing a similar tax burden on people who behave in very different ways. He presents an example of two couples, both of whom sell a family business for the same amount, but one couple spends all their proceeds and the other saves most of it to give to their children. Under the current federal tax system, both couples would end up paying the same amount of taxes, according to Mankiw, even though they ended up doing wildly different things with the money.

This example, however, assumes that the frugal couple who bequest their savings to their children end up paying the estate tax. If that were true, then the estate tax should be a larger part of a more effective tax system as the behavior impact of taxation on dead people is likely to be very small. But as Matt Levine at Bloomberg View points out, “We could fund the government with a lovely, efficient, non-distortionary system of taxing only the dead, except—and this is another key point—the dead don’t have any money.” The tax ends up getting paid by the heirs of the estate. Of course, the estate tax will influence how a person sets up their estate before they die, but the incidence of the tax will fall on those who end up receiving it.

This is why it might make sense to change the focus of taxes on inheritance from the estate to the heirs. Right now, an estate is taxed based the amount of money in the estate, regardless of how many heirs there are to the trust. But there are proposals to change the taxes on pass-down wealth so that the tax becomes an inheritance tax. In other words, the tax would be on the size of the wealth transfer a person receives and the tax rate would be decided by the person’s income bracket. Such a proposal comes from Lily Batchelder, of the New York University School of Law. This change would make clear who is really being taxed, shifting the burden onto high-income households that are inheriting large amounts. And, because it considers the economic status of the individual (or individuals) inheriting the estate, it also means that it could end up reducing the tax burden for lower-income households with larger inheritances (though this may not be a large group).

Mankiw’s example also assumes that the assets that lead to the wealth being passed along will be sold and taxed before death. But that’s often not the case, which leads to a good amount of inherited wealth not being taxed. Assume (as Mankiw does) that two couples who run small businesses are about to retire and sell their companies. The first couple, the Smiths, sell the company, pay the taxes on the gains from the increased value of the company, and pass along the proceeds to their heirs.

The second couple, the Jones, tragically die before they can sell the company and ownership passes to their heirs. Their heirs eventually sell the company, but the taxes they pay are only on the gains from when they get the company—not from when their parents founded the firm. The income created from the appreciation of the company before it gets passed on never gets taxed. This “stepped up basis” (in tax parlance) seems like a reform that could be made to the estate tax as well.

The current system for taxing capital in the United States could use quite a bit of changes, but the idea that inheritances shouldn’t be taxed due to concerns about horizontal equity seems strange. A concern for equity might suggest that policymakers change the form of certain wealth taxes, but not their wholesale elimination.

Must-Read: Larry Summers: Building the Case for Greater Infrastructure Investment

Must-Read: Note that the case for greater infrastructure investment is close to orthogonal to the case for bigger government deficits ending in a larger target national debt, and that both are together each close to orthogonal to the case for larger swings in the government’s fiscal balance–bigger surpluses in times of boom to create the fiscal space so that you can run bigger and more stimulative deficits in times of recession. Larry is here making a case that I believe is intellectually irresistible for the first only. But the cases for the second and third are, I believe, intellectually irresistible as well:

Larry Summers: Building the Case for Greater Infrastructure Investment:

The issue now is not whether the US should invest more but what the policy framework should be

There is a consensus that the US should substantially raise its level of infrastructure investment… [to] can create quality jobs… provide economic stimulus without posing the risks of easy-money policies… expand the economy’s capacity… and mitigate the huge maintenance burden we would otherwise pass on to the next generation. The case for infrastructure investment has been strong for a long time, but it gets stronger with each passing year, as government borrowing costs decline and ongoing neglect raises the return on incremental spending…. Just as the infrastructure failure at Chernobyl was a sign of malaise in the Soviet Union’s last years, profound questions about America’s future are raised by collapsing bridges, children losing IQ points because of lead in water and an air traffic control system that does not use GPS technology. The issue now is… what the policy framework should be. There are five key questions:

[1] How much more do we need to invest?… [2] What is the highest priority?… [3] How should investment be financed?… [4] What about the private sector?… [5] How can we be sure investment is carried out efficiently?… Every year that we allow our infrastructure to decay raises the burden that our generation places on the next. We will not always be able to borrow for the long term at a near zero interest rate. However the election turns out, a major infrastructure investment programme should be adopted by the president and Congress in the spring of 2017.

Thus (3) really does not belong on this list–it is a separate question. But (1), (2), (4), (5)–how much? what? how to harness private-sector initiative? and how to maintain efficiency?–are things that even moderate quality political reporters should be asking and reasking candidates for president and for other offices–federal, state, and local–this fall.

I’m not holding my breath. Our country’s political reporters are, by and large, uninterested in public policy and unconcerned with informing voters–who are interested in public policies and their effects. And they aren’t even very guide at covering the election-as-contest: as if they were horse-race reporters who knew nothing about the key fundamentals of bloodlines, jockeys, and tracks.

Must-Read: Lael Brainard: The “New Normal” and What It Means for Monetary Policy

Must-Read: Now can somebody please tell me why this is a minority and not the consensus view of the FOMC?:

Lael Brainard: The “New Normal” and What It Means for Monetary Policy:

Several features of the “new normal”… appear particularly noteworthy for our policy deliberations:

(1) Inflation Has Been Undershooting, and the Phillips Curve Has Flattened…. (2) Labor Market Slack Has Been Greater than Anticipated…. (3) Foreign Markets Matter, Especially because Financial Transmission is Strong…. (4) The Neutral Rate Is Likely to Remain Very Low for Some Time…. (5) Policy Options Are Asymmetric…. From a risk-management perspective, therefore, the asymmetry in the conventional policy toolkit would lead me to expect policy to be tilted somewhat in favor of guarding against downside risks relative to preemptively raising rates to guard against upside risks…. It will be important to assess whether our current policy tools are adequate to respond to negative shocks and, if not, what adjustments would be most appropriate…. For the time being, the most effective way to address these concerns is to ensure that our policy actions align with our commitment to achieving the existing inflation target, which the Committee has recently clarified is symmetric around 2 percent–and not a ceiling–along with maximum employment…

Must-Read: Victor Gay, Daniel Hicks and Estefania Santacreu-Vasut: Languages and Gender Norms

Must-Read: Victor Gay, Daniel Hicks and Estefania Santacreu-Vasut: [Languages and Gender Norms[]:

Forms of gender inequality are higher in countries where the language distinguishes gender…

…But these patterns could arise spuriously, as languages and other cultural institutions have co-evolved…. An epidemiological approach to isolate language from other cultural forces… provide[s] direct evidence on whether language matters… how gender roles have been shaped, how they are perpetuated, and, ultimately, how they can be changed.

Must-Read: David Beckworth: Fed is Trapped in a Rate Hike Talk Cycle

Must-Read: Every member of the FOMC needs to read this carefully, and either agree with it or lay out an analytical case for why David Beckworth is wrong:

David Beckworth: The Fed is Trapped in a Rate Hike Talk Cycle:

Since mid-2014 the Fed has been talking up interest rate hikes… but only has a 25 basis point rate increase to show for it….

The Fed’s plans… bump up against unexpected economic developments… in a cycle that goes as follows: the Fed talks up interest rate hikes → bad economic news emerges → the Fed dials down its rate hike talk → good economic news emerges → repeat cycle….

Recall… this year. After the FOMC did its 25 basis point hike in December 2015, FOMC members were talking up four more rate hikes in 2016…. Concerns… about financial stress… dial back… incoming economic data was improving so… a rate hike at the June FOMC seemed possible. The rate hike rhetoric quickly changed, however, when the the awful May jobs report… Brexit….

Now the cycle is starting over. The gangbuster June employment report and strong retail sales… officials… increasingly “confident” they can raise rates in September…. It is almost inevitable, in my view, that this cycle will repeat…. First, much of the bad economic news that has caused the Fed to repeatedly dial back its rate hike talk has… been a byproduct of the rate hike rhetoric itself. Whenever the Fed talks up rate hikes it also talking up the value of the dollar which, in turn, creates a drag… because a large swath of the global economy has its currency linked to the dollar and because there is almost $10 trillion in dollar denominated debt issued outside the United States….

The second reason is that the Fed’s desire to raise interest rates is pushing up against the Tsunami forces behind the global race to the bottom of safe asset yields…. This downward march of interest rates has occurred prior to and after QE programs… is the result of far bigger global market forces…. As Tim Duy notes, the Fed is fighting against this force and is unlikely to win…. Interest rates are being suppressed by market forces despite the Fed’s best efforts. The Fed will not be able to raise interest rates this year and maybe even next year.

Now the Fed could still force up its target interest rate temporarily. But it would learn the hard way what the Riksbank in 2010 and the ECB in 2011 learned: getting ahead of the recovery and market forces will only make matters worse. In the case of the ECB… another recession for the Eurozone. Ultimately, interest rates cannot be exogenously pushed up. They have to be endogenously pulled up by a healthy economy. Until this happens, the Fed is trapped in a self-defeating rate hike talk cycle.

Must-Read: Ben Thompson: Beyond the iPhone

Ben Thompson: Beyond the iPhone:

At first glance, as Manjoo noted, the iPhone 7… is mostly the same as the two-year-old iPhone 6….

Probably. I have been and remain relatively pessimistic about this iPhone cycle. However, I was actually very impressed by what Apple introduced… laid the foundation for both future iPhone features and, more importantly, a future beyond the iPhone…. The annual camera upgrade is always one of the best reasons to upgrade…. Bokeh, though, is only the tip of the iceberg: what Apple didn’t say was that they may be releasing the first mass-market virtual reality camera…. Apple hasn’t released a headset… but when and if they do, the ecosystem will already have been primed, and you can bet FaceTime VR would be an iPhone seller. Apple’s willingness and patience to lay the groundwork for new features over multiple generations remains one of its most impressive qualities. Apple Pay, for example….

Apple executives told BuzzFeed that removing the headphone jack made it possible to bring that image stabilization to the smaller iPhone 7, gave room for a bigger battery, and eliminated a trouble-spot when it came to making the iPhone 7 water-resistant. It’s a solid argument, albeit one not quite worth Schiller’s hubris. That said… Apple’s vision… is such a big deal for Apple in particular that I just might be willing to give Schiller a pass…. Putting aside the possibility of losing the AirPods… it really looks like Apple is on to something compelling. By ladling a bit of “special sauce” on top of the Bluetooth protocol, Apple has made the painful process of pairing as simple as pushing a button. Even more impressive is that said pairing information immediately propagates…. I can absolutely vouch for Apple’s insistence that there is a better way than wires, and the innovations introduced by the AirPod (which are also coming to Beats) help the headphone jack medicine go down just a bit more easily.

What is most intriguing, though, is that “truly wireless future”…. To Apple’s credit they are, with the creation of AirPods, laying the foundation for a world beyond the iPhone… a world that Apple, thanks to said product expertise, especially when it comes to chips, is uniquely equipped to create. That the company is running towards it is both wise–the sooner they get there, the longer they have to iterate and improve and hold off competitors–and also, yes, courageous. The easy thing would be to fight to keep us in a world where phones are all that matters, even if, in the long run, that would only defer the end of Apple’s dominance.

Must-Read: Nick Rowe: Money Stocks and Flows

Must-Read: Diligently and industriously study the Thought of Nick Rowe to understand the qualitative microfoundations of recessions in a monetary economy!

There can be excess demand for all kinds of things–kumquats, Mona Lisas, experiences of the ineffable, savings vehicles, stocks of safe assets, cash–*but unless the excess demand spills over into an excess demand for cash there will not be a recession. The difference between an excess demand for Mona Lisas or kumquats on the one hand and an excess demand for savings vehicles and safe assets on the other is that cash can be–and in some recessions is–pressed into service as a savings vehicle or a safe asset, and thus the initial excess demand propagates itself into an excess demand for cash:

Nick Rowe: Money Stocks and Flows:

Those… differences between money and all other assets means that it is misleading to think of the demand for money, like the demand for other assets, in terms of portfolio choice….

Money is not just a medium of account…. Money is the medium of exchange, which means it flows around the economy whenever anything else is traded…. It matters a lot whether individuals want to save in the form of money or want to save any other non-money asset. If individuals want to save in the form of land, they won’t collectively be able to if the stock of land does not increase. There will be an excess demand for land in the land market, if the price of land does not rise to dissuade that desire to save. There is nothing an individual can do if he wants to buy more land but nobody else wants to sell.

If individuals want to save in the form of money, they won’t collectively be able to if the stock of money does not increase. There will be an excess demand for money in all the money markets, except those where the price of the non-money thing traded in that market is flexible and adjusts to clear that market. In the sticky-price markets there will be nothing an individual can do if he wants to buy more money but nobody else wants to sell more. But… any individual can always sell less money…. Nobody can stop you selling less money…. Unable to increase the flow of money into their portfolios, each individual reduces the flow of money out of his portfolio. Demand falls in sticky-price markets, quantity traded is determined by the short side of the market (Q=min{Qd,Qs}), so trade falls, and some trades that would be mutually advantageous in a barter or Walsrasian economy even at those sticky prices don’t get made, and there’s a recession…. There’s now a stock-flow consistency, of sorts. But it’s a rather ugly one. We call it a recession.

Must-Read: Duncan Black: Mismatch

Must-Read: Duncan Black: Mismatch:

One of the phenomenon studied due to the suburbanization of employment was spatial mismatch…

…that there was a mismatch between where people lived and where jobs they were qualified to get were located. Roughly, for various reasons, less educated people lived in cities, without cars, and the jobs they would be able to get were in the suburbs, requiring either a car they didn’t have or a nightmarish public transit commute to places with horrible public transit.(It was more complicated than this, of course, with enforced residential segregation and other types of racial discrimination having a large impact on location patterns).

As poverty moves to the suburbs, people are going to be in worst-of-both-worlds territory. They’ll need a car for jobs, and for everything else, and cars are expensive things. And while there is no secret welfare system, it is the case that there are often more readily available social services and similar support systems – private and public – in some urban areas.