Monetary policy via income redistribution

Customers wait in line to make their purchases at Walmart in Arkansas.

Traditionally, central bankers haven’t considered income and wealth inequality much when they conduct monetary policy. Perhaps some of them think about the impact of monetary policy on the levels of economic inequality, but inequality as a factor affecting the impact of monetary policy isn’t something most of them ever discuss. Recently, however, researchers are beginning to give central bankers better points of reference by looking at how inequality and heterogeneity among households affects the transmission of monetary policy.

Adding to this line of analysis is a new paper that finds part of the way monetary policy increases consumption is by redistributing income among households. That paper, by Stanford University economist Adrien Auclert—based on part of his dissertation—shows how the redistribution of income and wealth play a role in monetary policy. Specifically, he finds that the simulative effect of monetary policy is amplified when it shifts income toward individuals who are more likely to spend it. Auclert’s paper adds three new possible policy transmission channels to the traditional set that central bankers consider, including the substitution effect (where lower interest rates increase consumption today) and the aggregate income effect (where higher incomes lead to more consumption).

The key to the effectiveness of the three new channels, Auclert argues, is that they interact with the variation in the marginal propensity to consume. The spending habits of households and individuals vary, as some will immediately spend an additional dollar of income while others will save it. The larger a person’s marginal propensity to consume, the more that individual will spend of the additional dollar he or she receives. Auclert identifies three ways that monetary policy can shift money away from individuals with low marginal propensities to consume and toward those with high propensities to consume.

The first channel is the earnings heterogeneity channel. The relevant inequality here is inequality of income, as the marginal propensity to consume tends to decrease as incomes increase. In other words, individuals with low incomes are more likely to spend another dollar of income. Monetary policy boosts consumption through this channel if, in boosting total income, it pushes income more toward lower-income individuals. This channel seems plausible given research on the effect of monetary policy on income inequality.

The second channel deals with inequality of wealth and debt. This so-called Fisher effect—named after the economist Irving Fisher—works through high inflation shifting income away from net asset holders and toward net debtors. An unexpectedly higher inflation rate, for example, reduces the amount of money debtors have to pay back to creditors. The value of debt declines, and debtors have more money to potentially spend. And as debtors have a higher marginal propensity to consumer than creditors, this shift of income helps boost consumption.

The redistribution work in the third channel identified by Auclert is related to the amount of exposure to changes in inflation-adjusted interest rates. This channel also involves inequality in asset ownership but focuses more on the timing of when individuals receive income from assets and when they have to pay off liabilities. At a given point in time, the more income a person has coming in from assets relative to their liabilities, the more a decrease in inflation-adjusted interest rates would reduce their income, which would be redistributed toward people with more money due to liabilities at that time. Think of homeowners with adjustable rate mortgages. A reduction in inflation-adjusted interest rates reduces the amount of money they need to pay toward that liability (their mortgages) at that moment. These homeowners and other individuals with liabilities to pay off soon have a higher marginal propensity to consume, on average, and a redistribution toward them would result in a boost to consumption.

Combining these three redistribution channels, Auclert finds that shifting incomes among households and individuals may be about as important to boosting total consumption as the well-known substitution effect. If that’s true, then it certainly would put a new spin on how researchers and policymakers think about what factors, including inequality, are going to make monetary policy more effective. Auclert says that his work is “very much a first pass.” Given the potential implications of this research, other passes as this line of research would be welcome.

Simon Wren-Lewis: GE2017 and the Stages of Leaver Grief

Should-Read: Simon Wren-Lewis: GE2017 and the Stages of Leaver Grief: “The EU knows that No Deal would be a disaster for the UK… https://mainlymacro.blogspot.com/2017/06/the-stages-of-leaver-grief.html

…Their overriding objective is to ensure the UK will be worse off under Brexit, not as some punishment but to ensure EU survival. Given that No Deal will be so much worse for the UK than the EU, and as the clock is already ticking, the EU are in a position where they can pretty well dictate terms. To the extent that this is a game, we lost it the moment Article 50 was triggered. The EU negotiations are still very important, but for the UK it is more a matter of making choices rather than extracting concessions. There are many kinds of Brexit. In thinking about who would be the best negotiator for the UK, the most important question to ask is who would make the right choices. Theresa May, by focusing so much on immigration and the European court, has already made two very bad decisions. She seems to be rather good at bad decisions. Personal qualities matter to a lesser extent, but success involves empathy and trust, not obstinacy. Unfortunately much of the country is still lost to the fiction that the negotiations are a battle of wills where the UK can emerge victorious if it is stubborn enough…

Hoisted from Ten Years Ago: Back When I Was Much More Optimistic About New Media and the Public Sphere…

Hoisted from June 4, 2007: Neil Henry vs. Jay Rosen Future-of-Journalism Smackdown! http://www.bradford-delong.com/2007/06/neil_henry_vs_j_1.html: “Excuse me, I need to worship my idol a bit more… There… That’s better…

Karl Marx said somewhere that the hand-loom gives you the feudal lord and the power-loom gives you the industrial capitalist. So in 1884 Ottmar Mergenthaler gave us the traditional American twentieth-century newspaper journalism of Charles Foster Kane (and the broadcast TV spectrum allocation gave us Edward R. Murrow and Walter Cronkhite). The Mergenthaler gives you the power to deliver advertisements–classified advertisements, department store advertisements, movie advertisements, new car advertisements–to every household metro-wide for pennies.

But how do you get people to read the advertisements rather than simply throw them away or use them, unread, for birdcage liner? You mix the advertisements with news, and reviews, and sports, and opinion, and entertainment. You make the twentieth-century American newspaper.

Because the ads that are mixed with the best news (and reviews, and sports, and opinion, and entertainment) get read the most, there is pressure on the then new-media moguls–because daily newspapers were once new media in their day–to employ lots of good people and to pay them well.

Over time the business consolidates: papers fold or find their niches, and establish stable competitive positions. Now there are monopoly profits to be distributed–and some of them go to the people who write the news (and reviews, and sports, and opinion, and entertainment). Now there is often an owner who is a big wheel in at least local politics and celebrity, and is willing to pay some out of his pocket to buy a better newspaper to increase his relative status vis-a-vis his or her other power-elite peers. It is a golden age. And, indeed the public sphere, the civic discourse, the informed citizenry created by journalism is well worth its price in terms of the subsidy from advertising profits that high-quality journalism needs.

But without sufficient competition, people and organizations get lazy. William Greider has his off-the-record breakfasts with Reaganite OMB Director David Stockman, who tells Greider that the Reagan administration is lying through all thirty-two of its teeth. William Greider doesn’t tell the reporters working for him “you can sharpen that criticism of the administration and it will still be accurate” or “that defense of the administration is substantively misleading” or “you’ve buried the lead.”

And he’s not alone: think of Clay Chandler or Jonathan Weisman or Sebastian Mallaby or Deborah Howell. All Washington Post reporters with temporary monopolies who have forgotten that their job is to inform their readers, and instead have fallen on their knees before their sources, their editors, their bosses, or the flacks leaving message after message on their answering machines.

And then, one day, the Mergenthaler’s descendants are obsolete, and the necessary link between the ads and the news (and reviews, and sports, and opinion, and entertainment) delivered via the morning paper vanishes. And the pool of money that had subsidized the news dries up.

And then (to be continued)…

Should-Read: Reuters: Fed’s Harker Still Sees Two More Interest Rate Hikes in 2017

Should-Read: This is one of the iron laws of bureaucracy: Whenever an incumbent in an office appoints a chair of the search committee who then winds up getting the job, something has gone badly wrong—the process has been rigged to flatter the outgoing occupant, rather than to choose an appropriate successor.

In the first four months of 2017 the monthly changes in the core PCE chain inflation index have added up to 0.52%-points: an average of 0.13%-point per month.

If all twelve months of 2017 are to add up to the 2%/year core PCE chain inflation that is the Federal Reserve’s target, the remaining eight months of 2017 need to average 0.19%-points.

That’s average over the next eight months—not kiss once or twice.

The economic world is a surprising place: it could happen. But I see nothing in the data or in any underlying economic relationships—no chain of logical reasoning—that would lead anybody to truthfully say that they anticipate that 0.19%-point will be the average monthly PCE core chain inflation rate reported over the next eight monthly releases.

Personal Consumption Expenditures Excluding Food and Energy Chain Type Price Index FRED St Louis Fed

Yet that is what Philadelphia Fed President Patrick Parker is currently claiming:

Reuters: Fed’s Harker Still Sees Two More Interest Rate Hikes in 2017: “Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank President Patrick Harker said on Friday that the U.S. central bank remains on track… https://www.nytimes.com/reuters/2017/06/02/business/02reuters-usa-fed-harker.html

…to meet its inflation goal… reiterated his support for a further two interest rate increases this year. “Turning to inflation, things are still on track, despite a couple of months trending in the wrong direction,” Harker said… add[ing] that he still forecasts inflation reaching the Fed’s 2 percent target around the end of this year…

Is this professional? Is this arithmetic?

Must-Read: Luciano Floridi: A fallacy that will hinder advances in artificial intelligence

Must-Read: There are many inconsistent and wildly different definitions of “artificial intelligence”. Here are two useful ones:

  • Building systems that humans can easily and successful interact with by acting as if they are a human-level intelligence (within their domain).
  • Building systems that behave in ways “that would be called ‘intelligent’ if a human were so behaving.”

Luciano Floridi says smart things about the second:

Luciano Floridi: A fallacy that will hinder advances in artificial intelligence: “The best definition of AI was written in 1955 by US computer scientist John McCarthy and colleagues… https://www.ft.com/content/ee996846-4626-11e7-8d27-59b4dd6296b8

….The problem, they wrote, “is taken to be that of making a machine behave in ways that would be called intelligent if a human were so behaving”…. The definition does not say the artificial agent is intelligent, but that a human would have to be to achieve the same goal…. The whole and only point is to perform a task such that the outcome is as good as, or better than, what human intelligence would have been able to achieve. “How” is not in question, only the outcome. This is why AI is not about reproducing but replacing human intelligence. A dishwasher does not clean the dishes as I do. But in the end its clean dishes are indistinguishable from mine—indeed, they may be cleaner…. AI is the continuation of intelligence by other means…

Must- and Should-Reads: June 2, 2017


Interesting Reads:

Should-Read: Ben Thompson: Blue Apron Files for IPO, Network Effects and Customer Acquisition Costs, Uber Concerns

Should-Read: Ben Thompson: Blue Apron Files for IPO, Network Effects and Customer Acquisition Costs, Uber Concerns: “I did find this bit in The Information article interesting… https://stratechery.com/2017/blue-apron-files-for-ipo-network-effects-and-customer-acquisition-costs-uber-concerns/

…In fact, smaller rivals like Lyft can spend a lot less money per ride in order to attract enough drivers to serve the company’s customers. That’s because it needs only a fraction of the number of drivers that Uber does, and it can get by with more part-time drivers versus Uber, which needs as many full-time drivers as possible to meet its customers’ demand.

Part-time drivers are the marginal supply I was referring to above, and Lyft reported last year that 82% of its drivers work fewer than 20 hours a week; it’s possible that it is these part-time drivers, exposed to Uber’s relentless rate cuts but ineligible for its high-volume bonuses, are what has kept Lyft (which generally monetizes better on a per-ride basis, in part because of tips) alive. If so—and again, there is very thin information here—that would be for Uber a truly large penalty for a lack of financial controls and properly calculated unit economics…

Should-Read: Pseudoreasmus: The Cold War Triumph of Liberal Capitalism—in Hindsight

Should-Read: Not just in hindsight! The point of my citing to George Kennan’s 1946 “Long Telegram”—published in 1947 in Foreign Affairs as “The Sources of Soviet Conduct”—was to stress that what you, Pseudoerasmus, whoever you are, call the retrospective assessment was Kennan’s prospective hope as well.

Kennan wanted containment, not rollback. Kennan wanted to move the conflict to the political economic-ideological level: which system better delivered on Enlightenment values of prosperity, security, freedom? He was confident that, if moving the conflict to that level could be accomplished, the U.S., the western alliance, liberal democratic capitalism would win if it deserved to win. And he was confident it deserved to win.

Curiously, N.S. Khrushchev—at least in his saner moments—wanted the same thing: he, too, sought to move the conflict to the political economic-ideological level: which system better delivered on Enlightenment values of prosperity, security, freedom? He was confident that, if moving the conflict to that level could be accomplished, Soviet communism would win if it deserved to win. And he was confident it deserved to win. “We will have to be the ones making your funeral arrangements…”

Khrushchev was wrong. But he was a believer…

Pseudoreasmus: The Cold War Triumph of Liberal Capitalism—in Hindsight https://medium.com/@pseudoerasmus/if-we-ask-the-retrospective-question-why-did-western-liberal-capitalism-actually-triumph-then-e025706801e0: “The tête-à-tête Soviet-American global struggle over the Third World…

…the support of comprador dictators, the interference in elections, the military coups that installed friendly tyrants, the interminable proxy civil wars in, etc.—these were sideshows. The Ogaden War; FRELIMO; Cuban troops in Angola; Vietnam; the 1964 coup in Brazil; the Algerian revolution; Yemen!!!, Nicaragua, Afghanistan!, Malaya!!!, Polisario!!!, the Indo-Pakistan wars, Allende, even the Greek civil war, the mass murder of hundreds of thousands of PKI by Suharto, etc.—all grand irrelevances…. If the Cold War in the Third World did matter in some way, it was by inducing the Soviet Union to allocate more of its resources to silly adventurism…. The true “Fukuyama vulgarism”… is not the triumphalism of liberal capitalism, which seems bloody obvious. It’s the utopian expectation that the Rest of the World would and could adopt the model.

Weekend reading: “Unstable incomes, uncertain world” edition

This is a weekly post we publish on Fridays with links to articles that touch on economic inequality and growth. The first section is a round-up of what Equitable Growth published this week and the second is the work we’re highlighting from elsewhere. We won’t be the first to share these articles, but we hope by taking a look back at the whole week, we can put them in context.

Equitable Growth round-up

Several central banks implemented previously unthinkable monetary policies during the Great Recession. How many of these tools will stick around? A new paper asks central bankers and academics just that question.

Bridget Ansel writes about a new study that uncovers a surprising performance enhancer for venture capital funds: hiring partners who have daughters.

New data on the U.S. labor market was released this morning from the U.S. Department of Labor in the form of the May Employment Situation Report. Check out five key graphs using data from the report.

Links from around the web

One part of President Trump’s proposed tax reform is a tax cut for pass-through business income. His administration is pitching it as a tax cut for small business, but Lily Batchelder of New York University Law School argues it’ll become a huge tax loophole.  [nyt]

Is the German trade surplus with the United States an issue? Unlikely. But is the German trade surplus with the rest of the world a problem for the global economy? Adam Davidson argues that it is. [new yorker]

“Conversations about inequality often miss something essential, something that the families we met felt strongly: The financial problem they were most immediately focused on wasn’t about relative earnings or wealth. It was about their ability to create stable lives in our uncertain world.” Jonathan Morduch and Rachel Schneider write about their study of income volatility. [atlantic]

As behavioral economics incorporated insights from psychology into economics, a new line of thinking from Nobel Laureate and Yale University economist Robert Shiller called narrative economics takes insights from the humanities. [chicago booth]

In an interview with the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, University of California, Berkeley economist Hilary Hoynes talks about food stamps, the recessionary effects on labor market segments, and the importance of poverty research. [minneapolis fed]

Friday figure

Figure from “Equitable Growth’s Jobs Day Graphs: May 2017 Report Edition” by Equitable Growth

The Truth Behind Today’s US Inflation Numbers

Live at Project Syndicate: The Truth Behind Today’s US Inflation Numbers https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/fed-low-inflation-more-stimulus-by-j–bradford-delong-2017-06: BERKELEY – In December 2015, the US Federal Reserve embarked on a monetary-tightening cycle, by raising the target range for the short-term nominal federal funds rate by 25 basis points (one-quarter of a percentage point). At the time, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)–the Fed body that sets monetary policy–issued a median forecast predicting three things… Read MOAR at Project Syndicate