Should-Read: Martin Wolf: Economics failed us before the global crisis

Should-Read: Martin Wolf: Economics failed us before the global crisis: “Macroeconomics… invented by John Maynard Keynes…. The tests… are whether its adepts understand what might go wrong in the economy and how to put it right…

…When the financial crisis that hit in 2007 caught the profession almost completely unawares, it failed the first of these tests. It did better on the second. Nevertheless, it needs rebuilding…. The core macroeconomic model rested on two critical assumptions: the efficient markets hypothesis and rational expectations. Neither looks convincing…. It is questionable whether it is even possible to have “rational expectations” of a profoundly uncertain future…. Hyman Minsky’s view of the dangers of speculative tendencies in finance was roughly right, while many of the brightest macroeconomists proved precisely wrong. It is not good enough to argue that the canonical model works in normal times. We need also to understand the risks of crises and what to do about them….

A big question is not only whether we know how to respond to a crisis, but whether we did so. In his contribution, the Nobel laureate Paul Krugman argues, to my mind persuasively, that the basic Keynesian remedies—a strong fiscal and monetary response—remain right. Also vital is swift revitalisation of the banking system. The contrast between the swifter US recovery and the dreadful delays in the eurozone gives striking support for this view….

Fixing a huge crisis after the event is terribly hard. The obvious need then is to make economies more resilient…. Obvious solutions include eliminating the incentives towards leverage in our tax systems, encouraging greater use by the economy of equity finance and debt that can be readily converted into equity, raising the reserve and capital requirements of banks and moving swiftly towards the issuance of digital central bank cash…. We may never understand how such complex systems—animated, as they are, by human desires and misunderstandings — actually function. This does not mean that attempting to improve understanding is a foolish exercise. On the contrary, it is important. But it is arguably more vital in practice to focus on two other tasks… how to make the body economic more resistant… how to restore it to health as quickly as possible. On both counts, we need to think more and do more…

Should-Read: Noah Smith: Why Money Managers Are Paid So Much Is a Mystery

Should-Read: Noah Smith: Why Money Managers Are Paid So Much Is a Mystery: “Mutual-fund managers are paid less for beating the market than for marketing—i.e., the ability to collect assets…

…This bolsters the notion of “money doctors”—the idea that managers mainly add value by building trust with investors. Investors are naturally wary about putting their money in stocks and other risky assets, and want a qualified professional to tell them it’s safe to do so. This could potentially be a win-win relationship; investors pay fees, but get higher returns than they would if they had stayed out of the market. Or it could be a potentially toxic relationship, if managers use personal or cultural affinity to sell investors on a bad deal. More research is needed in order to tell how many money doctors are really quacks. But the new research into fund-manager pay also shows that a large percentage of compensation remains unexplained, having apparently little to do with fund size or returns. There is a lot of money sloshing around in the financial industry, and much of how it gets divvied up remains a mystery…

Should-Read: Charlie Stross: Test Case – Charlie’s Diary

Should-Read: Charlie Stross: Test Case: “There are ramifications…

…The current legal framework privileges corporations over individuals with respect to moral hazard. So I’m going to stick my neck out and predict that there’s going to be a lot of lobbying money spent to ensure that this situation continues… and that in the radiant Randian libertarian future, all self-driving cars will be owned by limited liability shell companies…

Should-Read: Benjamin D. Sommers, Atul A. Gawande, and Katherine Baicker: Health Insurance Coverage and Health—What the Recent Evidence Tells Us

Should-Read: Benjamin D. Sommers, Atul A. Gawande, and Katherine Baicker: Health Insurance Coverage and Health—What the Recent Evidence Tells Us: “An analysis of mortality changes after Medicaid expansion suggests that expanding Medicaid saves lives at a societal cost of $327,000 to $867,000 per life saved…

…By comparison, other public policies that reduce mortality have been found to average $7.6 million per life saved, suggesting that expanding health insurance is a more cost-effective investment than many others we currently make in areas such as workplace safety and environmental protections.29,54 Factoring in enhanced well-being, mental health, and other outcomes would only further improve the cost–benefit ratio. But ultimately, policymakers and other stakeholders must decide how much they value these improvements in health, relative to other uses of public resources—from spending them on education and other social services to reducing taxes…

Should-Read: Lant Pritchett: Alleviating Global Poverty: Labor Mobility, Direct Assistance, and Economic Growth

Should-Read: Lant Pritchett: Alleviating Global Poverty: Labor Mobility, Direct Assistance, and Economic Growth: “A well-designed, well-implemented, multi-faceted intervention can in fact have an apparently sustained impact on the incomes of the poor (Banerjee et al 2015)…

…The magnitude of the income gains of the “best you can do” via direct interventions to raise the income of the poor in situ is about 40 times smaller than the income gain from allowing people from those same poor countries to work in a high productivity country like the USA. Simply allowing more labor mobility holds vastly more promise for reducing poverty than anything else on the development agenda. That said, the magnitude of the gains from large growth accelerations (and losses from large decelerations) are also many-fold larger than the potential gains from directed individual interventions and the poverty reduction gains from large, extended periods of rapid growth are larger than from targeted interventions and also hold promise (and have delivered) for reducing global poverty…

Should-Read: Simon Wren-Lewis: Beliefs about Brexit

Should-Read: Simon Wren-Lewis: Beliefs about Brexit: “I want to… ask why public opinion seems oblivious to the failures of all those claims before the negotiations that ‘we hold all the cards’ compared to the reality that the UK has largely agreed to the terms set out by the EU…

…The view of the overwhelming majority of economists, and all the analysis from serious academics, the OBR, IMF, OECD, and now even the government, is that leaving the EU will involve significant economic costs. Yet despite all this the poll above shows as many people think we will be better off leaving as think we will be worse off. This is the kind of polling that should stop everyone in their tracks, much like the polls before the US election that said more people trusted Donald Trump than Hillary Clinton. The result in this poll is all the more incredible because so far people are worse off as a result of Brexit….

I can think of two classes of explanation for this apparent paradox. The first is that people are fully aware of what experts and the government thinks, but ignore this…. If that is the line you want to take, then it has a clear implication. The implication is never hold a referendum on anything. It is not normally a good idea to take decisions where you ignore all expertise….

A second and much simpler explanation…. [How] do people who pay far less attention to economics and politics know this? How would they know this? They will know very little about it from reading the papers that campaigned so hard for Brexit in the first place…. This propaganda could be countered by informed and informing reporting by broadcasters. Unfortunately, with the exception of Sky News, the standard of reporting by broadcasters on Brexit has been very poor….

I missed the importance of the Irish border until September last year. I do not think I was unusual in this respect. I suspect I did so because I was influenced by the UK line that this issue was really a phase 2 problem, a line we heard over and over again on the MSM. What the MSM rarely did was ask what people in Irish Republic felt about the border, and hence why it got to be a first stage issue in the first place. Once I realised its importance, I could see that the Irish border issue would have a fundamental influence on any final deal…. But the BBC in particular seems unable to incorporate expert opinion, either directly or indirectly, into its coverage….

This is not the first time in recent memory that the media has failed to accurately report what was going on and what experts thought. Before the 2015 election the media accepted the idea that getting the budget deficit down was the most important goal of macroeconomic policy, and that the economic fundamentals were strong. Few experts would agree with the former, and the latter was simply false. What I call mediamacro swung the election for the Conservatives. The UK government wants a Brexit… not dictated by the referendum result but by the wishes of the Brexiters in the Conservative party. The only people who can stop this happening are other Conservative MPs, but many have said that these MPs will only be able to defy their government if public opinion swings against Brexit. But that is not going to happen…. People remain unaware of the overwhelming expert opinion that they will continue to become worse off after Brexit. That in turn represents another victory for right wing press propaganda, and another critical failure from most of our broadcast media…

Should-Read: Lawrence Summers: “A strong, fully employed economy

Should-Read: Lawrence Summers: “A strong, fully employed economy—where firms looking for workers is a larger issue than workers looking for firms…

….is the best social program we know. It is shortages of labor that induce firms to figure out how to train felons, to move beyond their traditional prejudices, to figure out how to skill unskilled workers, to reach into distressed or depressed communities…”

Should-Read: David Brady: We… would be delighted by… lift[ing] all single mothers out of poverty…. Making a substantial fraction of people not poor would reduce poverty. Duh

Should-Read: The Washington Post these days is a really bad neighborhood. Bad actors. Bad actions: David Brady: We… would be delighted by… lift[ing] all single mothers out of poverty…. Making a substantial fraction of people not poor would reduce poverty. Duh: “In @washingtonpost, Robert Samuelson has written a ‘critique’ of our NY Times piece…

…It isn’t clear he understands our arguments or whether his arguments actually contradict our arguments. His main grievance seems to be vaguely about what he says “the impression that the Times leaves its readers.” His biggest error is attributing to us: “eliminating poverty among single mothers wouldn’t have much effect on overall poverty.” Actually, we say eliminating single MOTHERHOOD–not single mother POVERTY–wouldn’t really reduce poverty…. Samuelson calculates what would happen if all single parent (not single mother) families were not (officially) poor. We simulate what would happen to overall poverty if all single mothers were not single mothers.

From a public policy perspective, we actually would be delighted by his suggestion to simply lift all single mothers out of poverty. We agree that making a substantial fraction of people not poor would reduce poverty. Duh. This is true for ANY random group of poor people.

He chastises us for not explain our poverty measure, which we explain in AJS but not the NYT piece. Okay. But, then, he uses the terrible official U.S. measure. I also don’t understand why he includes single fathers in his calculations. Samuelson alludes to “several acrimonious exchanges” with me, but we talked only once on the phone. It was a very strange conversation. I’ll admit I didn’t like when he condescendingly told me that social science wasn’t real science. Samuelson first asked me to send all published critiques of our piece and how we responded to them. It wasn’t clear to me why I should do his job for him. He said he was too old to read twitter himself. After Samuelson read text to me, he didn’t like it when I read him part of our piece that unambiguously contradicted his claims. Then, he said elsewhere in the piece gave reasonable readers a different impression (funny that part didn’t make it into his piece).

Then, Samuelson wanted me to compose a reply to what he had read to me over the phone. I said I needed to be quoted verbatim (as I didn’t trust his paraphrasing). He said “No. We simply cannot cede editorial responsibility to outsiders.”

I don’t have much experience with columnists like Samuelson, and it isn’t clear to me if this is how columnists normally operate. In the end, I’d be happy if his piece directs even more readers to our work. I’m happy to let readers decide for themselves.

New research on the relationship between race, place, and opportunity in the United States

A new paper released yesterday studies the impact of race on intergenerational mobility in the United States.

Stanford economist and Equitable Growth Steering Committee Member Raj Chetty and fellow researchers Nathaniel Hendren, Maggie R. Jones, and Sonya R. Porter released a new research paper yesterday, titled “Race and Economic Opportunity in the United States: An Intergenerational Perspective.” The paper analyzes the impact of race on intergenerational mobility, that is, the chances that children will earn more—or less—than their parents when they grow up.

The paper is the latest from Chetty and his fellow researchers at the Equality of Opportunity Project to examine the relationship between inequality, mobility, and opportunity in the United States. Equitable Growth thought its release was a good opportunity to revisit some of the key research findings of the project through seven charts, maps, and graphs that use their data.

One of the key findings of the paper released yesterday is that even when black and white boys are raised in families with similar incomes, black boys go on to earn less than white boys. This difference is noticeable and persistent across all incomes for boys, whereas there’s almost no discernable difference among girls. In fact, black girls go on to earn slightly more than white girls raised in families with a similar income. (See Figure 1.)

Figure 1
Source: Raj Chetty and Nathaniel Hendren, “Race and Economic Opportunity in the United States: Executive Summary” (Equality of Opportunity Project, 2018), available at http://www.equality-of-opportunity.org/assets/documents/race_summary.pdf.

This raises serious questions about why outcomes vary across gender, including arguments that point to differences in cognitive abilities to explain differences in outcomes. As The New York Times noted in its coverage of the report, “If such inherent differences existed by race, ‘you’ve got to explain to me why these putative ability differences aren’t handicapping women,’ said David Grusky, a Stanford sociologist who has reviewed the research.”

One of the most commonly cited reasons for differences in mobility across different incomes and races in the United States is the importance of place. The importance of neighborhood-level effects such as the quality of local schools, whether families in a neighborhood are headed by two or one parents, racial segregation, and other factors have been explored by Chetty himself in prior research.

Some places boost kids’ mobility more than others, as maps such as the one below from the slides for Chetty’s paper with Nathaniel Hendren, “The Impacts of Neighborhoods on Intergenerational Mobility I: Childhood Exposure Effects,” illustrate. (See Figure 2.)

Figure 2

As the map above shows, mobility is low in some parts of the United States such as the Southeast, and higher in others such as parts of the Great Plains. It’s particularly interesting to compare the above map from Chetty’s earlier work on mobility with the maps breaking down mobility by race and place in his newest paper. (See Figure 3.)

Figure 3

What the breakdown of these mobility maps by race shows is that the worst places for the mobility of white kids in low-income families are almost all better than the best places for the mobility of black kids in low-income families. As The New York Times noted in its coverage, “These new maps also suggest that part of the reason the Southeast looks bad for all children … is that the region is home to many black children who fare particularly poorly there.”

Even boys growing up in the same areas in families with similar incomes have dramatically different mobility later in life. In fact, black boys have lower incomes in adulthood than white boys in 99 percent of Census tracts. The authors note that, “These results reveal that differences in neighborhood-level resources, such as the quality of schools, cannot explain the intergenerational gaps between black and white boys by themselves.”

Chetty also has explored the impact of families’ incomes and race on innovation in a previous paper, funded in part by the Washington Center for Equitable Growth: “Who Becomes an Inventor in America? The Importance of Exposure to Innovation.” He and co-authors Alex Bell, Xavier Jaravel, Neviana Petkova, and John Van Reenen linked tax, school district, and patent records to identify the key factors in childhood that led to someone filing a patent later in life.

One of their key findings was that difference in ability—measured by test scores in early childhood—explained little in the difference in patent applications. (See Figure 4.)

Figure 4

As the chart above from The New York Times coverage of the paper illustrates, kids from families in the bottom quintile of the income distribution with high math scores were only just as likely to hold a patent as kids with low math scores who were from families in the top income quintile. A similar dynamic plays out when looking at the question from the perspective of race. (See Figure 5.)

Figure 5

In other research, “The Fading American Dream: Trends in Absolute Income Mobility Since 1940,” Chetty and fellow researchers David Grusky, Maximillian Hell, Nathaniel Hendren, Robert Manduca, and Jimmy Narang examined the impact of economic growth and inequality on trends in mobility over the second half of the 20th century. (See Figure 6.)

Figure 6

As the co-authors explained in a column they wrote for Equitable Growth about the paper, while 92 percent of children born in 1940 earned more than their parents, that was only true for 50 percent of children born in 1984. (See Figure 7.)

Figure 7

Two key differences between the start and end of the time period that Chetty and his co-authors analyzed (1940–1984) were that at the beginning of that period, economic growth was higher and income inequality was lower than was the case at the end of the time period. Examining the relative impact on mobility of boosting the former and lowering the latter, the authors found that simply returning inequality back to its earlier, lower rate would do more to improve mobility than boosting growth to the earlier, higher rate. You can read more about the importance of equitable growth for mobility in Nick Bunker’s Value Added on the original paper.

The research paper published yesterday by Chetty and his co-authors on race and mobility is just the latest by the researchers of the Equality of Opportunity Project to illustrate the role of factors outside of kids’ control—what neighborhood they grow up in, their parents’ income, their race—in determining their success later in life. It is also a powerful argument that policies that address income alone will be insufficient to ensure equality of opportunity for all Americans.

Should-Read: Paul Krugman: Trump and Trade and Zombies

Should-Read: Paul Krugman: Trump and Trade and Zombies: “Until now, the most visible neo-goldbug in the administration has been David Malpass… the former chief economist of Bear Stearns…

…a man with a Kudlow-like record of being wrong about everything. In particular, however, back in 2011 Malpass published an op-ed article declaring that what America needed to fix its economic ills was a stronger dollar (and higher interest rates). It was a bizarre claim. After all, at the time the unemployment rate was still 9 percent—and a stronger dollar would have made things even worse. Why? Because it would have made U.S. products less competitive, increasing the trade deficit—and a situation of persistently high unemployment is the one situation in which trade deficits really are an unambiguously bad thing, reducing the demand for domestic goods and services. But here’s the thing: Kudlow appears to share Malpass’s worldview. In fact, his first newsworthy statement after Trump announced his selection was a call for a higher dollar—something that would worsen the very trade deficit Trump sees as a sign of American weakness.

Why has Trump hired people with such conflicting notions about international economic policy? The answer, presumably, is that he doesn’t understand the issues well enough to realize that the conflict exists. And what both sides in this dispute share is a general propensity for invincible ignorance, which makes them Trump’s kind of people. Anyway, on international economics the Trump administration is now on track for a battle of the zombies—a fight between two sets of bad ideas that refuse to die. Pass the popcorn…