Things to Read at Nighttime on June 6, 2014

Should-Reads:

  1. Max Auffhammer: The Yoga Theorem: “With yesterday’s historical release of the EPA’s new carbon emissions policy, I took an extra day to comb through and digest the news. I have organized my intermediate microeconomics class around something called the ‘Yoga Theorem’. This almost universal truth states that the less flexible you are, the more you will suffer. It holds in a very large number of settings (e.g., tax incidence, market power). Yesterday, the Obama administration… turned up the heat on existing coal fired power plants. This is big news. Almost 40% of energy related US CO2 emissions come from power generation and the new rule will cut these emissions by 30%…. As far as standards are concerned, there is a lot to like about the new rule…. Instead of prescribing what states have to do to meet these standards, there are a number of flexibility mechanisms…. While I applaud the Obama administration for this very smart piece of regulation in a world where the right side of the aisle is hostile to least-cost, market-based approaches, I am concerned that this will do little to move the countries that matter to act in a significant way. China, one day after the new rule was published, signaled that it is likely to put a total cap on carbon emissions–not just the carbon intensity of GDP. We will find out soon whether the negotiating strategies of the LDCs will change at the all important Paris meeting of the parties and how big that Chinese cap is. I am certain that this new rule is part of a solution, but by no means the last word in mitigation policy. We need to do much more. And very soon.”

  2. Josh Bivens et al.: Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s Our Central Economic Policy Challengee: “The failure of wages to grow for the vast majority is the leading reason why progress in reducing poverty has stalled over the last three-and-a-half decades. Wage-driven inequality has severed the link between poverty reduction and overall economic growth…. From 1979 to 2012, the impact of rising inequality was nearly five times more important in explaining poverty trends than changes in family structure, while rising educational attainment of low-wage workers actually put downward pressure on the poverty rate over that time. Wage growth is key to poverty reduction: The bottom fifth of non-elderly American households relied on work-related income (wages, benefits, and wage-based tax credits) for more than two-thirds (69.7 percent) of their total incomes in 2010…”

Should Be Aware of:

And:

  1. James Fallows: Prisoners of Knowledge: “It was the most exultantly pro-war that I can recall. The prevailing mood was a William Randolph Hearst–type production. It was not just disagreement on the merits of doing this, it was dismissive ridicule of the weakness of the people who weren’t with the program. [If you were against the war] it was a sign that you shrank reflexively from the use of force, that you were a symptom of America’s long slouch into fearfulness around the world, that you were dismissive of the moral claims of the Kurds or others in Iraq. If you were tough as a thinker and decision-maker, if you were brave about America’s role in the world, and if you were properly sensitive to the moral claims of the people Saddam Hussein had abused, then the logic of history and the times led you not to just support the war, but to embrace it…. The editorial page of the Washington Post… was stridently pro-war and has never reflected on that…. I’ve never seen any introspection from them. They were the only major publication that on the ten-year anniversary didn’t have any look-back.”

  2. Ashok Rao: This is Ashok: “I think this only further implicates the European elite by serving a certain ‘German perspective’ that requires such a deep prior that any and all monetary stimulus is always and everywhere evil. And while journalists are responsible for their audience, they are also beholden to the truth: and at least given what I know the perspective peddled in this interview is an unfair representation of reality. To a layman reading the interview, the tone is dominated not necessarily by the clarity of Praet’s thought, but the forceful austerity of Schieritz’ question…”

  3. Catherine Garcia: A decade later, woman blamed for fiancé’s death discovers it was caused by faulty GM part: “For almost 10 years, Candice Anderson blamed herself for the car accident that killed her fiancé, Mikale Erickson. But in May, she found out that GM has linked his death to a faulty ignition switch…. Anderson told CBS News that in November 2004, the Saturn Ion she was driving in Canton, Texas, went off the road. The airbags did not deploy and there were no skid marks or any other obvious clues as to what had happened. Anderson barely survived, and was found with a small amount of anti-anxiety drugs in her system. She was charged with manslaughter and pleaded guilty to criminal negligent homicide. ‘It’s been a question if I was at fault for his death, and I’ve carried it for so long’, she told CBS News. In May, Anderson and Mikale’s mother, Rhonda Erickson, heard that Mikale’s death was one of 13 GM linked to the faulty ignition switch, a fact confirmed by the National Highway Traffic Safety Administration. The women say they have yet to hear from GM. ‘I think they owe me an apology’, Erickson said. ‘They can’t give me back my son. But, I mean, they could at least give me an apology’.” She would also like to see Anderson’s record cleared.”

  4. Brian Buetler: Republican Bergdahl Overreach Will Backfire: “The original sin was to crosswire the question of the propriety of the administration’s communication strategy with the issues surrounding the quality of the deal that secured his release. The answer to the former hinges on the conduct of the soldier himself. If Bergdahl was a deserter, he didn’t deserve a hero’s welcome. But conservatives decided to lace the debate over the terms of his rescue with doubts about his worthiness. The proposition of trading terrorists for a traitor isn’t cursed with nuance. On the basis of third party testimonials, they rendered a verdict on his conduct; and on the basis of that verdict they concluded his rescue was misbegotten, turning the “leave no man behind” ethos on its head…”

Already-Noted Must-Reads:

  1. Where s the Automation in the Productivity Accounts Jared Bernstein On the Economy Jared Bernstein: Where’s the Automation in the Productivity Accounts?: “The pace of productivity growth has decelerated…. There’s considerable speculation that the pace at which machines are displacing workers has accelerated…. The robots-are-coming advocates need to explain why a phenomenon that should be associated with accelerating productivity is allegedly occurring over a fairly protracted period where the trend in output per hour is going the other way. A shave with Occam’s razor would lead one to conclude that over this weak expansion characterized by large output gaps, a simpler explanation for decelerating productivity would be weak demand and its corollary, weak capital investment…. Until someone can convince me what’s wrong with the above argument, I don’t want to hear that automation-induced productivity gains are precluding full employment. The problem isn’t productivity; it’s negligent policy.”

  2. Ezra Klein: 7 reasons America will fail on climate change: “I don’t believe the United States or the world… will do nearly enough, nearly fast enough, to hold the rise in temperatures to safe levels. I think we’re fucked. Or, at the least, I think our grandchildren are fucked…. 1) We’ve waited so long that what America needs to do is really, really hard — and maybe impossible: In the early 1990s, scientists converged on 2°C…. We’ve waited so long to begin cutting emissions that two degrees looks flatly impossible. We’re on track for 4°C of warming…. The question isn’t whether we’ll fail. It’s how badly we’ll fail…. 2) The people most affected by climate change don’t get a vote: This map… the US… is one of the countries least affected by global warming…. Carbon emissions disproportionately benefit the US and disproportionately harm countries that are not the US…. 3) We’re bad at sacrificing now to benefit later…. 4) The effects of global warming are not easily reversible…. 5) The Republican Party has gone off the rails on climate change…. 6) The international cooperation required is unprecedented, and maybe impossible…. 7) Geoengineering is nuts…. Not to be a killjoy, but it’s hard to believe that the consequences of the huge, unpredictable changes to the global climate can be safely reversed by further efforts to make huge, unpredictable changes to the climate. So what now?… I could make up a more optimistic story. I just don’t believe it…. On climate change, the truth has gone from inconvenient to awful. Right now we’re failing our future. And we will be judged harshly for it.”

  3. Paul Krugman: Energy Choices: “Nate Silver got a lot of grief when he chose Roger Pielke Jr., of all people, to write about environment for the new 538. Pielke is regarded among climate scientists as a concern troll – someone who pretends to be open-minded, but is actually committed to undermining the case for emissions limits any way he can. But is this fair? Well, I’m happy to report that Pielke has a letter… that abundantly confirms his bad reputation…”

  4. Routinous rouinous FT Alphaville Cardiff Garcia: Routinous, Rouinous: “The chart comes via this recent note from the Dallas Fed, and the theme will be familiar to those who have read the earlier work of Frank Levy, Richard Murname, and David Autor…. These were mainly middle-income jobs, and as their share of the work force declined, the nonroutine jobs at opposite ends of the wage spectrum–nonroutine cognitive and manual jobs — replaced them…. Another worry is that even jobs that were once considered impossible to automate because of their distinctly ‘human’ qualities might themselves be vulnerable…. Food service and retail jobs are being replaced by kiosks. Machine intelligence is already changing the legal industry. Robots will take over some pattern recognition duties and surgery from doctors. Driverless cars will replace long-distance truck drivers…. What is nonroutine to a human will one day be (by definition?) routine to a machine…”

  5. Joe Romm: 7 Reasons America Should Succeed On Climate Change: “1. What America and the world needs to do is really, really cheap economically, as key clean technologies plummet in cost…. 2. All of the people who get a vote are severely affected by climate change…. 3. We’re sometimes very good at sacrificing now to benefit later (and to benefit others)…. 4. There NEVER will be a time when aggressive climate action is not the best strategy for everyone….

  6. The Republican Party has gone so far off the rails on climate change that it is triggering a backlash…. 6. The international cooperation required is unprecedented, but the key country for a treaty, China, is on a path toward capping its carbon emissions…. 7. Geoengineering is nuts…”

Evening Must-Read: Joe Romm: 7 Reasons America Should Succeed On Climate Change

Joe Romm: 7 Reasons America Should Succeed On Climate Change: “1. What America and the world needs to do is…

…really, really cheap economically, as key clean technologies plummet in cost…. 2. All of the people who get a vote are severely affected by climate change…. 3. We’re sometimes very good at sacrificing now to benefit later (and to benefit others)…. 4. There NEVER will be a time when aggressive climate action is not the best strategy for everyone….
5. The Republican Party has gone so far off the rails on climate change that it is triggering a backlash…. 6. The international cooperation required is unprecedented, but the key country for a treaty, China, is on a path toward capping its carbon emissions…. 7. Geoengineering is nuts…

The labor market is doing better, but not fully recovered

Six-and-a-half years after the start of the Great Recession, in some ways, the U.S. labor market has recovered nicely. According to today’s Bureau of Labor Statistics Employment Situation report, the total number of workers with jobs has exceeded its pre-recession high of 138,365,000. The three-month average for job growth is 234,000 a month, a respectable level that’s higher than the average monthly rate during 2001-to-2007 business cycle. And the unemployment rate has dropped from its high of 10 percent in October 2009 to 6.3 percent in May.

But, to keep with the medical analogy, the patient still isn’t close to optimal health and remains weak. These improvements are not insignificant, but they are not enough to alleviate the pain the Great Recession inflicted on our economy.

Consider this chart from Bill McBride of Calculated Risk showing this employment recovery has been the slowest of any recovery since the end of World War II:

2014-may-employ

Then consider the employment-to-population ratio. The share of Americans over the age of 16 with a job remained at 58.9 percent in May. That’s almost 4 percentage points lower than the ratio in December 2007. And the ratio has only increased by 0.7 percentage points since its low in November 2010. That’s not a recovery.

060614-employ-pop

The labor force participation rate, or the percentage of workers who have a job or are actively looking for one, was 62.8 percent in May. That rate is 3.2 percentage points lower than its pre-recession level in December 2007. And the rate has yet to start an upward climb. Some of this decline is due to the retirement of baby boomers, but it’s mostly due to workers simply giving up on finding a job.

 

And wage growth has been muted during the recovery as well. The year-on-year growth in nominal wages was 2.1 percent in May, just above its average rate of 2 percent since March 2010. The rate is not only below its pre-recession pace of roughly 3 percent, but it hasn’t accelerated recently either.

 

Settling into this new normal would affect not only the life prospects of the unemployed and the underemployed but also the future output of our entire economy. By letting workers sit idle, we risk the possibility of forever losing them and their economic potential. Economists refer to this process as hysteresis. The Congressional Budget Office has already revised down its projection of potential economic growth due to the weak recovery.

Boosting growth and getting the labor market back on track would help avoid this less equitable and poor future. On so many fronts, policy can be done to boost growth in the short term. Congress needs to seriously consider expansionary fiscal policy given today’s low interest rates and the high need of improving infrastructure. The Federal Reserve should consider if it really is time to start pulling back from quantitative easing.

Policy makers should not, and cannot, take today’s jobs report as a sign that our economy is on the right path. Too much work is left to be done.

 

Another Employment Report with Yet Another Data Point in the Continuing Flat-Lining of the Employment-to-Population Ratio

There has been very little recovery of the employment share from its business-cycle nadir trough. Very little. And it isn’t happening now.

Fromhttp://www.bls.gov/:

Two-thirds of the 1.2%-point reduction in the unemployment rate in the past year comes from a further decline in labor-force participation; only one-third comes from an increase in the employment-to-population ratio:

Employment Situation Summary Table A Household data seasonally adjusted

Nominal wages today are 2.05% above their level of last year–and with a 2%/year trend rate of labor-productivity growth, that means that the rate of inflation consistent with a stable labor share of income is 0.05%. There is no inflation pressure on this economy at all save for pressure exerted by widening inequality, and damned little of that:

Employment Situation Summary Table B Establishment data seasonally adjusted

Inequality and the future rate of savings

Thomas Piketty’s second “fundamental law of capitalism” in his book “Capital in the 21st Century” is generating some intriguing attention of late. This law argues that in the long run the ratio of wealth to income will rise to a level equal to the savings rate divided by the growth rate of the economy. This ratio is important for economists and policymakers to understand because if this is indeed a fundamental law then our economy would become increasingly dominated by the accumulating capital of the wealthy.

Recently there’s been a discussion about whether the variables underlying Piketty’s second law would actually lead to a rising wealth-to-income ratio. In particular, how much will the savings rate increase at all in the future? Economists Per Krusell of Stockholm University and Tony Smith of Yale University, for example, argue that there is a positive relationship between growth and the saving rate leading to a declining savings rate as growth declines. This means that the ratio of savings to growth, and therefore the wealth-to-income ratio, would not increase as much as Piketty predicts.

There’s also the issue of net savings versus gross savings. In order for savings to create new capital, the rate of savings has to be higher than the rate of decline in old capital, known as depreciation. If savings just keeps up with the depreciation, then old capital is just being replaced and nothing new is created. Piketty acknowledges this in the book, but only briefly and moves right along. The distinction, however, is important. As S.H. at the Economist notes, the net savings rate has been on the decline in recent decades. In the long turn, rising income inequality could be the source of the rise in the savings rate. As S.H. points out, rising inequality could come from other sources such as skill-based technological change. But that rise could itself feed into Piketty’s second law.

Then there’s this consideration—as more and more income flows to those at top, the consumption and savings decisions of top earners would have a larger effect on the overall savings rate. We know that high-income individuals have a higher savings rate than the rest of the population, as detailed in research by economist Karen Dynan at the Federal Reserve Board, Dartmouth College’s Jonathan Skinner, and Stephen Zeldes of Columbia University. Shifting income toward those at the top could increase the gross savings rate of the economy, increasing the savings rate and potentially increase the wealth-to-income ratio.

Of course, the net savings rate depends not only the gross savings rate but also the depreciation rate. Depreciation in the future could accelerate and counteract the rise in net savings. It could also decrease or stay constant and the net savings rate would increase.

As quantum physicists and baseball players know, predictions are difficult. Especially those about the future. According to Piketty’s second fundamental law, the wealth-to-income ratio depends upon the future path of savings, depreciation, and the total growth of the economy. Making solid predictions about any of these variables is a difficult task. But inequality could play an important role in the future rate of savings.

 

Afternoon Must-Read: Cardiff Garcia: Routinous, Rouinouis

Routinous rouinous FT Alphaville

Cardiff Garcia: Routinous, Rouinous: “The chart comes via this recent note from the Dallas Fed…

…and the theme will be familiar to those who have read the earlier work of Frank Levy, Richard Murname, and David Autor…. These were mainly middle-income jobs, and as their share of the work force declined, the nonroutine jobs at opposite ends of the wage spectrum–nonroutine cognitive and manual jobs — replaced them…. Another worry is that even jobs that were once considered impossible to automate because of their distinctly ‘human’ qualities might themselves be vulnerable…. Food service and retail jobs are being replaced by kiosks. Machine intelligence is already changing the legal industry. Robots will take over some pattern recognition duties and surgery from doctors. Driverless cars will replace long-distance truck drivers…. What is nonroutine to a human will one day be (by definition?) routine to a machine….”

Trying, Yet Again, to Communicate the Arithmetic Scaffolding of Piketty’s “Capital in the Twenty-First Century”: Thursday Focus: June 5, 2014

I am once again flummoxed by the number of economists of note and reputation who have been commenting on Piketty’s Capital in the 21st Century without, apparently, bothering to do the work to understand the basic arithmetic scaffolding of the book.

I think that the most fruitful way to understand the basic arithmetic is via the road I took in my “Mr. Piketty and the ‘Neoclassicists'”, focusing on the equilibrium rate of accumulation n+g, the wedge ω between the rate of accumulation and the warranted rate of net profit, the warranted rate of net profit rnw, and the resulting equilibrium wealth-to-annual-net-income ratio K/Yn.

But there is another road–one that goes not through prices but through the quantities of the Solow growth model: gross savings, depreciation, and population and technology growth. I think this road is less illuminating and more likely to cause confusion. But perhaps it will help some people who do not currently do so to understand the arithmetic scaffolding of the book.

James s Kindle for Mac 3 Capital in the Twenty First Century

Piketty and his coauthors estimate that back before 1914 the wealth-to-annual-net-income ratio for northwest European economies was on the order of 700%: the total holdings of property by the economy’s wealthholders amounted to seven times annual income. They also calculate a northwest European rate of growth of income of 1.2%/year–about half from population and labor force, and about half from labor productivity. In the framework of the Solow growth model, you can calculate the rate of savings out of gross income required to maintain that wealth intensity from the formula:

MathType Untitled 1

if you know the annual rate at which wealth is subject to depreciation δ.

Three depreciation rates have been proposed. I tend to favor a depreciation rate of 3.33%/year–a lot of the wealth held in the economy back before World War I was in the form of land, which does not depreciate, or various property rights guaranteed by successful rent-seeking of one sort or another. With a depreciation rate of 3.33%, we calculate that 25.7% of gross output was saved and reinvested in maintaining and building the wealth stock; of this 8.4% of gross output keeps the capital stock growing at the 1.2%/year rate of income, and 17.3% of gross output covers the depreciation.

Alex Tabarrok favors a depreciation rate of 5.0%/year–what one would get out of a standard long-run growth model. This seems to me a little high given what kinds of property make up the claims to income included in Piketty’s definition of “capital”. But it is certainly in the admissible range. For this depreciation rate, we calculate that 32.1% of gross output in northwest Europe back before World War I was saved and reinvested in maintaining and building the wealth stock; of this, once again 8.4% keeps the capital stock growing at the 1.2%/year rate of income, and 23.7% to cover depreciation.

Krusell and Smith favor a deprecation rate of 10%/year–and I genuinely do not understand why they think it is appropriate. We are not, after all, dealing with short-run business-cycle fluctuations in which the pieces of the capital stock that vary are made up mostly of inventories and machines here. We are talking about land, very durable buildings, powerful property rights and the ability to summon the police to protect them–claims over future output that do not, I think, erode away at anything like 10%/year. And, indeed, if you try to understand the pre-WWI northwest European economies with such an assumed depreciation rate, you get results that strike me as completely nonsensical: 46.1% of gross output in gross investment; I think we would have noticed if, in pre-WWI northwest Europe’s economies, two out of every five workers spent their days simply keeping society’s collective capital stock from depreciating by repairing rust and wear-and-tear. That is simply not what the pre-WWI northwest European economies looked like.

Untitled numbers

But the Belle Époque comes to an end. World War I, the Bolshevik Revolution, the Great Depression, and World War II wreak their effects on the North Atlantic. The wealth-to-annual-net-income ratio falls to 300% or so as the growth acceleration of the twentieth century raises the rate of growth of income to 3.0%/year. And then during the Thirty Glorious Years of post-WWII social-democracy and growth the wealth-to-annual-net-income ratio shows no signs of rising swiftly back to its previous equilibrium of 700%. Viewed from the perspective of the Solow growth model, the economy of the generation after 1950 is and remains much less capital-intensive than the economy before World War I, and to support this lower capital-intensity equilibrium requires savings rates out of gross output reduced by a third from their pre-WWI shares:

Untitled numbers

Starting around 1980, Piketty argues, the North Atlantic shifted out of its Social-Democratic Era and is now moving into a new configuration, with increasingly-concentrated wealth, savings no longer reduced by highly progressive capital taxation and fear of expropriation, and slower rates of population and labor productivity growth. Piketty expects the consequence to be a rise in the savings rate back to Belle Époque levels and a return to the capital intensity and inherited-wealth dominance of those days. In my view, the next questions are two:

  1. Would this be a good thing? More savings and wealth accumulation by the rich that increase the capital intensity of the economy increase real wages for the working class and the poor, no? Here I think the answer is perhaps–and I think this is what the debate over Piketty should be about. Unfortunately, that is not the debate we are having. Instead, we have:

  2. Can this happen? And Krusell and Smith and company are saying: no, it cannot. As the capital-output ratio rises, the desire to consume wealth pushes the gross savings rate goes down and the fact that capital depreciates at 10%/year pushes the net savings rate down much further, and so there are no macroeconomic forces in play that could push the wealth-to-annual-net-income ratio far up above its current value of 300%.

But if the savings rate necessarily falls as the wealth-to-annual-net-income ratio rises, why was the (gross) savings rate half again as high back before World War I when the economy was wealth-dominated as it is today? And from where comes the 10%/year depreciation rate assumption?

What we clearly have here is a failure to communicate. And I really, really do not think that it is the result of a failure to try on Thomas Piketty’s part.

Calculations here: https://www.icloud.com/iw/#numbers/BAKWqmBPWn9zULDVGZGBDMJheVCgDvXgeXaF/20140605_Piketty_Solow.numbers


1351 words

Morning Must-Read: Paul Krugman on Roger Pieleke, Jr., 538.com, and Global Warming

Paul Krugman: Energy Choices: “Nate Silver got a lot of grief when he chose Roger Pielke Jr….

…of all people, to write about environment for the new 538. Pielke is regarded among climate scientists as a concern troll – someone who pretends to be open-minded, but is actually committed to undermining the case for emissions limits any way he can. But is this fair? Well, I’m happy to report that Pielke has a letter… that abundantly confirms his bad reputation…. Pielke:

Carbon emissions are the product of growth in gross domestic product and of the technologies of energy consumption and production. More precisely, this relationship is called the Kaya Identity – after Yoichi Kaya…. A ‘carbon cap’ necessarily means that a government is committing to either a cessation of economic growth or to the systematic advancement of technological innovation in energy systems on a predictable schedule…. Because halting economic growth is not an option, in China or anywhere else, and because technological innovation does not occur via fiat, there is in practice no such thing as a carbon cap.

This is actually kind of wonderful, in a bang-your-head-on-the-table sort of way. Pielke isn’t claiming that it’s hard in practice to limit emissions without halting economic growth, he’s arguing that it’s logically impossible. So let’s talk about why this is stupid…. Emissions reflect the size of the economy and the available technologies. But they also reflect choices… about what to consume… how to produce it… which of a number of energy technologies to use. These choices are, in turn, strongly affected by incentives…. Electricity consumption isn’t in a fixed relationship with GDP…. Even more important, there are many ways to generate electricity: coal, gas, nuclear, hydro, wind, solar…. That doesn’t mean that reducing emissions has no cost–but again, the idea that, say, a 30 percent fall in emissions requires a 30 percent fall in GDP is ludicrous…. Pielke’s fallacy… [is] the notion that there’s a rigid link between growth and pollution…. What we actually need is a change in the form of growth–and that’s exactly the kind of thing markets are good at, if you get the prices right. Anyway, I guess I should thank Pielke for his intervention, which has helped clarify how we should think both about energy issues and about him.

Morning Must-Read: Ezra Klein: 7 Reasons the World Will Fail on Global Warming

Ezra Klein: 7 reasons America will fail on climate change: “I don’t believe the United States…

…or the world… will do nearly enough, nearly fast enough, to hold the rise in temperatures to safe levels. I think we’re fucked. Or, at the least, I think our grandchildren are fucked…. 1) We’ve waited so long that what America needs to do is really, really hard — and maybe impossible: In the early 1990s, scientists converged on 2°C…. We’ve waited so long to begin cutting emissions that two degrees looks flatly impossible. We’re on track for 4°C of warming…. The question isn’t whether we’ll fail. It’s how badly we’ll fail…. 2) The people most affected by climate change don’t get a vote: This map… the US… is one of the countries least affected by global warming…. Carbon emissions disproportionately benefit the US and disproportionately harm countries that are not the US…. 3) We’re bad at sacrificing now to benefit later…. 4) The effects of global warming are not easily reversible…. 5) The Republican Party has gone off the rails on climate change…. 6) The international cooperation required is unprecedented, and maybe impossible…. 7) Geoengineering is nuts…. Not to be a killjoy, but it’s hard to believe that the consequences of the huge, unpredictable changes to the global climate can be safely reversed by further efforts to make huge, unpredictable changes to the climate. So what now?… I could make up a more optimistic story. I just don’t believe it…. On climate change, the truth has gone from inconvenient to awful. Right now we’re failing our future. And we will be judged harshly for it.

Morning Must-Read: Jared Bernstein: Where’s the Automation in the Productivity Accounts?

Where s the Automation in the Productivity Accounts Jared Bernstein On the Economy

Jared Bernstein: Where’s the Automation in the Productivity Accounts?: “The pace of productivity growth has decelerated….

…There’s considerable speculation that the pace at which machines are displacing workers has accelerated…. The robots-are-coming advocates need to explain why a phenomenon that should be associated with accelerating productivity is allegedly occurring over a fairly protracted period where the trend in output per hour is going the other way. A shave with Occam’s razor would lead one to conclude that over this weak expansion characterized by large output gaps, a simpler explanation for decelerating productivity would be weak demand and its corollary, weak capital investment…. Until someone can convince me what’s wrong with the above argument, I don’t want to hear that automation-induced productivity gains are precluding full employment.  The problem isn’t productivity; it’s negligent policy.