High concentration of poverty is a threat to our economy

The U.S. Census Bureau earlier this week released a report looking the distribution of poverty geographically across the U.S. economy in 2010. The results are troubling for anyone concerned about creating a more inclusive, dynamic and equitable economy.

The report finds that a quarter (25 percent) of Americans that year resided in an area where at least 20 percent of the population lived in poverty. To put that number in context, the overall poverty rate was just under 15 percent.

To be clear, this isn’t the share of people who themselves are in poverty and who live in high-poverty areas. These data show that 25 percent of all Americans live in high-poverty areas. For Americans living in poverty, the rate is about half.

The concentration of poverty varies quite a bit across regions in the United States as well by education level. But the largest variation in poverty concentration is by race. Seventeen percent of white, non-Hispanic Americans live in a high-poverty area, according to the Census Bureau. Fifty percent of all black Americans live in high-poverty areas. That rate is higher than the rate of white Americans who themselves are in poverty, 38 percent. To put this another way, any black American, in poverty or not, is more likely to live in a high-poverty area than a white American who is actually in poverty. (To learn more about this issue, check out New York University sociologist Patrick Sharkey’s book, “Stuck in Place.)

The consequences of poverty concentration are significant and malignant. Harvard University economists Raj Chetty and Nathaniel Hendren alongside University of California, Berkeley economists Patrick Kline and Emmanuel Saez find that children raised in areas with higher economic segregation are less likely to be economically mobile. Segregation also interacts with primary and secondary education as low-income areas are less likely to have adequate schools, which in turn reduces mobility and human capital development, a key asset for economic growth.

And those are just the economic consequences. As the new Census Bureau report points out, high-poverty areas have higher levels of violence and crime as well as lower quality housing.

Segregation by race and income is nefarious for many reasons. For the people living in these neighborhoods, they are denied access to opportunity. And that lack of opportunity hurts the entire U.S. economy by denying us the fruits of their untapped skills and talents.

To be clear, the Census Bureau data do not include the effects on poverty of tax and transfer programs, such as the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program and the Earned Income Tax Credit. According to researchers at Columbia University, these and other programs have put a significant dent in poverty.

These poverty trends in the U.S. economy are troubling, to say the least. Policymakers need to be aware of these disparities, especially when it comes to matters of race, and understand the implications for future U.S. economic competitiveness. Possible policy solutions hinge on grappling with the implications of these data findings.

Things to Read on the Afternoon of July 2, 2014

Should-Reads:

  1. Robert Johnson: Growing Up in the Cauldron of 1960’s Detroit:

  2. Americans delayed retirement expectations in 3 sad charts VoxDanielle Kurtzleben: Americans’ delayed retirement expectations

  3. Mark Thoma sends us to Janet Yellen: Monetary Policy and Financial Stability: “Accommodative monetary policy has contributed to low interest rates, a flat yield curve, improved financial conditions more broadly, and a stronger labor market. These effects have contributed to balance sheet repair among households, improved financial conditions among businesses, and hence a strengthening in the health of the financial sector… [and] increased safety of the financial sector…. I do not presently see a need for monetary policy to deviate from a primary focus on attaining price stability and maximum employment, in order to address financial stability concerns…. The policy approach to promoting financial stability has changed dramatically in the wake of the global financial crisis. We have made considerable progress in implementing a macroprudential approach…. The IMF plays an important role in this evolving process as a forum for representatives from the world’s economies and as an institution charged with promoting financial and economic stability globally. I expect to both contribute to and learn from ongoing discussions on these issues…”

  4. Robert Waldmann: A Comment on Kling on Remembering the 1970s: “Friedman did not believe in rational expectations and had no trouble explaining and more or less, predicting the stagflation…. It was obvious to prominent Keynesians (I am thinking of Solow and Tobin) that the one-lag autoregressive expectations model wasn’t the truth…. There was a debate which can be translated into contemporary econospeak as “in around 1970, Solow believed that US inflation expectations (unlike Latin American inflation expectations) were anchored.” This doesn’t mean that he predicted that they would remain anchored…. Solow’s position was very explicitly that inflation expectations are sometimes anchored and sometimes not… the view currently expressed by, among others, Ben Bernanke, Janet Yellen and Narayana Kocherlakota… the standard view among monetary policy makers…. I think the key event was the spread of the strange belief that Samuelson, Solow et al believed in an expectations-unaugmented Phillips curve…. The take-home lesson was that you better not trust data without formal theory…. I don’t know exactly when or how the strange delusion about old Keynesians began. It is certainly expressed in Friedman’s Nobel lecture (in which he doesn’t name his straw Keynesians)…”

  5. Austin Frakt Two things we learned from the Hobby Lobby decision: “Thing 1: The majority of the Supreme Court doesn’t get science. Thing 2: The majority of the Supreme Court doesn’t get economics. On the merits, I’m not in agreement with the decision, but I’m actually more favorable to it than this bit of snark would suggest. There certainly must be some limits…. I’m just not convinced that this is where the line is, particularly given the evidence. But, back to my main point: It’s deeply troubling when any branch of government (or anyone at all) makes policy decisions that turn on arguments in contradiction with evidence. That doesn’t make such decisions wrong, but it makes them improperly justified. Find a less obviously incorrect argument or rethink your position. This, perhaps, is too much to ask in America or of people in general. And if so (either one), it’s sad. Deeply sad.”

Should Be Aware of:

And:

  1. Paul Krugman: Trick or Tweak: “Sam Tanenhaus asks, ‘Can the G.O.P. Be a Party of Ideas?’ Why, no. This is another edition of simple answers to simple questions…. ‘Reform conservatives’ seem mainly to be offering supposedly new ideas for the sake of being seen to offer new ideas. And there isn’t much there there; can you find anything in the Tanenhaus piece that sounds like an important new idea rather than a minor tweak on the current conservative catechism? I can’t…. The central policy debate in US politics hasn’t changed in decades, nor should it. Liberals want a strong social safety net, financed with relatively high taxes, especially on high incomes. Conservatives want much less of a safety net, and much lower taxes on the affluent. Thirty-five years ago conservatives did produce a new argument–the claim that high taxes and generous benefits were producing such a drag on the economy that even lower-income Americans would be better off if we slashed all of that. And they got most of what they wanted…. But growth failed to take off while inequality soared…”

  2. Stefan Nagel: The Liquidity Premium of Near-Money Assets: “Treasury bills and other near-money assets provide owners with liquidity service benefits that are reflected in prices in the form of a liquidity premium. I relate time variation in this liquidity premium to changes in the opportunity cost of money: The liquidity service benefits of near-money assets are more valuable when short-term interest rates are high and hence the opportunity cost of holding money is high. Consistent with this prediction, the liquidity premium of T-bills and other near-money assets is strongly positively correlated with the level of short-term interest rates. Once short-term interest rates are controlled for, Treasury security supply variables lose their explanatory power for the liquidity premium. I argue that an analysis of scarcity and price of near-money assets is incomplete without taking into account the substitution relationship with money and its supply by the central bank. Payment of interest on reserves (IOR) could potentially reduce liquidity premia because IOR reduces the opportunity cost of at least one type of money (reserves). In the UK and Canada, however, the introduction of IOR did not shrink liquidity premia. Apparently, the reduction in banks’ opportunity cost of money did not result in a broader fall in the opportunity costs of money for non-bank market participants…”

3.David Dayen: Supreme Court’s out-of-control spiral: Ideologues rewriting their own laws: “As you probably know, the court ruled in the Hobby Lobby case that closely held corporations, where the top five shareholders control more than 50 percent of the company, must be given an accommodation for providing birth control in their employer-based insurance coverage, if they say it violates their religious beliefs. The decision, written by Justice Samuel Alito, explicitly argues companies like Hobby Lobby could be granted the same accommodation as churches and religious nonprofits…. Alito… drew a completely arbitrary line…writes, ‘our decision in these cases is solely concerned with the contraception mandate’…. As Kevin Drum notes, this is a very ‘Bush v. Gore’ type of effort, where the majority, as they’re writing the ruling, warn everyone to never use it as precedent. Not only is this not how the law works, the randomness of the distinction makes no sense: Indeed, contraception plays a major role in stopping the spread of infectious diseases! Justice Alito boiled down all religious sentiment into caring about whether women have too much unauthorized sex. He actually picks and chooses among religions, essentially saying that only beliefs about abortion matter in the religious liberty context. Furthermore, the ruling ignores science, by associating contraception with abortifacients…”

Already-Noted Must-Reads:

  1. Betsey Stevenson et al.: The Council of Economic Advisers: Missed Opportunities: The Consequences of State Decisions Not to Expand Medicaid: “24 States have not yet expanded Medicaid including many of the States that would benefit most…. The Urban Institute estimate[s] that… 5.7 million people will be deprived of health insurance coverage in 2016. Meanwhile, these States will forgo billions in Federal dollars that could boost their economies…. If the States that have not yet expanded Medicaid did so: 1.4 million more people would have a usual source of clinic care…. States that have already expanded Medicaid… 1.0 million…. 651,000 more people would receive all care they feel they need in a typical year….. States that have already expanded Medicaid will achieve this outcome for 494,000 people…. 829,000 people would receive cholesterol‐level screenings once expanded coverage was fully in effect. States that have already expanded… 630,000…. 214,000 women between the ages of 50 and 64 would receive mammograms…. States that have already expanded… 161,000 women…. 345,000 women would receive pap smears…. States that have already expanded… for 261,000 women…. 15.4 million physician office visits…. States that have already expanded… 11.7 million….255,000 fewer people will face catastrophic out‐of‐pocket medical costs in a typical year…. States that have already expanded… 194,000…. 810,000 fewer people will have trouble paying other bills due to the burden of medical…. States that have already expanded… 348,000…. 757,000 additional people would report being in excellent, very good, or good health… States that have already expanded… 575,000 people….
     
    “$88 billion in Federal support through calendar year 2016. States that have already expanded… $84 billion…. Boosted employment by 85,000 jobs in 2014, 184,000 jobs in 2015, and a total of 379,000 job‐years through 2017. States that have already expanded… 356,000 job‐years…. $66 billion in total economic activity through 2017. States that have already expanded… $62 billion…”

  2. Danny Quah: It Is Not Easy Being Leader Of The World: “In Rajan’s view sensible policy-makers ought to believe: ‘We would like to live in a world where countries take into account the effect of their policies on other countries and do what is right, broadly, rather than what is just right given the circumstances of that country.’ The industrial countries, led by the US, would not play by these implicit rules of the game. Rajan’s statements… elicited a US response with four distinct lines of reasoning. The US central bank could not, by law, take into account the well-being of any party except the US economy… the world economy was not really as inter-connected as Rajan and others might think… if any foreign economy was adversely affected by US monetary policy, it was only because… [of] ‘the challenge is brought on by their own domestic policies’… hat is good for the US is, ultimately, good for the world. It must be tough to be global hegemon…”

  3. Pierre-Cyrille Hautcoeur, Angelo Riva, and Eugene N. White: Banque de France’s 1889 ‘lifeboat’ bank rescue : “The key challenge for lenders of last resort is to ameliorate financial crises without encouraging excessive risk-taking…. The lessons from the Banque de France’s successful handling of the crisis of 1889. Recognising its systemic importance, the Banque provided an emergency loan to the insolvent Comptoir d’Escompte. Banks that shared responsibility for the crisis were forced to guarantee the losses, which were ultimately recouped by large fines–notably on the Comptoir’s board of directors. This appears to have reduced moral hazard–there were no financial crises in France for 25 years…”

Lunchtime Must-Read: Pierre-Cyrille Hautcoeur et al.: Lend Freely *at a Penalty Rate*: The Banque de France’s 1889 ‘Lifeboat’ Bank Rescue

Pierre-Cyrille Hautcoeur, Angelo Riva, and Eugene N. White: Banque de France’s 1889 ‘lifeboat’ bank rescue: “The key challenge for lenders of last resort…

…is to ameliorate financial crises without encouraging excessive risk-taking…. The lessons from the Banque de France’s successful handling of the crisis of 1889. Recognising its systemic importance, the Banque provided an emergency loan to the insolvent Comptoir d’Escompte. Banks that shared responsibility for the crisis were forced to guarantee the losses, which were ultimately recouped by large fines–notably on the Comptoir’s board of directors. This appears to have reduced moral hazard–there were no financial crises in France for 25 years…

Lunchtime Must-Read: Council of Economic Advisors: Missed Opportunities: The Consequences of State Decisions Not to Expand Medicaid

Betsey Stevenson et al.: The Council of Economic Advisers: Missed Opportunities: The Consequences of State Decisions Not to Expand Medicaid: “24 States have not yet expanded Medicaid…

…including many of the States that would benefit most…. The Urban Institute estimate[s] that… 5.7 million people will be deprived of health insurance coverage in 2016. Meanwhile, these States will forgo billions in Federal dollars that could boost their economies…. If the States that have not yet expanded Medicaid did so: 1.4 million more people would have a usual source of clinic care…. States that have already expanded Medicaid… 1.0 million…. 651,000 more people would receive all care they feel they need in a typical year….. States that have already expanded Medicaid will achieve this outcome for 494,000 people…. 829,000 people would receive cholesterol‐level screenings once expanded coverage was fully in effect. States that have already expanded… 630,000…. 214,000 women between the ages of 50 and 64 would receive mammograms…. States that have already expanded… 161,000 women…. 345,000 women would receive pap smears…. States that have already expanded… for 261,000 women…. 15.4 million physician office visits…. States that have already expanded… 11.7 million….255,000 fewer people will face catastrophic out‐of‐pocket medical costs in a typical year…. States that have already expanded… 194,000…. 810,000 fewer people will have trouble paying other bills due to the burden of medical…. States that have already expanded… 348,000…. 757,000 additional people would report being in excellent, very good, or good health… States that have already expanded… 575,000 people….

$88 billion in Federal support through calendar year 2016. States that have already expanded… $84 billion…. Boosted employment by 85,000 jobs in 2014, 184,000 jobs in 2015, and a total of 379,000 job‐years through 2017. States that have already expanded… 356,000 job‐years…. $66 billion in total economic activity through 2017. States that have already expanded… $62 billion…

Nighttime Must-Read: Paul Krugman: Neomonetarist Delusions

Paul Krugman: Neomonetarist Delusions: “Danny Vinik notes that…

‘reform conservatives’, who are trying either to rescue the right from its intellectual torpor or to provide cover for its fundamental anti-intellectualism… have gotten… lip service for some of their ideas, but none at all for… monetary policy to assure full employment…. The neomonetarist movement starts from an acknowledgement of reality: shortfalls of aggregate demand do happen, and they do matter, and we need an answer…. They argue that the Fed and its counterparts can do the job all on their own…. I don’t buy this on the economics; to do what’s needed central banks either have to take on a lot of risk, which is in effect a form of fiscal policy, or change inflation expectations, which is far beyond conventional monetary policy. But… the more important point is that the neomonetarists are deluded in imagining that there is any constituency for their ideas in the modern conservative movement….

Underlying this [right wing] total opposition to monetary expansion lie two deep forces. First, much of the right is thoroughly committed to the view that bad things only happen because of the government…. Paul Ryan is… the intellectual leader… and he gets his monetary economics from characters in Ayn Rand novels. Moreover, the Kalecki argument about why business interests oppose activist fiscal policy applies to monetary policy too. If ‘captains of industry’ want the body politic to believe that prosperity depends on their ‘confidence’… they’re going to hate monetarism… [because it says] full employment depends on policy…. There’s really no constituency for neomonetarism. Milton Friedman would be an isolated outcast in today’s conservative movement, and his would-be successors have no home.

Evening Must-Read: Danny Quah: It Is Not Easy Being Leader Of The World

Danny Quah: It Is Not Easy Being Leader Of The World: “In Rajan’s view…

…sensible policy-makers ought to believe:

We would like to live in a world where countries take into account the effect of their policies on other countries and do what is right, broadly, rather than what is just right given the circumstances of that country.

The industrial countries, led by the US, would not play by these implicit rules of the game. Rajan’s statements… elicited a US response with four distinct lines of reasoning. The US central bank could not, by law, take into account the well-being of any party except the US economy… the world economy was not really as inter-connected as Rajan and others might think… if any foreign economy was adversely affected by US monetary policy, it was only because… [of] ‘the challenge is brought on by their own domestic policies’… hat is good for the US is, ultimately, good for the world. It must be tough to be global hegemon…

What is compensation? And what should it be?

Yesterday’s Supreme Court decision in Burwell v. Hobby Lobby Stores, Inc. was at its heart a case about religious liberty and women’s health. But it was also a case about employee compensation. Two companies, Hobby Lobby and Conestoga Wood Specialties, objected to the federal government’s decision to include contraceptives in mandated health insurance. Putting aside the constitutional issues, the case raises an important question: What’s the proper role of employers in providing benefits, such as health insurance, to employees?

Put simply, all wages are compensation but not all compensation takes the form of wages. If you have health insurance through your job, then the funds spent to purchase the insurance is part of your compensation. The same goes to contributions to retirement saving plans such as 401(k) plans. Your employer can compensate you in many ways that go beyond cash compensation.

Over the past 60 years, employers have, on average, shifted toward those other ways. Researchers at the Economic Policy Institute put together data on the long-term trends in compensation. According to their calculations, the average hourly wage was about 93 percent of average compensation in 1948. By 2013, wages were a smaller portion of compensation, dropping to just over 80 percent of average compensation.

So the shift toward more non-wage benefits for many employees has changed the composition of compensation but it has not altered trend in the inequality of compensation, which is the same as wage inequality—rising.

A look at current Bureau of Labor Statistics data can show the specific forms of compensation. (Note: the data from EPI and the BLS do not perfectly match due to different data sets and the fact that they look at slightly different groups of workers.) According to the Employer Costs for Employee Compensation data set, wages and salaries for all private-sector workers are about 70 percent of compensation in the first quarter of 2014. All paid leave, including vacation, holidays, sick leave, were 7 percent of total compensation. Employer contributions to private insurance, such as health insurance, were about 8 percent of compensation. Retirement savings plans were just under 4 percent of compensation. And contributions to Social Security, Medicare, and unemployment insurance make up another 8 percent of compensation.

But of course, these numbers are all averages. A vast number of American workers have no access to these programs and don’t receive compensation in these forms. Many employers don’t provide health insurance or access to a retirement savings program. And employers are under no legal obligation to provide paid family leave insurance. Denying some workers access to these programs is not only discriminatory but also makes the pay-setting process less transparent. The locked-out workers would see a reduction in wages in return for these benefits, but given the willingness of other workers to take this trade-off many of these workers may do the same.

Given the wide range of employee benefits provided by employers and the difficulty in sometimes providing those benefits, we have to ask if employers are the right vehicles for providing some non-wage benefits. Perhaps the provision of some these benefits are better handled by the federal government. And some benefits might be best left for workers to purchase in the market with their wage earnings. These questions about the proper role of employer and government in providing benefits are some of the most controversial in our policy debates. But that intensity is just a sign that they are the questions we should be asking and need to answer.

Things to Read on the Morning of July 1, 2014

Should-Reads:

  1. Adrianna Macintyre: The Hobby Lobby decision is only about birth control: “The Supreme Court decided in a 5-4 split that ‘closely-held’ corporations cannot be compelled to cover birth control in their insurance benefits…. The opinion is written narrowly enough that it doesn’t allow companies to touch benefits that aren’t contraceptives…. Justice Alito addresses the issue specifically in the majority opinion: ‘This decision concerns only the contraceptive mandate and should not be understood to hold that all insurance-coverage mandates, e.g., for vaccinations or blood transfusions, must necessarily fall if they conflict with an employer’s religious beliefs.’ That means that corporations–no matter how closely held–cannot use this decision to start denying coverage for other services based on religious beliefs…”

  2. Scott Lemieux: Hobby Lobby and the War on Women: “Shorter Sam Alito: ‘When Congress said that the executive cannot impose a “substantial burden” on the religious beliefs of “persons,” it meant that it cannot impose “any burden, no matter how trivial and no matter what the burden to third parties” on “closely held corporations.” However, our consideration is limited to the present circumstances, for the problem of women and their strange parts generally presents many complexities…'”

  3. Nick Bunker: The Decline of Unions in America Abetted More by Supreme Court: “Justice Samuel Alito, writing for a five-justice majority, found that some public-sector workers cannot be compelled to pay certain fees to unions…. After an earlier Supreme Court decision, Communication Workers of America v. Beck, workers covered by collective bargaining agreements can’t be compelled to pay membership fees. But they must pay agency fees to cover the union’s collective bargaining efforts. What was at stake in today’s Harris v. Quinn decision was the ability of public-sector unions to compel workers to pay the agency fee…. Private-sector unionization rates have dropped significantly from 24.2 percent in 1973 to 6.7 percent in 2013 while public sector rates have actually increased from 23 percent to 35.3 percent over the same period. The decline of private-sector union membership is a major contributor to the rise in income inequality over the past 30 plus years. This decline is responsible for between 15 percent to 20 percent of the rise in wage inequality for male workers between 1973 and 1993, according to… David Card…”

Should Be Aware of:

And:

  1. Jessica Valenti: The Hobby Lobby ruling proves men of the law still can’t get over ‘immoral’ women having sex: “Thirty-five years ago… Ellen Willis wrote, ‘it is depressing to have to insist that sex is not an unnecessary, morally dubious self-indulgence but a basic human need, no less for women than for men’. If it was depressing in 1979, it looks downright miserable today…. The underlying values that drove this company to sue… is the belief that women having pre-marital or non-procreative sex is wrong. There is a reason that the first large-scale cultural reaction to the issue of insurance coverage for birth control was a female law student being called a ‘slut’. Sandra Fluke’s testimony to a congressional committee in favor of contraceptive coverage for a friend’s serious medical condition set off an apoplectic frenzy of sexually-based attacks on her…. Legal decisions about contraception have always been based, at least in part, on concerns about women’s potential promiscuity. The supreme court decision in Eisenstadt v Baird… was sparked by the arrest of William Baird after he handed a condom to an unmarried woman… his action violated Massachusetts law on “crimes against chastity”. Decades later, we’ve seen the conservative obsession with women’s sexual purity restrict access to Plan B and the HPV vaccine…. The message about women and sex remains the same…”

  2. Winston Churchill (1940): “The fierce and bitter controversies which hung around [Neville Chamberlain] in recent times were hushed by the news of his illness and are silenced by his death. In paying a tribute of respect and of regard to an eminent man who has been taken from us, no one is obliged to alter the opinions which he has formed or expressed upon issues which have become a part of history; but at the Lychgate we may all pass our own conduct and our own judgments under a searching review. It is not given to human beings, happily for them, for otherwise life would be intolerable, to foresee or to predict to any large extent the unfolding course of events. In one phase men seem to have been right, in another they seem to have been wrong. Then again, a few years later, when the perspective of time has lengthened, all stands in a different setting. There is a new proportion. There is another scale of values. History with its flickering lamp stumbles along the trail of the past, trying to reconstruct its scenes, to revive its echoes, and kindle with pale gleams the passion of former days. What is the worth of all this? The only guide to a man is his conscience; the only shield to his memory is the rectitude and sincerity of his actions. It is very imprudent to walk through life without this shield, because we are so often mocked by the failure of our hopes and the upsetting of our calculations; but with this shield, however the fates may play, we march always in the ranks of honour. It fell to Neville Chamberlain in one of the supreme crises of the world to be contradicted by events, to be disappointed in his hopes, and to be deceived and cheated by a wicked man. But what were these hopes in which he was disappointed? What were these wishes in which he was frustrated? What was that faith that was abused? They were surely among the most noble and benevolent instincts of the human heart-the love of peace, the toil for peace, the strife for peace, the pursuit of peace, even at great peril, and certainly to the utter disdain of popularity or clamour. Whatever else history may or may not say about these terrible, tremendous years, we can be sure that Neville Chamberlain acted with perfect sincerity according to his lights and strove to the utmost of his capacity and authority, which were powerful, to save the world from the awful, devastating struggle in which we are now engaged. This alone will stand him in good stead as far as what is called the verdict of history is concerned…”

  3. Ruth Bader Ginsburg: Dissent on the Hobby Lobby Contraception Decision: “Religious organizations exist to foster the interests of persons subscribing to the same religious faith. Not so of for-profit corporations….” “Any decision to use contraceptives made by a woman covered under Hobby Lobby’s or Conestoga’s plan will not be propelled by the Government, it will be the woman’s autonomous choice, informed by the physician she consults….” “It bears note in this regard that the cost of an IUD is nearly equivalent to a month’s full-time pay for workers earning the minimum wage….” “Would the exemption…extend to employers with religiously grounded objections to blood transfusions (Jehovah’s Witnesses); antidepressants (Scientologists); medications derived from pigs, including anesthesia, intravenous fluids, and pills coated with gelatin (certain Muslims, Jews, and Hindus); and vaccinations[?]… Not much help there for the lower courts bound by today’s decision….” “Approving some religious claims while deeming others unworthy of accommodation could be ‘perceived as favoring one religion over another,’ the very risk the Establishment Clause was designed to preclude.”

  4. Lawrence Summers: U.S. Economic Prospects: Secular Stagnation, Hysteresis, and the Zero Lower Bound: “The nature of macroeconomics has changed dramatically in the last seven years. Now, instead of being concerned with minor adjustments to stabilize about a given trend, concern is focused on avoiding secular stagnation. Much of this concern arises from the long- run effects of short-run developments and the inability of monetary policy to accomplish much more when interest rates have already reached their lower bound. This address analyzes contemporary macroeconomic problems and proposes solutions to put the U.S. economy back on a path toward healthy growth.”

Already-Noted Must-Reads:

  1. Ryan Avent: Monetary policy: Dead economies blow no bubbles: “The stopped clock that is the Bank for International Settlements is showing the same face…. In 2011… the BIS argued that global growth needed to slow in order to reduce inflationary pressure. In 2012 it warned that central banks shouldn’t do any more to boost growth lest they create financial instability and discourage structural reform…. In its latest annual report, it argues that what the world needs now is higher interest rates. One of these days the BIS may just turn out to be right. Not this year…. Low rates are not doing much to help the real economy, BIS says, but are contributing to another worrying credit boom…. Because it knows the result it wants (higher interest rates) it misreads the particular risks of the moment…. It was until very recently taken for granted that loose money meant policy that allows for excessively fast demand growth…. Rich economies currently suffer from none of those ailments. One could conclude then that policy is not too loose. Instead, the BIS, which is pretty sure that it is, finds a different measure of policy looseness with which to justify its call for higher rates: the financial cycle…. Raising rates now would almost certainly be counterproductive…. As markets priced in a perpetual slump (and lower inflation or deflation) long-term interest rates would edge even lower. Weak demand would also reduce the growth boost to structural forms, making them a harder sell, and would lead to still more deterioration in public balance sheets…”

  2. Ralph Nader: October 20, 2000: “The only difference between Al Gore and George W. Bush is the velocity with which their knees hit the floor when corporations knock…. George W. Bush we can dismiss with a summary comment: nothing more than a corporation disguised as a human being. There’s no end to [Gore’s] betrayal…. All I can see is this Pinocchio nose coming…. He exudes a lack of credibility…. If it were a choice between a provocateur and an ‘anesthetizer’, I’d rather have a provocateur. It would mobilize us…”

  3. Unlearning Economics: Capital in Pikettys Capital: “Although Piketty relates his framework back to the neoclassical production function, it plays only a supporting role (he refers to Cobb-Douglas somewhat disparagingly as a ‘simple story’), and his conception of ‘capital’, as defined above, is far more general than a literal interpretation of the production function might suggest…. Rognlie’s argument takes the estimates of the elasticity as central…. Piketty only references elasticity estimates for support, and actually stakes most of his claim that diminishing returns will not become a problem on historical observation: ‘On the basis of historical data, one can estimate an elasticity between 1.3 and 1.6. But not only is this estimate uncertain and imprecise. More than that, there is no reason why the technologies of the future should exhibit the same elasticity as those of the past. The only thing that appears to be relatively well established is that the tendency for the capital/income ratio β to rise…. To be sure, it is likely that the return on capital, r, will decrease as β increases. But on the basis of historical experience, the most likely outcome is that the volume effect will outweigh the price effect, which means that the accumulation effect will outweigh the decrease in the return on capital.’ This is not to say that Rognlie’s arguments are not worth considering, and he makes some good points… that the returns to new, IT-based technologies are not especially high… that, absent housing housing bubbles, capital’s share of income has declined in many countries over the past few decades…”

  4. Federal Reserve Bank San Francisco Will Inflation Remain LowYifan Cao and Adam Shapiro:Will Inflation Remain Low?: “The well-known Phillips curve suggests that future inflation depends on current and past inflation and a measure of economic slack or resource utilization. Using the unemployment gap to measure slack, a simple Phillips curve currently predicts that inflation will remain quite low through 2015. Two variations of the model, which impose a higher anchor for inflation expectations or focus only on a short-term unemployment gap, still predict that inflation will remain low, albeit higher than implied by the basic model…”

  5. Chris Dillow: How I would defend inequality: “Defenders of inequality are doing a desperately poor job. Tim Worstall’s claim that the tax and benefit system already does a lot of redistribution fails to engage with the argument that pre-tax inequality might be a bad thing. And Greg Mankiw’s claim that the rich deserve their fortune barely counts as an effort. Even if we concede–heroically–that high salaries are due to high marginal productivity, questions remain such as: what about Rawls’ claim that talents are arbitrary from a moral point of view? Do people really deserve to have been born at a time when their marginal productivity is high[?]… And even if people do deserve credit for cultivating their own ability, they hardly deserve credit for the fact that others’ inability to do so renders their ability scarce…. More intelligent rightists, such as Hayek or Nozick, have acknowledged that the link between merit and income is weak. So, is it possible to defend inequality better? The issue here is not one of free markets: it’s perfectly possible for a free marketeer to worry about inequality precisely because so much of it arises from market imperfections or state interventions such as bank subsidies, QE, crony capitalism or copyright laws.
     
    “Subject to that caveat, here’s how I would try to defend inequality: 1. [If] bosses and bankers… were paid less, they would seek other ways of satisfying their self-regard…. There’s a reason why the word ‘efficiency’ appears in the phrase ‘efficiency wage models’. It’s because it might be efficient to bribe workers not to exploit their power…. Some policies to curb high salaries would merely shift incomes between the rich…. One of the best ways to increase equality would be to create countervailing power…. But there is no demand for such policies…. It’s our neighbour’s new car or our colleague’s pay rise that upsets us from day to day, not footballers’ million-pound salaries…. One big fact… warns us not to expect a growth bonanza from egalitarian policies…. [because] long-term economic growth doesn’t vary much across countries or time…. I’m not sure about these arguments…. But I suspect they are better than wibble about desert.”

Morning Must-Read: Chris Dillow: How I Would Defend Inequality

Chris Dillow: How I would defend inequality: “Defenders of inequality are doing a desperately poor job….

…Tim Worstall’s claim that the tax and benefit system already does a lot of redistribution fails to engage with the argument that pre-tax inequality might be a bad thing. And Greg Mankiw’s claim that the rich deserve their fortune barely counts as an effort. Even if we concede–heroically–that high salaries are due to high marginal productivity, questions remain such as: what about Rawls’ claim that talents are arbitrary from a moral point of view? Do people really deserve to have been born at a time when their marginal productivity is high[?]… And even if people do deserve credit for cultivating their own ability, they hardly deserve credit for the fact that others’ inability to do so renders their ability scarce…. More intelligent rightists, such as Hayek or Nozick, have acknowledged that the link between merit and income is weak. So, is it possible to defend inequality better? The issue here is not one of free markets: it’s perfectly possible for a free marketeer to worry about inequality precisely because so much of it arises from market imperfections or state interventions such as bank subsidies, QE, crony capitalism or copyright laws.

Subject to that caveat, here’s how I would try to defend inequality: 1. [If] bosses and bankers… were paid less, they would seek other ways of satisfying their self-regard…. There’s a reason why the word ‘efficiency’ appears in the phrase ‘efficiency wage models’. It’s because it might be efficient to bribe workers not to exploit their power…. Some policies to curb high salaries would merely shift incomes between the rich…. One of the best ways to increase equality would be to create countervailing power…. But there is no demand for such policies…. It’s our neighbour’s new car or our colleague’s pay rise that upsets us from day to day, not footballers’ million-pound salaries…. One big fact… warns us not to expect a growth bonanza from egalitarian policies…. [because] long-term economic growth doesn’t vary much across countries or time…. I’m not sure about these arguments…. But I suspect they are better than wibble about desert.

The Federal Reserve Needs to Fulfill Its Global Role: Tuesday Focus for July 1, 2014

Over at Project Syndicate: The Federal Reserve Needs to Fulfill Its Global Role: The Federal Reserve these days is focusing well-nigh completely on the state of the US economy. It is broadly happy with its policies. I am not happy with its policies, not even from a narrow domestic demand-management perspective. Since mid 2007 policy has been and remains insufficiently expansionary: behind the curve. The policy most likely to succeed right now would be one of a shift in régime–analogous to what was carried out by Paul Volker in the U.S. 1979, by Franklin Delano Roosevelt in the U.S. in 1933, by Neville Chamberlain in Great Britain in 1931, and is being carried out by Shinzo Abe today.

But those of us who hold to my position and fear that the Federal Reserve’s failure to match the curve has not just greatly deepened the Lesser Depression but is also turning our cyclical unemployment into permanent long-term structural non-employment have lost the domestic monetary policy argument.

However, there is another policy argument that needs to be joined. The Federal Reserve is not just the central bank of the United States: it is the central bank for the world.

The United States is not just another large open economy in a world of flexible exchange rates capable of following its own monetary policy. The United States is a global hegemon. The Federal Reserve is thus a global central bank: the central bank for the world as well as the United States. It has a responsibility not just to stabilize output, employment, and inflation and ensure financial stability in the United States. It has a responsibility to successfully manage the world economy in its entirety: that means crafting policy in the interest of the world as a whole, and that means that its policy should take into account and compensate for market, institutional, governance, and policy failures elsewhere. One such ares of concern is the health and stability of growth in emerging markets as they attempt to (a) gain the benefits of capital inflows for development, (b) satisfy North Atlantic demands for open financial markets, and yet (c) manage the resulting instability created by “hot money”, the carry trade, irrational exuberance, and overshooting.

The most extraordinary problem facing the global economy today is the crisis of Europe, and of euros. Europe cannot resolve this crisis. It lacks the institutions of global governments to do so. What needs to happen is the northern and southern Europe need to rebalance their costs this is best done through insulation in the north rather than through deflation in the south. The problem is that European institutions within the euro zone cannot at least as presently constituted, deliver that outcome.

But leave that, too, to one side. Focus on the greatest institutional vulnerability in the world today and its devastating macroeconomic consequences: the manner in which the scope and governance of the eurozone was designed. That is the principal source of microeconomic distress and risk in the world today. That is a mammoth failure–in labor market flexibility, in the construction of the institution of a single currency that far exceeds what is justifiable on optimal currency-area principles, in what groups and interests are represented to what degree in the governing councils, and in the policies adopted–that it is the Federal Reserve’s duty to craft global monetary policy to attempt to offset and neutralize, to the limited degree that it can.

We all know what happened: The creation of the euro without an appropriate banking union or sufficient coordination between national-level banking regulators encouraged massive capital flows to southern Europe without proper risk calibration. Once the risks became clear, the money dried up, imposing an enormous deflationary shock on the south. The creation of the euro without an appropriate fiscal union meant that transfers from surplus to deficit regions would not rebalance or even cushion the maladjustments in demand. The fact that the eurozone lacked the labor market flexibility that would make it an optimal currency area meant that adjustment via the regional reallocation of economic activity would be glacial. The fact that the eurozone was a fixed currency zone ruled out adjustment via nominal depreciation.

There were only two roads to recovery: reflation in northern Europe to push up relative costs and boost the north’s demand for exports from the south to allow it to pay off its debts and deleverage, or deflation in southern Europe to push down its relative costs–at the price of deep depression and lost decades. And the way the institutions had been built, the voices of the interests in the governing councils pushed for the destructive policies that set Europe on the deflationary road, thus all but guaranteeing a failure of the European Union to deliver prosperity and growth for a period that will exceed a decade.

We have an example from the early twentieth century of what such a period of economic depression and stagnation does in politics, in Europe at least. The lesson from eighty years ago is that if parliamentary democracy does not deliver prosperity and growth, voters turn away from parliamentary democracy and toward nationalism, authoritarianism, and fascism. The interest group corruption, the corrupt corruption, and the near-gridlock of incremental parliamentary politics turns people off if the parliamentary régime does not deliver rough justice, prosperity, and growth. The reaction to what used to be called the cretinism of parliaments is the rise of movements that seek, instead, a leader: someone to tell people what to do. Such leaders soon learn that they have little better real solutions than anybody else. They decide that the best way to remain in the seats of power–because –is distraction. Identify the leaders with the group and the group with the leaders and so define critics of the leaders’ as deviant aliens outside the group who are not to be listened to. Silence outsiders and dissenters as deviant from the group. They decide that the best people to blame for the defects of the situation are those who cannot vote in national-level plebiscites: foreigners. Thus they turn to busying giddy minds with foreign quarrels, and making exaltation of the nation in what is at best a series of zero-sum nation-vs.-nation contests the focus of politics–one of the standard tools of power since the Lancastrian Dynasty.

It is in the strong medium- and long-run interest of United States not to have to deal with a Europe swirling with political currents that at the least flirt with nationalism, authoritarianism, and fascism. A prosperous parliamentary-democratic world is a much better and safer world for the United States to be in. And a world in which the United States has a proven record of fulfilling the trust it has taken on by assuming the role of global economic hegemon–and thus in which the United States is trusted to manage the global economy for the collective common good–is a much better world for the United States then one in which it is not trusted, and in which global macroeconomic management becomes the emergent result of nation-level race to the bottom policy struggles that at best zero-sum.

Right now is thus one of those moments in which the medium- and long-run national interest of the United States–political, security, and, yes, economic–requires the Federal Reserve to note that its proper policy mission is not to focus narrowly on attempting to achieve and maintain internal balance but rather to actively take on and successfully achieve its mandate as global central bank of balancing aggregate demand to potential supply for the world as a whole.