Afternoon Must-Read: James Pethokoukis vs. “Big Solar”

When there are negative externalities out there–political-military from boosting the incomes of not-very-friendly state actors like Muscovy and nonstate actors like Al Qaeda, narrow-environmental from local pollution, and broad-environmental from global warming–we like for the government to provide subsidies. Thus this from the usually-reliable James Pethokoukis strikes me as way, way, way off–subsidies for “Big Solar” are no more a problem than is the excessive power over our political system wielded by Big Poor Children:

James Pethokoukis:
Should Republicans Ignore Income Inequality? | National Review Online:
“Inequality has increased across advanced economies…

…Macro factors such as globalization and technology deserve most — but maybe not all — of the ‘blame.’ Big Government loves to pick winners and losers in the private sector. Some lucky ducks owe their place in the 1 percent or 0.1 percent or 0.01 percent to federal favoritism. Conservatives shouldn’t mind at all when value-creating innovators and entrepreneurs strike it rich while crony capitalists do not. The precious tax breaks and subsidies that go to rent seekers, such as those in the agriculture and alternative-energy sectors, should get the ax. Sorry, Big Sugar and Big Solar…

Slides for a Talk: Thoughts on Making a Better Economics

https://www.icloud.com/keynote/AwBUCAESEDBM_vLkLCQgT0Nu6oV4ZSsaKde5vm771OMPZatz7f4g5QMkCxthNIhPQ4-dDpWFxltBtWRq4rjoXxe_MCUCAQEEIEnMxkSumJovn1H0CTuhapGtUDqrCSAHUbr3ycqNRe1P#2014-11-13_INET_Presentation.key


Economic Methodology, Economic History, and Economic Thinking

Creating and supporting intellectual spaces in which insightful thoughts about how the economies of the present and the future work can be thought. As I see it, this requires combining a broad catholic range of empirical and theoretical inputs with effective quality control. But how?


Four Gaps:

  • Between what economists should say and what they do say
  • Between what economists do say among themselves and what they are heard to say outside the community
  • Between what economists are heard to say and what the public sphere concludes
  • Between what the public sphere concludes and what policies are actually implemented
  • Concentrate for now on the first two

What Went Wrong?:

  • In the development of economic theory
  • In the application of theory to policy before 2008
  • In the application of theory to policy since 2008
  • What economics was relevant?
    • Larry Summers and Martin Wolf at Bretton Woods
    • Bagehot, Minsky, Kindleberger
    • (Eichengreen, Akerlof, Woodford)

What Is Good and Bad Theory?:

  • Good theory is and can be nothing other than crystalized history
  • Microfoundations from first principles?
    • Paul Dirac’s relativistic electron’s magnetic moment: 1, 1.00118, 1.00115965221±4
    • Does this help us with protein folding and pharmaceutical molecule design?
    • Isaac Newton: “I can calculate the movement of the stars, but not the madness of men”
      • Lost £20000
    • True then, true now

Bad Theory:

  • Assuming infinitely-lived rational-expections representative agents
  • Waving your hands
  • Hoping that all heterogeneity and frictions will cancel out
  • Almost as bad theory
    • Assuming ILRERA
    • Adding one friction
    • Hoping that all other heterogeneity and frictions will cancel out
  • Robert Solow:
    • “Attaching a realistic or behavioral deviation to the Ramsey model does not confer microfoundational legitimacy on the combination”
    • “Quite the contrary: a story loses legitimacy and credibility when it is spliced to a simple, extreme, and… irrelevant special case”

Two Branches:

  • Creating space to build better economic theory * Better communicating economic theory
  • Second branch easier

Second Branch: Better Communicating Economic Theory:

  • What does history teach us?
  • Keynes: The End of Laissez-Faire
    • J.R. McCulloch’s parrot
    • Triumph of the popularizers
    • Marketeers: markets are efficient, governments are incompetent or corrupt
    • In Keynes’s day there were planners: governments harness collective purpose to technocratic plans, markets are wasteful
  • Need a grammar of forms of organization–market, hierarchy, plan, collective, yardstick competition, regulated monopoly, etc.–and when they work and when they do not
  • Consider that, historically, education, health, pensions, infrastructure, technology, security not amenable to market provision–and that those are growing

First Branch: Space to Build Better Economic Theory:

  • Knowledge of history the sine qua non
  • Catholic approach to modeling strategies–broadening the tool set
  • Somehow, exercising effective quality control

Jobless recoveries and the decline of startups

The slow U.S. labor market recovery from the Great Recession is a well-known, oft-lamented, and thought-provoking phenomenon. A famous graph by writer Bill McBride shows how long it has taken the labor market to return to its previous employment peak level: 51 months, or just over 4 years. The graph actually overstates the recovery, which is considerably slower than any other since the end of WWII, because it doesn’t account for population growth.

But notice that the two weakest recoveries before this one were those following the two most recent recessions, starting in 2001 and 1990. Labor market recoveries are becoming weaker and weaker. Paul Krugman has called these recoveries “postmodern.” But what is causing this decline in employment growth? A new paper argues that the decline in new businesses, or startups, could be responsible.

The paper is authored by economists Benjamin Pugsley and Ayşegül Şahin, both of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. The authors document the increasing age of businesses in the United States. What has happened since the mid-1980s is not that new business are more likely to fail or that they growth more quickly. Rather, the rate at which startups enter has fallen. What the labor market is left with is employment residing in more “grown-up” firms.

Shifting employment toward older firms could boost growth. Because “grown-up firms” are less affected by recessions, older firms have higher growth rates and smoother changes in employment. Or the effects could go the other way. A lack of startups could hinder employment growth, make employment growth more sensitive to economic recessions and mute the strength of employment recoveries.

The impact of this trend on labor markets isn’t clear until one looks at the data. When Pugsley and Şahin look closely, they find the negative effects from this startup deficit outweigh the benefits of having more employment in older firms. In particular, the impact of the startup deficit on business cycles fits in line with jobless recoveries: employment growth falls much more during recessions and employment doesn’t pick up as much when gross domestic product starts growing again. The authors calculate that if the startup rate were equal to its average from 1980 to 1985 then the employment recovery would be two years ahead of where it is now.

If Pugsley and Şahin’s research is correct, the labor market is suffering significantly from a lack of startups. But this isn’t to say this deficit is the only reason for jobless recoveries. The build-up in private debt and collapse of asset bubbles that Krugman highlights could be responsible as well. The fall-off in consumption independently reduces employment demand, and may in fact also be a cause of the decline in the startup rate.  Or it could be another reason altogether. But at the moment, no one is quite sure by how much each factor is affecting the slowdown. Sifting through these different hypotheses is a critical task for future research.

Nighttime Must-Read: Kevin Drum: Non-Chart of the Day: Where’s the Austerity?

Non Chart of the Day Where s the Austerity Mother Jones
Non Chart of the Day Where s the Austerity Mother Jones

Kevin Drum:
Non-Chart of the Day: Where’s the Austerity?:
“Tyler Cowen… [and] Angus….

‘Either austerity means nominal cuts and we never had any of it, or austerity means cuts relative to trend and we are still savagely in its grasp.’ Oh come on…. Let’s take a look at this chart done right… real per capita government expenditures…. This is what austerity looks like: a drop in government expenditures. For a little while, in 2009 and 2010, stimulus spending partially offset… but by the third quarter of 2010 the stimulus had run its course…. If you run this chart back for 50 years you’ll never see anything like it…. Finally, in 2014, the spending decline stops. Austerity is over, and we even start to see a small uptick. At the same time, the economy starts to pick up. This is not bulletproof evidence that austerity is bad for the economy, or that government spending helps it. But it’s certainly consistent with the hypothesis, and it’s really not hard to see.

Still Relevant: Sisyphus as Social Democrat: A Review of Richard Parker’s ‘John Kenneth Galbraith’

J. Bradford DeLong (2005): “Sisyphus as Social Democrat: A Review of Richard Parker’s ‘John Kenneth Galbraith'”, Foreign Affairs (May/June):

If there were justice in the world, John Kenneth Galbraith would rank as the twentieth century’s most influential American economist. He has published several books that are among the best analyses of modern U.S. history, played a key role in midcentury policymaking, and advised more presidents and senators than would seem possible in three lifetimes. Yet today, Galbraith’s influence on economics is small, and his influence on U.S. politics is receding by the year.

In this lively and thoughtful biography, Richard Parker sets himself the task of explaining Galbraith’s career: why it was so dazzling, and why its long-term impact has turned out to be so much less than expected. The result is not only the story of a smart, witty, and important man, but also a fascinating meditation on the rise and fall of twentieth-century American liberalism.

A MAN FOR ALL SEASONS

That Galbraith’s career has been dazzling nobody can dispute. Professors of post-World War II American history can still do no better than to assign his books The Affluent Society and The New Industrial State to teach students how the midcentury U.S. economy came to dominate the world (and what should have been done to make it work better). Anyone wanting to learn about the beginning of the Great Depression should start with The Great Crash; there is no other history of the stock-market crash of 1929 that is as short and even half as worthwhile. During World War II, Galbraith helped run the Office of Price Administration, working to square the growth-inflation circle by pushing production far above economists’ measures of potential output without sparking runaway price increases that would threaten the economic mobilization. And after the war, his work on the Defense Department’s “United States Strategic Bombing Survey” made Washington rethink the efficacy of its standard war-fighting policy — staying high in the sky and dropping lots of explosives on all kinds of people far below — although perhaps the rethinking did not go far enough.

Lots of ideas in the background of contemporary U.S. political and economic thought are Galbraith’s. His work as an economist was a scattered but comprehensive attempt to think through the consequences of the transition from a nation of small farms and workshops to one of large factories and superstores. In doing so, he took on many of the questions most central to the new U.S. economic landscape: How much can advertising shape demand? In a world of passive shareholders, autonomous managers and engineers, and firm decisions that emerge out of internal bureaucratic contests, just what are the objectives that drive big firms? How does competition work when its principal dimensions are quality and marketing rather than price? And critically, how do the limits of polite discourse allow the system to hold itself together while constraining its flexibility?

For decades, Galbraith’s influence in politics was unmatched by any other economist. The pieces of his advice best remembered are those that went against the “conventional wisdom” (a now ubiquitous phrase that Galbraith coined): strategic bombing did not win World War II; Vietnam was a strategically unimportant quagmire where the United States would do more harm than good; macroeconomic “fine tuning” is likely to blow up in the face of policymakers; the businessman’s capacity for self-delusion is nearly infinite.

Galbraith sees the United States as a would-be social democracy that has lost its way, assuming that if only the self-serving declarations of the right could be wiped away, the benefits of a bigger, more activist government would become obvious to everyone. The right-wing claim that the most efficient economy is one in which the gales of perfect competition scour the land is, in Galbraith’s view, nonsense. Modern industrial and post-industrial production is a large-scale process, large-scale processes require planning, and planning requires stability — which means that the gales of the market must be calmed.

This political vision, however, has been in retreat since the early 1980s. Nobody wants to hear about the importance of Big Government, Big Bureaucracy, or Big Labor (which hardly even exists). Galbraith’s economic views have undergone an even more distressing eclipse. Among economists (excluding economic historians), the 70-year-olds have read Galbraith and think he is very important; the 50-year-olds have read Galbraith and know that the 70-year-olds think he is important but are not sure why; and the 30-year-olds have not even read him.

Parker has an explanation — a relatively convincing one — for the retreat of Galbraith’s politics. The story behind it is the Democratic establishment’s loss of nerve. Too many party intellectuals and politicians drink cocktails on Martha’s Vineyard, in Parker’s view, and too few spend time on the shop floor learning what issues are important to those sweeping up or manning an assembly line or tending the convenience-store cash register from midnight to six a.m. Thus, the mass base of the Democratic Party has withered, and without a mass base Democratic politicians listen too much to their rich contributors and turn into Eisenhower Republicans — people who are interested above all in balancing the budget. Galbraith, a committed social democrat, has wielded his pen and his tongue in an effort to halt this decades-long rightward drift. But he has failed: his allies are too few, and the loss of nerve among the party elite is too complete.

Parker also has an explanation — also a relatively convincing one — for the eclipse of Galbraith’s economic thought. The story here is of the blindness of an academic establishment steeped in Paul Samuelson’s Foundations of Economic Analysis. Economists, Parker believes, have sold their birthright for a tasteless pottage of mathematical models. As a result, they can say much about theory but little about reality. And they ignore Galbraith because he is a guilt-inducing reminder of how much broader and more relevant economics can be.

WHAT WOULD GALBRAITH DO?

This explanation, however, is far from complete. Late-twentieth-century American economics centers on the use of mathematical models to reach one of two conclusions: that the market is already doing a good job, or that some imperfection is causing “market failure” and correcting or counterbalancing the imperfection will make everything okay.
Thus there are New Classical macroeconomists, who believe that the market works fine and that even depressions are necessary and inevitable; Monetarists, who believe that recessions result from failures in the banking system, which can be corrected by ensuring stable growth of the money supply; and New Keynesians, who are indistinguishable from Monetarists save for their identification of market failures in the labor market or in the investment decisions of firms.

In all these cases, it is clear what an economist must do to belong to a particular school: start underneath the lamppost, take a few steps in one direction by describing a market failure, and then start searching for lost keys. New Classicals master the solutions of “dynamic stochastic general- equilibrium representative-agent models.” Monetarists analyze the details of the financial system in an effort to define a “neutral monetary policy.” New Keynesians trace the implications of subtle differences in labor- and capital-market failures.

Just what a “Galbraithian” economist would do, however, is not clear. For Galbraith, there is no single market failure, no single serpent in the Eden of perfect competition. He starts from the ground and works up: What are the major forces and institutions in a given economy, and how do they interact? A graduate student cannot be taught to follow in Galbraith’s footsteps. The only advice: Be supremely witty. Write very well. Read very widely. And master a terrifying amount of institutional detail.

Harry Johnson, in his superb but not entirely fair critique of Milton Friedman’s Monetarists, said that in order to carry out an intellectual revolution in economics, one must propound a doctrine that has three qualities: it can be summarized in a single sentence, it provides the young with an excuse for ignoring the work of their elders, and it tells the young what they can do to further the revolution. John Maynard Keynes and Friedman both offered such doctrines. They said, respectively, that “aggregate demand determines supply” and that “inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon”; they dismissed their predecessors as obsolete; and they set hundreds of young to the task of estimating consumption, investment, and money-demand functions.

Galbraith propounded no such easily summarized doctrine. The closest we can get is: “the world is complicated, and both right-wing ideology and the conventional wisdom that is this age’s self- image are terribly wrong.” He offered critiques that required you to read and understand old theories, not new theories that allowed you to dismiss everything prior as irrelevant.

The result? Nearly all economists today are Paul Samuelson’s children. Many are Keynes’ children. Friedman, Robert Lucas, Robert Solow, and James Tobin all have plenty of descendants. But there are few Galbraithians on the ground. Would economics as a discipline be stronger if the 50-year- old and 30-year-old economists had a better appreciation of Galbraith? Almost surely. Will the winds of economic fashion shift and cause economists to appreciate Galbraith once again? For that to happen, an astute young economist would have to devote himself to “mathing up” chapters of The Affluent Society and The New Industrial State and publishing them in journals — not a likely prospect in today’s risk-adverse academic environment.

ALGER LIVES

Galbraith’s life traces an arc through an age in which three gigantic shocks appeared to transform U.S. politics. The Great Depression convinced the upwardly mobile that they could be downwardly mobile too, the middle class that it and the working class had common interests, and high-wire entrepreneurs that even they needed government to provide a strong safety net — hence Franklin Roosevelt’s New Deal. Then the self-destruction of the Old Republican Party in the wake of its takeover by Barry Goldwater led to a decade of Democratic dominance that brought forth Lyndon Johnson’s Great Society. And finally, with the advent of Richard Nixon’s “southern strategy,” the base of the northern Democratic Party moved to the left, leading to a decade of southern conservative Democrats voting for northern Democratic liberals to chair committees and run Congress. This was the age of Galbraith’s ascendancy — an age during which the United States looked to be moving ever closer to his vision of the good society.

But all these shocks turned out to be temporary. The middle class no longer fears impoverishment at the hands of another Great Depression, as it did in the 1950s, and it is less certain that it shares interests with the working class. Republican legislators may still feel that extremism in the defense of liberty is no vice, but they are now smart enough to keep quiet about it. The Democratic South has morphed into the Republican South, and enough electricity to power Illinois and New York could be produced if only one could attach magnets to Abraham Lincoln and William Seward as they spin in their graves.

What has survived throughout is the American myth of rugged individualism, and it is this that Parker’s political story neglects. The power of this myth has meant that the United States is not, and never will be, a European-style social democracy. People may come together for barn raisings, but America is still the land of upward mobility and opportunity, where the most common questions are, I’ve done it, so why haven’t you? and Doesn’t this social solidarity stuff mean that I’ve got to pull more than my share of the weight? In spirit, it is still a nation of upwardly mobile immigrants blessed with an abundance of resources (free land) and an absence of government constraints (free labor).

Galbraith would say, sardonically, that this national self-image is just another fraudulent piece of conventional wisdom — nurtured by the delusional, who cannot see reality, and the rich, who see it all too well but know that such delusions make them richer and more powerful. And Galbraith would be more than half right. But this self-image is also a very powerful social fact, and this more than anything else explains his waning influence on U.S. politics. It is not that the Democratic establishment has lost its nerve or been seduced by law firms and lobbyists; it is that the old Horatio Alger myth has proved extraordinarily durable.

At the beginning of the twenty-first century, it has become clear who John Kenneth Galbraith really is: Sisyphus, constantly pushing the boulder of social-democratic enlightenment up the hill. But the hill, it turns out, is too steep, and Galbraith not mighty enough.

Things to Read on the Afternoon of January 10, 2014

Must- and Shall-Reads:

 

  1. Raj Chetty:
    Behavioral Economics and Public Policy
  2. Andrew Kaczynski (2012):
    Mitt Romney’s Long, Careful Health Care Evolution:
    “Romney’s path… tracked a hardening Republican reaction… in real time…. January 30[, 2009] speech… [called for] market dynamics, free choice, and personal responsibility, a phrase typically used to refer to the individual mandate…. [On] February 27, Romney said: ‘We need to advance a conservative plan… based on free choice, personal responsibility, and private medicine… like what I proposed in Massachusetts… the plan is a good model.’… In May, Romney wrote an op-ed… largely based off his Massachusetts plan, including an individual mandate…. On June 1… Romney thanked Heritage for helping craft health care reform in Massachusetts…. On June 14 Romney… said the President could learn from RomneyCare, saying: ‘I understand the President considers his plan in respects following the model of Massachusetts. Let’s learn from our experience.’… [On] June 24 Romney said… of the President reviving the exchanges put in place in RomneyCare, ‘we put together an exchange, and the president’s copying that idea. I’m glad to hear that’…
  3. Paul Krugman:
    Orthodoxy, Heterodoxy, Ideology:
    “I’m very much in accord with Simon Wren-Lewis on the remarkable unhelpfulness of recent heterodox assaults… misidentifies the problem… gives aid and comfort to the wrong people…. Standard macroeconomics does NOT justify the attacks on fiscal stimulus and the embrace of austerity…. Formal modeling and quantitative analysis doesn’t justify the austerian position; on the contrary, austerians had to throw out the models and abandon statistical principles to justify their claims…. So if you go around claiming that model-oriented, quantitative economics gave rise to austerity mania, you’re getting the story all wrong… [and] covering up for the austerians’ intellectual sins…”
  4. Nick Bunker:
    Weekend Reading:
    “Frances Coppola on the fiscal theory of monetary expansion… Ben Walsh argues that the boom in oil jobs… is over…. Shane Ferro reports that one million Americans are at risk of losing access to the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program…. The United States has the highest GDP per capita, but as Matt Bruenig shows, incomes at the bottom are higher in other developed countries…. What explains the decline in the labor share of income? Dylan Matthews looks into the competing hypotheses…. Cardiff Garcia lays out his observations from the annual Allied Social Sciences Associations meeting…. Ben Casselman and Andrew Flowers… noticed that economists seem to be more engaged with policy.”
  5. Tim Duy:
    Wage Growth–Lack of–Continues to Surprise:
    “The December employment report… surprising combination of solid job gains and decelerating wage growth…. Overall, the story is one of ongoing improvement in labor markets…. Wage growth, however, nosedived…. If June rolls around with no inflation and no greater wage growth, the Fed will find it challenging to begin normalization…. The wage numbers present a dilemma for the Fed. Simply put, no wage growth means the Fed can’t be particularly confident that inflation will trend toward target…. The Fed is still looking at June, but they need some more help from the data. Of course, June is still a long way off…”
  6. Tim Worstall:
    Someone Needs To Tell Vox.com That Numbers Don’t Work Quite This Way:
    “A TEU being a twenty foot container equivalent unit, the standard measure of these things, half the size of the container you see on an 18 wheeler trucking rig…. You can get 30 cubic metres of packing peanuts into one and not have to worry very much about the weight. But 30 cubic metres of gold or lead placed on the back of a truck will have the axles exploding into metal shards pretty much instantaneously…. Less than half the density of water and it’s volume that is important. More than that and it’s the weight…. The larger picture about shipping and containerisation [is that] it’s almost certainly true that this one technology is vying with the mobile phone as being the most important influence upon our lifestyles since WWII. Certainly vastly more important than anything that has come out of Congress or the House of Commons in that time. If you want to know quite how much difference then I recommend The Box (although I think he manages to underplay the economic impact)….And both the Vox and BBC pieces are interesting as well. Even if MSC Oscar cannot in fact carry 900 million cans of dog food.”
  7. Mark Thoma:
    Retail jobs are better than you might think:
    “Many workers shy away from retail jobs believing they’re occupations with low pay, low benefits and low opportunity. Is this true? Are they mostly dead-end, minimum wage jobs?.. While these jobs do not pay as well as jobs in the manufacturing sector, large, modern, multi-establishment retail chains pay better than many people believe and offer better opportunities for advancement than many other occupations…. Retail pays better than service sector jobs: ‘…service occupations paid $13.97 and $11.15 for men and women, respectively, while retail occupations paid $16.28 and $12.79…’ In addition, although retail jobs pay less on average than manufacturing jobs, employment in manufacturing has declining, while the growth in retail has been ‘pronounced.’ In 1963, multi-establishment retail chains accounted for 20 percent of all retail. But by 2000, the share had grown to 35 percent, and it has continued to grow since. Furthermore, and importantly, retail jobs offer more opportunity for advancement than most other jobs due to the high rate of growth of retail establishments and the multi-tiered nature of these firms…”
  8. Mark Thoma:
    Economist’s View: The Mythical Confidence Fairy):
    “After harming the recovery from the Great Recession–and making it harder for the unemployed to find jobs–through austerity, blocking jobs bills, and standing in the way of additional stimulus measures, Republicans are trying to take credit for the recovery. They made things worse, and when they stopped doing harmful things, the economy improved and they want credit for that…. That deserves ridicule. Republicans were terribly wrong about Federal Reserve policy, just as wrong about austerity and the confidence fairy, yet here they are once again telling us that the confidence fairy rather than the end of their awful policy is responsible for the recovery.”

Should Be Aware of:

 

  1. Jack Baruth:
    Why Chrysler’s rotary gear selector is the way of the future: “Your parents went on month-long roadtrips carrying only a crumpled map and a classical education but you have to take five electronic devices and three food items just to pick up your 0.8 children from their aftercare program. There’s no room for any of it in your car. It’s one thing to put up with this indignity so you can drive a Dodge Viper TA 2.0, but are you really willing to deal with having a 2.1-amp-rapid-charged iPhone 6XXS raising the temperature between your legs to Death Valley levels all day because your center console is devoted to pretending your mid-priced sedan or luxury-equipped CUV has a fake stick shift?…”
  2. Glenn Fleishman:
    The Software and Services Apple Needs to Fix: “Marco Arment’s excellent post on Apple’s current state of development has this pithy sentence: ‘The software quality has fallen so much in the last few years that I’m deeply concerned for its future.’… None of us think Apple will go out of business. Rather, that we will lose the reasons we have selected using Apple’s products over those of other companies…”
  3. Rebecca Schoenkopf:
    Inside The Collapse of The New Yorker’s Inside The Collapse of The New Republic: “We haven’t had much–or anything?–to say about the mass hissyfit at The New Republic, because, honestly, how could we care? But that was before we read Ryan Lizza’s Inside the Collapse of The New Republic at the New Yorker, to which we could only sit at our kitchen table and moan OH SAVE US SWEET JESUS. Lizza, a TNR alumnus who points out he is hardly an impartial observer–which is fine!–paints the whole wretched episode in gleaming detail. But the details he unearths–how to put this–make his colleagues and cohorts look like a bunch of petty children so insulated in their shiny, important workplace they’ve forgotten how the rest of the world, not to mention journalism, works…”
  4. Pascal-Emmanuel Gobry:
    How the Catholic Church made its peace with Charlie Hebdo – The Week:
    “At the Second Vatican Council, the Catholic Church… accept[ed] religious freedom and pluralism. But let’s face it: the Catholic Church fought liberalism, and lost. I love the Catholic Church more than anything in the world, and I hope I would die for her if I had to–but I am glad she lost. Charlie Hebdo reminded me that… I am also a man of Enlightenment liberalism…. An attack against people with whom I disagree on almost everything [is] an attack on my values, on what I believe in and cherish. That is the value system that any civilization worth cherishing must incorporate–and that is the value system that we must defend against these jihadi barbarians.”
  5. Paul Krugman:
    Deflation As Betrayal:
    “Ambrose Evans-Pritchard writes that Europe’s slide toward deflation amounts to a ‘betrayal’ of Southern Europe. This sounds over the top, but it is the simple truth…. The ECB should have been aggressively expanding as soon as it became clear that inflation was sliding. There should have been a determined effort to offset fiscal austerity in southern Europe with expansion in the north. Instead, inflation and deficit obsession were allowed to rule for years; and now the situation is very close to irretrievable. The market clearly thinks the cause is almost lost. German 5-year bonds are yielding zero; index bonds of the same maturity are yielding -0.2. That’s an implied forecast of just 0.2 percent inflation over the next five years, which means intense deflationary pressure in the south. Really not good.”
  6. Jim Henley:
    Jim’s Rule of Buts:
    “The most obvious example of the power of Jim’s Rule of Buts is the classic apology. Compare, ‘I’m sorry I yelled at you, but what you said made me really angry.’ and ‘What you said made me really angry, but I’m sorry I yelled at you.’ As a coordinating conjunction, ‘but’ joins independent and theoretically equal clauses. But in practice, what follows ‘but’ always dominates what precedes it. So if you really want to apologize, and really want to mollify your interlocutor, you really want to make sure the apology itself is in the dominant position. Otherwise, you’re not apologizing; you’re excusing…. If you really want to soothe rather than rile, learn Jim’s Rule of Buts today! It will do you good for many days to come.”

What Was and Is the Real Macroeconomic Research Frontier?: Daily Focus

Screenshot 3 13 13 8 40 AM

The last time I taught graduate macroeconomics to students about to take their pre-thesis oral exams was way, way, way, way back in 2003. This was what I thought then was the real research frontier in macroeconomics–the papers and directions which people should be extending and in which people should be working if they wanted to do economic research that would truly add to our stock of useful tools and boost our understanding of the macroeconomy.

Which of the bets that I wanted people to place more than a decade ago now have paid off? Which have not? What are the papers from which people should start thinking about further progress in these directions now? And what bets should I have advised graduate students a decade and more ago to make, but did not?

Brad DeLong : Economics 236: Your Last Course in Macroeconomics

PART I: A QUICK OVERVIEW

January 22: Introduction

  • Olivier Blanchard (2000), “What Do We Know About Macroeconomics that Fisher and Wicksell Did Not?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115:4 (November), pp. 1375-1410.
  • Olivier Blanchard (1990), “Why Does Money Affect Output? A Survey”, in B.M. Friedman and F. Hahn eds, Handbook of Monetary Economics, 1990, Vol 2, 779-835.

January 29: Unemployment and Institutions

  • Dale Mortensen and Christopher Pissarides (1994), “Job Creation and Job Destruction in the Theory of Unemployment,” Review of Economic Studies 61, pp 397-416.
  • Olivier Blanchard and Justin Wolfers (2000) “The Role of Shocks and Institutions in the Rise of European Unemployment: The Aggregate Evidence,” Economic Journal, 110 (March), pp. C 1 —33.
  • Olivier Blanchard and Lawrence Katz (1997), “What We Know and Do Not Know About the Natural Rate of Unemployment”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 11-1 (Winter), pp. 51-73.
  • Steven Nickell (1997), “Unemployment and Labor Market Rigidities: Europe versus North America”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 11-3 (Summer), pp. 55-74.

February 5: Contracts and Aggregate Output

  • Robert Townsend (1979) “Optimal Contracts and Competitive Markets with Costly State Verification”, Journal of Economic Theory 21 (October), pp. 265-293.
  • Benjamin Bernanke and Mark Gertler (1989), “Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations,” American Economic Review 79 (March), pp . 14-31.

February 12: Taking Technology-Shock Theories Seriously

  • Susanto Basu and John Fernald (2000), “Why Is Productivity Procyclical? Why Do We Care?” (Cambridge: NBER Working Paper W7940, October).
  • Andrei Shleifer (1986), “Implementation Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy 94-6 (December), pp. 1163-1190.
  • Dale Jorgenson and Kevin Stiroh (2000), “Raising the Speed Limit: U.S. Economic Growth in the Information Age,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2000-1 (Spring), pp. 125-235.

PART II: THE GROWING STRENGTH OF BEHAVIORALIST APPROACHES

February 19: The Rationale for Behavioralist Approaches

  • George Akerlof and Janet Yellen (1985), “Can Small Deviations from Rationality Make Significant Differences to Economic Equilibria?” American Economic Review 75-4 (September), pp. 708-20.
  • J. Bradford DeLong, Andrei. Shleifer, Lawrence Summers, and Robert Waldmann (1990), “Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets,” Journal of Political Economy 98-4 (August), pp. 703-38.
  • Richard Thaler (1986), “The Psychology and Economics Conference Handbook,” Journal of Business 59-4 part 2 (October), pp. S279 – 284.

February 26: Unemployment and Behavioral Economics

  • George Akerlof (1982), “Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange”, Quarterly Journal of Economics pp. 543-69.
  • Truman Bewley (1998), “Why Not Cut Pay?” European Economic Review pp. 459-490.
  • Matt Rabin (1998), “Economics and Psychology,” Journal of Economic Literature 36-1 (March)pp. 11-46.

March 5: Money Illusion and Aggregate Output

  • George Akerlof and Janet Yellen (1985), “A Near-Rational Model of the Business Cycle, with Wage and Price Inertia,” Quarterly Journal of Economics pp. 823-838.
  • Robert Shiller (1997) “Public Resistance to Indexation: A Puzzle”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1997-1 (Spring), pp. 159-228.
  • E. Shafir, P. Diamond, and A. Tversky (1997), “Money Illusion”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 112-2 (May), pp. 341-374.
  • George Akerlof, William Dickens, and George Perry, “The Macroeconomics of Low Inflation”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1996-1 (Spring), pp. 1-76

March 12: Savings and Economic Psychology

  • David Laibson (1997), “Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112-2 (May), pp. 443-77.
  • D Laibson, A. Repetto, and J. Tobacman (1998), “Self-Control and Saving for Retirement”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1998-1 (Spring), pp. 91-196.
  • D Laibson, A. Repetto, and J. Tobacman (1998), “A Debt Puzzle” http://www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/laibson/papers.html.
  • E. Duflo and E. Saez (2001), “Participation and Investment Decisions in a Retirement Plan: The Influence of Colleagues’ Choices” (Cambridge: NBER Working Paper W7735).

March 19: What Should Investors Do?

  • Hal Varian (1987), “The Arbitrage Principle in Financial Economics,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1-2 (Fall), pp. 55-72.
  • Stephen LeRoy (1989), “Efficient Capital Markets and Martingales,” Journal of Economic Literature 27, pp. 1583-1621.
  • Narayana R Kocherlakota (1995), “The Equity Premium: It’s Still a Puzzle,” Journal of Economic Literature, 1996-1, pp. 42-72.
  • John H. Cochrane (1991), “Volatility Tests and Efficient Markets: A Review Essay, Journal of Monetary Economics 27, pp. 463-485.

April 2: What Do Investors Do?

  • Terence Odean (1998), “Are Investors Reluctant to Realize Their Losses?” Journal of Finance, pp. 1775-1798
  • Terence Odean (1999), “Do investors trade too much?” American Economic Review (December).
  • Andrei Shleifer and Robert Vishny (), “The Limits of Arbitrage”, Journal of Finance 52, 25-55.

April 9: Whither Behavioral Macro?

  • Matt Rabin (2001), “Risk Aversion and Expected-Utility Theory: A Calibration Theorem”, Econometrica http://emlab.Berkeley.EDU/users/rabin/wpapers2.html
  • John Gruber and Botond Koszegi (2001), “Is Addiction ‘Rational’?: Theory and Evidence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116-4 (Fall), pp. 1261-1305.
  • Xavier Gabaix and David Laibson (2001) “Bounded rationality and directed cognition” http://web.mit.edu/xgabaix/www/papers.html.
  • E. Fehr, E. S. and Gachter (1998), “Reciprocity and Economics: The Economic Implications of Homo Reciprocans”, European Economic Review pp.845-59 http://www.iew.unizh.ch/home/fehr/.
  • Matt Rabin (1993), “Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics”, American Economic Review 103, pp.1058-82.

PART III: GROWTH ONE LAST TIME

April 16: Corruption and Political Blockages to Growth

  • Andrei Shleifer and Robert Vishny (1992), “Corruption,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, pp. 599-618.
  • Paulo Mauro (1995), “Corruption and Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110-3, pp. 681-713.
  • Jonathan Temple and Paul Johnson (1998), “Social Capability and Economic Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, pp. 965-990.
  • William Easterly and Ross Levine (1997), “Africa’s Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, pp. 1203-1250.

April 23: Trade and Growth

  • Paul Krugman and Anthony Venables (1995), “Globalization and the Inequality of Nations,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, pp. 857-880.
  • Paul Krugman (1991), “Increasing Returns and Economic Geography,” Journal of Political Economy 99-3 (June), pp. 483-499.
  • Gene Grossman and Elhanen Helpman (1990), “Comparative Advantage and Long-Run Growth,” American Economic Review 80-4 (September), pp. 796-815
  • Jaume Ventura (1997), “Growth and Interdependence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112-1 (February), pp. 57-84.
  • Daron Acemoglu and Jaume Ventura (2001), “The World Income Distribution” (Cambridge: NBER Working Paper W8083, January).

April 30: Institutional Roots of Growth

  • Lant Pritchett (1997), “Divergence, Bigtime,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11-3 (Summer), pp. 3-18.
  • Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson (2002), “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (November).
  • Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson (2001), “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development,” American Economic Review 91-5 (December), pp. 1369-1401.
  • Stanley Engerman and Kenneth Sokoloff (1997), “Factor Endowments, Institutions, and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies,” in Steven Haber, ed., How Latin America Fell Behind (Palo Alto: Stanford University Press).

Afternoon Must-Read: Andrew Kaczynski (2012): Mitt Romney’s Long, Careful Health Care Evolution

Andrew Kaczynski (2012):
Mitt Romney’s Long, Careful Health Care Evolution:
“Romney’s path… tracked a hardening Republican reaction…

…in real time…. January 30[, 2009] speech… [called for] market dynamics, free choice, and personal responsibility, a phrase typically used to refer to the individual mandate…. [On] February 27, Romney said: ‘We need to advance a conservative plan… based on free choice, personal responsibility, and private medicine… like what I proposed in Massachusetts… the plan is a good model.’… In May, Romney wrote an op-ed… largely based off his Massachusetts plan, including an individual mandate…. On June 1… Romney thanked Heritage for helping craft health care reform in Massachusetts…. On June 14 Romney… said the President could learn from RomneyCare, saying: ‘I understand the President considers his plan in respects following the model of Massachusetts. Let’s learn from our experience.’… [On] June 24 Romney said… of the President reviving the exchanges put in place in RomneyCare, ‘we put together an exchange, and the president’s copying that idea. I’m glad to hear that.’…

[On] June 29… Romney touted both his plan and the Wyden-Bennet…. Both plans include a individual mandate. On July 30, Romney… [said] the President could learn a thing or two from… Massachusetts, including using the individual mandate…. On July 31, Romney… spoke specifically about ending the practice of free riding….

On September 19 Romney… spoke positively about his health care reform bill in Massachusetts… didn’t talk about the individual mandate or keeping reforms at the state level…. ‘We can get everyone insured, without breaking the bank and without a government option—there is no government insurance in my Massachusetts reform. The right answer for health care is not more government, it’s less government.’… In December, Romney defended his plan from attacks from Tim Pawlenty…. Romney said ‘What’s primarily wrong with the president’s plan is that he wants to get the federal government into the health insurance business. It’s going to require massive subsidies, a trillion dollars of costs down the road. That is not the right way to go. Instead, let states solve this problem…’ On January 8, 2010 Romney… mentioned his support for a federalist approach…. On February 18 Romney remarked at CPAC that health care reform should be accomplished at the state level….

After health care reform was signed into law on March 23, Romney seemed to briefly re-embrace the [individual] mandate…. In an April 4th interview… Romney… commented the ‘best features’ of the President’s plan were those similar to RomneyCare, including the ‘individual responsibility for getting insurance’…. Kavon Nikrad, frustrated by his failure to get an answer from Romney’s staff on the question of what ‘repeal’ actually meant, cornered Romney at a book signing in mid-April…. “asked Gov. Romney if… ‘the ‘worst aspects’ of Obamacare… include the repeal of the individual mandate and pre-existing exclusion?’ The Governor’s answer: ‘No.’… Romney went on to explain that he does not wish to repeal these aspects”….

Eric Fehrnstrom emailed Ben Smith… ‘Mitt Romney has been very clear in all his public statements that he is opposed to a national individual mandate. He believes those decisions should be left to the states,’ and then later emailed that the mandate ‘should be repealed.’ That email seemed to represent a final decision to stop the political bleading and cauterize the wound. For the last 23 months, Romney has been consistent: He has embraced repeal of the mandated, and stopped making references to the similarities between his plan and President Obama…

Afternoon Must-Read: Paul Krugman: Orthodoxy, Heterodoxy, Ideology

Paul Krugman:
Orthodoxy, Heterodoxy, Ideology:
“Many economists responded badly to the economic crisis…

…And there’s a lot wrong with mainstream economic analysis. But how closely are these two assertions related? Not as much as you might think. So I’m very much in accord with Simon Wren-Lewis on the remarkable unhelpfulness of recent heterodox assaults… a lot… misidentifies the problem… gives aid and comfort to the wrong people…. Standard macroeconomics does NOT justify the attacks on fiscal stimulus and the embrace of austerity. On these issues, people like Simon and myself have been following well-established models and analyses, while the austerians have been making up new stuff and/or rediscovering old fallacies…. Formal modeling and quantitative analysis doesn’t justify the austerian position; on the contrary, austerians had to throw out the models and abandon statistical principles to justify their claims….

People who should know better claim… whether fiscal stimulus can work involve[s]… Ricardian equivalence…. But that’s all wrong. Claims that a temporary rise in government spending crowds out an equal amount of private spending were based either on crude confusions between accounting identities and causation, or on a complete misunderstanding of… Ricardian equivalence…. Expansionary austerity… is really hard to get out of any formal model, and by and large the advocates of that position didn’t… try… invoked the confidence fairy pretty much on faith…. Claims that the US and the UK were at risk of an attack by bond vigilantes were similarly hard to justify…. It’s very hard to come up with a way such an attack can either happen or do much damage to a country that borrows in its own currency. As I’ve written many times, I reproach myself for having worried about such things back in 2003, when my own models refused to tell that story…. Last but not least, all that 90 percent threshold of doom stuff was based on no model… just an alleged statistical regularity… [which] probably reflected a lot of reverse causation. So if you go around claiming that model-oriented, quantitative economics gave rise to austerity mania, you’re getting the story all wrong… [and] covering up for the austerians’ intellectual sins…