Weekend reading

This is a weekly post we publish on Fridays with links to articles we think anyone interested in equitable growth should be reading. We won’t be the first to share these articles, but we hope by taking a look back at the whole week we can put them in context.

Links

Susan Dynarski points out that the gap in college completion rates for rich and poor students is even wider than the enrollment gap. [the upshot]

Steve Randy Waldman argues that Ben Bernanke didn’t acknowledge some important counterfactuals when talking about monetary policy and inequality. [interfluidity]

J.W. Mason observes that “fifteen years ago, the representative rich person in the US was plausibly a CEO, or even an elite professional. Today, they mostly just own stuff.” [the slack wire]

Gavyn Davies says that low productivity in the United Kingdom isn’t a puzzle at all. [ft]

Shane Ferro makes the case for increased unionization as the path forward for higher wages and wage-led economic growth. [business insider]

Friday figure

060515-employment

Figure from “Waiting for healthy U.S. wage growth” by Nick Bunker

Must-Read: Roger Farmer (2013): Animal Spirits, Financial Crises, and Persistent Unemployment

Must-Read: Roger E.A. Farmer (2013): Animal Spirits, Financial Crises, and Persistent Unemployment: “This article uses a rational expectations model with multiple equilibrium unemployment rates…

…to explain financial crises. The model has equilibria where asset prices are unbounded above. I argue that this is an important feature of any rational-agent explanation of a financial crisis, since for the expansion phase of the crisis to be rational, investors must credibly believe that asset prices could keep increasing forever with positive probability. I explain the sudden crash in asset prices that precipitates a financial crisis as a large shock to expectations that leads to a permanent increase in the unemployment rate.

Must-Read: Ben Thompson: The Funnel Framework

Must-Read: If you are going to read only one tech newsletter… I believe this is the one you should read:

Ben Thompson: The Funnel Framework: “The post-Internet Microsoft was the proverbial emperor with no clothes…

…That reality would only manifest itself… as soon as something better came along…. In the case of Apple… winning via the user experience…. iOS owns the best customers, i.e. the customers who are most willing to pay…. The companies who… own the funnel… are the ones who gain… in the long run, outsized profits…. Google[‘s]… search engine was, and is, superior…. And, now that they own access to the most consumers looking to buy something online–now that they own the funnel–they have outsized influence and outsized profits. Facebook… built a superior product that connected an extraordinary number of people, all generating content that made the product even more attractive and able to capture even more attention. And, now… that they own the funnel… have outsized influence and outsized profits.

All three companies succeed with very different product focuses, but all share the ability to capture a specific type of customer and funnel them to someone who is willing to pay…. If you look around you can see the funnel framework everywhere: Taxis… Uber…. Hotels… Airbnb…. Messaging apps… LINE and WeChat…. Newspapers… BuzzFeed…. Broadcast channels… Netflix and HBO…. Failing business models… most… were based on something other than providing a superior product…

Must-Read: IMF Warns Fed to Hold Its Fire on Rate Rise

Must-Read: The obvious thing. The technocratic thing. The reasonable thing. So why does the Federal Reserve think otherwise?

IMF Warns Fed to Hold Its Fire on Rate Rise: “The International Monetary Fund has urged the Federal Reserve…

…to wait until next year to raise interest rates, cautioning that the central bank’s credibility was at stake and that there was too much uncertainty to justify a much-anticipated lift-off. In its annual review of the state of the US economy released on Thursday, the IMF said it expected the US economy to grow 2.5 per cent this year despite a contraction in the first quarter. ‘The underpinnings for continued growth and job creation remain in place,’ fund economists wrote. But the IMF said conditions were still not right for the Fed to raise rates for the first time in almost a decade. It urged the central bank to wait for ‘greater signs of wage or price inflation than are currently evident’.

Waiting for healthy U.S. wage growth

The U.S. Federal Reserve should take a very close look at the latest jobs numbers released today as it contemplates when to begin raising interest rates. Job growth continued apace in May, but not swiftly enough to spur adequate wage growth. The U.S. economy added 280,000 jobs last month and the unemployment rate moved up slightly to 5.5 percent, according to data released this morning by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Yet nominal wage growth (not accounting for inflation) for all private-sector workers has yet to accelerate, growing at a 2.3 percent rate over the past 12 months. The forecast for nominal wage growth doesn’t look any better either, unless job growth picks up significantly.

The overall unemployment rate slightly increased by a percentage point over the month due to increased labor force participation, but there are still many signs that slack in the labor market is diminishing only slowly. The share of workers who are marginally attached to the labor force or working part-time for economic reasons declined to 5.3 percent in May and has been on the decline for over three years. But the level is still above 3.8 percent, what is was right before the Great Recession in December 2007.

Another key measure of the labor market is the share of prime-age workers (those between the ages of 25 and 54) with a job. The prime-age employment ratio has been steadily increasing as the recovery from the Great Recession took hold, with job growth chipping away at those deep, recession-driven job losses. The ratio is currently 77.2 percent, significantly above its nadir of 74.8 percent in November 2010. But the ratio is below its pre-recession peak of 79.7 percent in December 2007 and its level before the previous recession in March 2001 of 81.3 percent.

A good indicator of a healthy labor market is strong and sustainable wage growth. Given that goal, what level of the prime-age employment rate would indicate a robust labor market? Assuming a 1.5 percent labor productivity growth rate and 2 percent annual inflation – the target inflation rate of the Federal Reserve—then adequate nominal wage growth is at least 3.5 percent. Wage growth for production and non-supervisory workers has only hit that target over the past 25 years when the prime-age employment ratio was at least 79 percent six months prior. (See Figure 1.)

Figure 1

060515-employment

 

How long will it take to hit that 79 percent target? If we assume the employment ratio continues to grow at the rate it has been over the past year, then it will hit that target in 27 months, or around September 2017. And then six months later, in March 2018 we would expect to see healthy wage growth.

Economists and market analysts alike believe the slowdown in overall economic growth will cause the Fed to hold back on raising interest rates until later this year. But as this quick analysis shows, it may be years before the labor market is strong enough to produce adequate wage growth. Maybe those interest rate hikes can wait a bit longer.

Must-Read: Paul Krugman: Multipliers and Reality

Must-Read: Paul Krugman: Multipliers and Reality: “When Bernstein and Romer assumed that [the fiscal multiplier] was 1.5, Robert Lucas accused them of ‘shlock economics‘…

…and smeared Romer’s professional ethics. Since then there has been quite a lot of empirical work, which generally indicates a multiplier of about… 1.5. Now… Simon Wren-Lewis and Robert Waldmann raise… interesting issues. Wren-Lewis argues for a multiplier of around one… [from] a priori reasoning…. Waldmann counters that… real consumption decisions reflect rules of thumb that can easily lead to a multiplier much more than one….

And I would add: don’t forget the investment accelerator as well. Tobin’s q is really not a sufficient statistic for the determination of business investment; capacity utilization measures matter a lot.

Krugman:

The point [Wren-Lewis] makes about the implications even of perfectly well-informed and rational consumers was and as far as I know still is totally misunderstood by freshwater economists…. Lucas’s attack on Romer rested in part on the [false] claim that government spending on a new bridge would lead consumers, anticipating future taxes, to offset it one for one with cuts in their own spending; this is completely wrong if the spending is temporary….

Rigorous intertemporal thinking, even if empirically ungrounded, can be useful to focus one’s thoughts. But as a way to think about the reality of spending decisions, no…. Consider (from Vox) what the public knows about the biggest new government program of recent years[, ObamaCare]…. If people are that uninformed about something that big, imagining that they do anything like the calculations assumed in DSGE models is ludicrous. Surely they rely on rules of thumb that don’t make use of the kind of information that plays such a large role in our models…

Must-Read: Cullen Roche: Does a “Liquidity Trap” Ever End?

Must-Read: Cullen Roche: Does a “Liquidity Trap” Ever End?: “Brad Delong has a very smart post over at Equitable Growth…

…discussing the recent Feldstein commentary on inflation as well as Paul Krugman’s Liquidity Trap model of the current economic environment. Brad, unlike Paul, is not so quick to assert that the Hicksian model that Dr. Krugman has been using, is a big success.  He says:

The problem is that the macroeconomics that Paul Krugman learned at Jim Tobin’s knee wasn’t just 1930s-style Hicks-Hansen Keynesianism. It was the 1970s adaptive-expectations Phillips Curve neoclassical synthesis–nearly the same stuff that I first learned at Marty Feldstein and Olivier Blanchard’s knees in the spring of 1980. That is the framework that Marty is using know, and that generates his puzzlement. That framework had a short run of 1-2 years, a medium-run transition-dynamics phase of 2-5 years, and a long run of 5 years or more baked into it. You cannot–or at least I cannot–just throw away the medium run transition dynamics* and the declaration that the long run Omega Point is five years out, and say that mainstream economics does well.

Another way of saying this is that we’ve supposedly had a ‘Liquidity Trap’ in Japan for several decades and now we’re starting to get very long in the tooth in the ‘Liquidity Trap’ in the USA.  Given the apparent permanence of this environment we have to wonder at what point we begin to question whether we’re in a ‘Liquidity Trap’ at all. Or, were we never in a Liquidity Trap?

To be clear, a Liquidity Trap, according to Paul Krugman, is when conventional monetary policy (changing interest rates) doesn’t work. This isn’t the old Keynesian definition, but who cares because Paul isn’t using a Keynesian model anyhow (Keynes flatly rejected the Natural Rate of Interest that is so central to Krugman’s theory).

So, with the USA now into year 7 in its Liquidity Trap we have to wonder – is traditional monetary policy permanently broken?  Is it going to become ‘normal’ some time soon? If so, when? OR, could it be that traditional monetary policy was never quite as powerful as we thought which means that its recent lack of efficacy is nothing abnormal at all?

That last question is particularly interesting because it would mean that models like Paul Krugman’s Hicksian model, which are based on the Natural Rate of Interest, are a lot less useful than one thinks.  And that would mean that New Keynesian economics has much bigger holes in it than some of its adherents believe. Most importantly, it means that Paul Krugman hasn’t been right for the right reasons. It means he has been right for the wrong reasons.

Watching a Discussion: The Omega Point

Watching a Discussion: The Omega Point:

Must-Read: Mark Thoma: Krugman v. DeLong

Must-Read: The hawk-eyed Mark Thoma picks up and develops a very important point:

Mark Thoma: Krugman vs. DeLong: “Theoretical models often act as if there is only one type of demand shock…

…and the short-run depends upon a single variable, e.g. the time period when inflation expectations are wrong. But the short-run depends upon the type of recession we experience, and the variable that signals the length of the recovery will not be the same in every case. A monetary induced recession will have a much shorter short-run than a balance sheet recession induced by a financial collapse, and an recession caused by an oil price shock will recover differently from both.

Early in the Great Recession, policymakers, analysts, and most economists did not fully recognize that this recession truly was different, and hence required a different policy approach from the recessions in recent memory. Krugman, due to his work on Japan, did see this early on, but it took time for the notion of a balance sheet recession to take hold, and we never fully adopted fiscal policy to deal with this fact (e.g. sufficient help with rebuilding household balance sheets).

To me this is one of the big lessons of the Great Recession — we must figure out the type of recession we are experiencing, realize that the ‘short-run’ will depend critically on the type of shock causing the recession, and adopt our policies accordingly. If we can do that, then maybe the short-run won’t be a decade long the next time we have a balance sheet recession. And there will be a next time.