Needed: More Government, More Government Debt, Less Worry

**Introduction**

Olivier Blanchard, when he parachuted me into this panel, asked me to “be provocative”.

So let me provoke:

My assigned focus on “fiscal policy in the medium term” has implications. It requires me to assume that things are or will be true that are not now or may not be true in the future, at least not for the rest of this and into the next decade. It makes sense to distinguish the medium from the short term only if the North Atlantic economies will relatively soon enter a régime in which the economy is not at the zero lower bound on safe nominal interest rates. The medium term is at a horizon at which monetary policy can adequately handle all of the demand-stabilization role.

The focus on a medium run thus assumes that answers have been found and policies implemented for three of the most important macroeconomic questions facing us right now, here in the short run, today. Those three are:

* What role does fiscal policy have to play as a cyclical stabilization policy?

* What is the proper level of the inflation target so that open-market operation-driven normal monetary policy has sufficient purchase?

* Should truly extraordinary measures that could be classified as “social credit” policies–mixed monetary- and fiscal-expansion via direct assignment of seigniorage to households, money-financed government purchases, central bank-undertaken large-scale public lending programs, and other such–be on the table?

Those three are still the most urgent questions facing us today. But I will drop them, and leave them to others. I will presume that satisfactory answers have been found to them, and that they have thus been answered.

As I see it, there are three major medium-run questions that then remain, even further confining my scope to the North Atlantic alone, and to the major sovereigns of the North Atlantic. (Extending focus to emerging markets, to the links between the North Atlantic and the res of the world, and to Japan would raise additional important questions, which I will also drop on the floor.) These three remaining medium-run questions are:

* What is the proper size of the 21st-century public sector?

* What is the proper level of the 21st-century public debt for growth and prosperity?

* What are the systemic risks caused by government debt, and what adjustment to the proper level of 21st-century public debt is advisable because of systemic risk considerations?

To me at least, the answer to the first question–what is the proper size of the 21st-century public sector?–appears very clear.

The optimal size of the 21st-century public sector will be significantly larger than the optimal size of the 20th-century public sector. Changes in technology and social organization are moving us away from a “Smithian” economy, one in which the presumption is that the free market or the Pigovian-adjusted market does well, to one that requires more economic activity to be regulated by differently-tuned social and economic arrangements (see DeLong and Froomkin (2000)). One such is the government. Thus there should be more public sector and less private sector in the 21st-century than there was in the 20th.

Similarly, the answer to the second question appears clear, to me at least.

The proper level of the 21st century public debt should be significantly higher than typical debt levels we have seen in the 20th century. Looking back at economic history reveals that it has been generations since the intertemporal budget constraint tightly-bound peacetime or victorious reserve-currency issuing sovereigns possessing exorbitant privilege (see DeLong (2014), Kogan et al. (2015)).

Thus, at the margin, additional government debt has not required a greater primary surplus but rather allowed a greater primary deficit–a consideration that strongly militates for higher debt levels *unless interest rates in the 21st century reverse the pattern we have seen in the 20th century, and mount to levels greater than economic growth rates*.

This consideration is strengthened by observing that the North Atlantic economies have now moved into a régime in which the opposite has taken place. Real interest rates on government debt are not higher but even lower relative to growth rates than they have been in the past century. Financial market participants now appear to expect this now ultra-low interest-rate régime to continue indefinitely (see Summers (2014)).

The answer to the third question–what are the systemic risks caused by government debt?–is much more murky.

Be clear: The point is not that additional government debt imposes an undue burden in the form of distortionary taxation and inequitable income distribution on the future. When current and projected interest rates are low, they do not do so. The point is not that additional government debt crowds out productive investment and slows growth. When interest rates are un- or minimally-responsive to deficits, they do not do so. Were either of those to fail to hold, we would have exited the current régime of ultra-low interest rates, and the answer to the second question immediately above would become different.

The question, instead, is: in a world of low current and projected future interest rates–and thus also one in which interest rates are not responsive to deficits–without much expected crowding out or expected burdens on the future, what happens in the lower tail and how should that lower tail move policies away from those optimal on certainty-equivalence? And that question has four sub-questions: How much more likely does higher debt make it that interest rates will spike in the absence of fundamental reasons? How much would they spike? What would government policy be in response to such a spike? And what would be the effect on the economy?

The answer thus hinges on:

* the risk of a large sudden upward shift in the willingness to hold government debt, even absent substantial fundamental news.

* the ability of governments to deal with such a risk that threatens to push economies far enough up the Laffer curve to turn a sustainable into an unsustainable debt.

I believe the risk in such a panicked flight from an otherwise sustainable debt is small. I hold, along with Rinehart and Rogoff (2013), that the government’s legal tools to finance its debt via financial repression are very powerful, Thus I think this consideration has little weight. I believe that little adjustment to one’s view of the proper level of 21st-century public debt of *reserve currency-issuing sovereigns with exorbitant privilege* is called for because of systemic risk considerations.

But my belief here is fragile. And my comprehension of the issues is inadequate.

Let me expand on these three answers:

—-

**The Proper Size of 21st Century Government**

Suppose commodities produced and distributed are properly rival and excludible:

* Access to them needs to be cheaply and easily controlled.

* They need to be scarce.

* They need to be produced under roughly constant-returns-to-scale conditions.

Suppose, further, that information about what is being bought and sold is equally present on both sides of the marketplace—i.e., limited adverse selection and moral hazard.

Suppose, last, that the distribution of wealth is such as to accord fairly with utility and desert.

If all these hold, then the competitive Smithian market has its standard powerful advantages. And so the role of the public sector should then be confined to:

1. antitrust policy to reduce market power and microeconomic price and contract stickinesses,

2. demand-stabilization policy to offset the macroeconomic damage caused by macroeconomic price and contract stickinesses,

3. financial regulation to try to neutralize the effect on asset prices of the correlation of current wealth with biases toward optimism or pessimism, along with

4. largely-fruitless public-sector attempts to deal with other behavioral-economics psychological market failures—envy, spite, myopia, salience, etc.

The problem, however, is that as we move into the 21st century, the commodities we will be producing are becoming:

* less rival,

* less excludible,

* more subject to adverse selection and moral hazard, and

* more subject to myopia and other behavioral-psychological market failures.

The twenty-first century sees more knowledge to be learned, and thus a greater role for education. If there is a single sector in which behavioral-economics and adverse-selection have major roles to play, it is education. Deciding to fund education via very long-term loan-finance, and thus to leave the cost-benefit investment calculations to be undertaken by adolescents, shows every sign of having been a disaster when it has been tried (see Goldin and Katz (2009)).

The twenty-first century will see longer life expectancy, and thus a greater role for pensions. Yet here in the United States the privatization of pensions via 401k(s) has been, in my assessment, an equally great disaster (Munnell (2015)).

The twenty-first century will see health-care spending as a share of total income cross 25% if not 33%, or even higher. The skewed distribution across potential patients of health-care expenditures, the vulnerability of health insurance markets to adverse selection and moral hazard, and simple arithmetic mandate either that social insurance will have to cover a greater share of health-care costs or that enormous utilitarian benefits from health care will be left on the sidewalk.

Moreover, the twenty-first century will see information goods a much larger part of the total pie than the twentieth. And if we know one thing, it is that it is not efficient to try to provide information goods via a competitive market for they are neither rival nor excludible. It makes no microeconomic sense at all for services like those provided by Google to be funded and incentivized by how much money can be raised not off of the value of the services but off of the fumes rising from Google’s ability to sell the eyeballs of the users to advertisers as an intermediate good.

And then there are the standard public goods like infrastructure and basic research.

Enough said.

The only major category of potential government spending that both should not–and to an important degree cannot–be provided by a competitive price-taking market, and that *might* be a smaller share of total income in the twenty-first century than it was in the twentieth? Defense.

We thus face a pronounced secular shift away from commodities that have the characteristics–rivalry, excludability, and enough repetition in purchasing and value of reputation to limit myopia–needed for the Smithian market to function well as a societal coordinating mechanism. This raises enormous problems: We know that as bad as market failures can be, government failures can often be little if any less immense.

We will badly need to develop new effective institutional forms for the twenty-first century.

But, meanwhile, it is clear that the increasing salience of these market failures has powerful implications for the relative sizes of the private market and the public administrative spheres in the twenty-first century. The decreasing salience of “Smithian” commodities in the twenty-first century means that rational governance would expect the private-market sphere to shrink relative to the public. This is very elementary micro and behavioral economics. And we need to think hard about what its implications for public finance are.

—-

**The Proper Size of the Twenty-First Century Public Debt**

Back in the Clinton administration–back when the U.S. government’s debt really did look like it was an an unsustainable course–we noted that the correlation between shocks to U.S. interest rates and the value of the dollar appeared to be shifting from positive to zero, and we were scared that the U.S. was alarmingly close to its debt capacity and needed major, radical policy changes to reduce the deficit (see Alan Blinder and Janet Yellen (2000)).

Whether we were starting at shadows then, or whether we were right then and the world has changed since, or whether the current world is in an unstable configuration and we will return to normal within a decade is unclear to me.

But right now financial markets are telling us very strange things about the debt capacity of reserve currency-issuing sovereigns.

Since 2005, the interest rate on U.S. ten-year Treasury bonds has fallen from roughly the growth rate of nominal GDP–5%/year–to 250 basis points below the growth rate of nominal GDP. Because the duration of the debt is short, the average interest rate on Treasury securities has gone from 100 basis points below the economy’s trend growth rate to nearly 350 basis points below. Maybe you can convince yourself that the market expects the ten-year rate over the next generation to average 50 basis points higher than it is now. Maybe.

Graph 10 Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate FRED St Louis Fed

Taking a longer run view, Richard Kogan et al. (2015) of the CBPP has been cleaning the data from OMB. Over the past 200 years, for the U.S., the government’s borrowing rate has averaged 100 basis points lower than the economy’s growth rate. Over the past 100 years, 170 basis points lower. Over the past 50 years, 30 basis points lower. Over the past twenty years Treasury’s borrowing rate has been on average greater than g by 20 basis points. And over the past ten years, 70 basis points lower.

Banners and Alerts and 2 27 15bud f1 png 450×280 pixels
When we examine the public finance history of major North Atlantic industrial powers, we find that the last time that the average over any decade of government debt service as a percentage of outstanding principal was higher than the average growth rate of its economy was… the Great Depression. And before that… 1890.

Since then, over any extended time period for the major North Atlantic reserve-currency issuing economies, g > r, for government debt.

Only those who see a very large and I believe exaggerated chance of global thermonuclear war or environmental collapse see the North Atlantic economies as dynamically inefficient from the standpoint of our past investments in private physical, knowledge, and organizational capital. r > g by a very comfortable margin. Investments in wealth in the form of private capital are, comfortably, a cash-flow source for savers.

But the fact that g > r with respect to the investments we have made in our governments raises deep and troubling questions. Since 1890, a North Atlantic government that borrows more at the margin benefits its current citizens, increases economic growth, and increases the well-being of its bondholders (for they do buy the paper voluntarily): it is win-win-win.

That fact strongly suggests that North Atlantic economies throughout the entire 20th Century suffered from excessive accumulation of societal wealth in the form of net government capital—in other words, government debt has been too low.

The North Atlantic economies of major sovereigns throughout the entire 20th Century have thus suffered from a peculiar and particular form of dynamic inefficiency. Over the past 100 years, in the United States, at the margin, each extra stock 10% of annual GDP’s worth of debt has provided a flow of 0.1% of GDP of services in taxpayers in increased primary expenditures or reduced taxpayers.

What is the elementary macroeconomics of dynamic inefficiency? If a class of investment–in this case, investment by taxpayers in the form of wealth held by the government via amortizing the debt–is dynamically inefficient, do less of it. Do less of it until you get to the Golden Rule, and do even less if you are impatient. How do taxpayers move away from dynamic inefficiency toward the Golden Rule? By not amortizing the debt, but rather by borrowing more.

Now we resist this logic. I resist this logic.

Debt secured by government-held social wealth ought to be a close substitute in investors portfolios with debt secured by private capital formation. So it is difficult to understand how economies can be dynamically efficient with respect to private capital, and yet “dynamically inefficient” with respect to government-held societal wealth. But it appears to be the case that it is so.

But there is this outsized risk premium, outsized equity and low-quality debt premium, outsized wedge. And that means that while investments in wealth in the form of private capital are a dynamically-efficient cash-flow source for savers, investments by taxpayers in the form of paying down debt are a cash-flow sink.

I tend to say that we have a huge underlying market failure here that we see in the form of the equity return premium–a failure of financial markets to mobilize society’s risk-bearing capacity, and that pushes down the value of risky investments and pushes up the value of assets perceived as safe, in this case the debt of sovereigns possessing exorbitant privilege. But how do we fix this risk-bearing capacity mobilization market failure? And isn’t the point of the market economy to make things that are valuable? And isn’t the debt of reserve-currency issuing sovereigns an extraordinarily valuable thing that is very cheap to make? So shouldn’t we be making more of it? Looking out the yield curve, such government debt looks to be incredibly valuable for the next half-century, at least.

These considerations militate strongly for higher public debts in the 21st-century then we saw in the 20th-century. Investors want to hold more government debt: the extraordinary prices at which it has sold since 1890 tell us that. Market economies are supposed to be in the business of producing things that households want whenever that can be done cheaply. Government debt fits the bill, especially now. And looking out the yield curve Government debt looks to fit the bill for the next half-century at least.

—-

**Systemic Risks and Public Debt Accumulation:**

One very important question remains very live: Would levels of government debt issue large enough to drive r > g for government bonds create significant systemic risks? Yes, the prices of the government debt of major North Atlantic industrial economies are very high now. But what if there is a sudden downward shock to the willingness of investors to hold this debt? What if the next generation born and coming to the market is much more impatient? Governments might then have to roll over their debt on terms that require high debt-amortization taxes, and if the debt is high enough those taxes could push economies far enough up a debt Laffer curve. That might render the debt unsustainable in the aftermath of such a preference shift.

Two considerations make me think that this is a relatively small danger.

First, when I look back in history I cannot see any such strong fundamental news-free negative preference shock to the willingness to hold the government debt of the North Atlantic’s major industrial powers since the advent of parliamentary government. The fiscal crises we see—of the Weimar Republic, Louis XIV Bourbon, Charles II Stuart, Felipe IV Habsburg, and so forth—are all driven by fundamental news.

Second, as Reinhart and Rogoff (2013) have pointed out at substantial length, 20th and 19th Century North Atlantic governments have proven able to tax their financial sectors via financial repression with great ease. The amount of real wealth for debt amortization raised by financial repression scales roughly with the value of outstanding government debt. And such taxes are painful for those taxed. But only when even semi-major industrial countries have allowed large-scale borrowing in potentially harder currencies than their own—and thus, cough, cough written unhedged puts on their currencies in large volume—is there any substantial likelihood of major additional difficulty or disruption.

Now Kenneth Rogoff (2015) disagrees with drawing this lesson from Reinhart and Rogoff (2013). And one always disagrees analytically with Kenneth Rogoff at one’s great intellectual peril. He sees the profoundly depressed level of interest rates on the debt of major North Atlantic sovereigns as a temporary and disequilibrium phenomenon that will son be rectified. He believes that excessive debt issue and overleverage are at the roots of our problems–call it secular stagnation, the global savings glut, the safe-asset shortage, the balance-sheet recession, whatever.

In Rogoff’s view:

>Unlike secular stagnation, a debt supercycle is not forever…. Modern macroeconomics has been slow to get to grips with the analytics of how to incorporate debt supercycles…. There has been far too much focus on orthodox policy responses and not enough on heterodox responses…. In a world where regulation has sharply curtailed access for many smaller and riskier borrowers, low sovereign bond yields do not necessarily capture the broader “credit surface” the global economy faces… The elevated credit surface is partly due to inherent riskiness and slow growth in the post-Crisis economy, but policy has also played a large role…

The key here is Rogoff’s assertion that the low borrowing rate faced by major North Atlantic sovereigns “do[es] not necessarily capture the broader ‘credit surface'”–that the proper shadow price of government debt issue is far in excess of the sovereign borrowing rate. Why? Apparently because future states of the world in which private bondholders would default are also those in which it would be very costly in social utility terms for the government to raise money via taxes.

I do not see this. A major North Atlantic sovereign’s potential tax base is immensely wide and deep. The instruments at its disposal to raise revenue are varied and powerful. The correlation between the government’s taxing capacity and the operating cash flow of private borrowers is not that high. A shock like 2008-9 temporarily destroyed the American corporate sector’s ability to generate operating cash flows to repay debt at the same time that it greatly raised the cost of rolling over debt. But the U.S. government’s financial opportunities became much more favorable during that episode.

Moreover, Rogoff also says:

>When it comes to government spending that productively and efficiently enhances future growth, the differences are not first order. With low real interest rates, and large numbers of unemployed (or underemployed) construction workers, good infrastructure projects should offer a much higher rate of return than usual…

and thus with sensible financing and recapture of the economic benefits of government spending, have little or no impact on debt-to-income ratios.

—-

**Conclusion:**

I conclude that, looking forward:

1. North Atlantic public sectors for major sovereigns ought, technocratically, to be larger than they have been in the past century.
2. North Atlantic relative public debt levels for major sovereigns ought, technocratically, to be higher than they have been in the past century.
3. With prudent regulation—i.e., the effective limitation of the banking sector’s ability to write unhedged puts on the currency—the power major sovereigns possess to tax the financial sector via financial repression provides sufficient insurance against an adverse preference shock to the desire for government debt.

The first two of these conclusions appear to me to be close to rock solid. The third is, I think, considerably less secure.

Nevertheless, in my view, if the argument against a larger public sector and more public debt in the 21st century than in the 20th for major North Atlantic sovereigns is going to be made successfully, it seems to me that it needs to be made on a political-economy government-failure basis.

The argument needs to be not that larger government spending and a higher government debt issued by a functional government would diminish utility, but rather that government itself will be highly dysfunctional.

Government needs to be viewed not as one of several instrumentalities we possess and can deploy to manage and coordinate our societal division-of-labor, but rather as the equivalent of a loss-making industry under really existing socialism. Government spending must be viewed as worse than useless. Therefore relaxing any constraints that limit the size of the government needs to be viewed as an evil.

Now the public choice school has gone there. As Lawrence Summers (2011) said, they have taken the insights on government failure and:

>driven it relentlessly towards nihilism in a way that isn’t actually helpful for those charged with designing regulatory institutions…

or, indeed, making public policy in general. In my opinion, if this argument is to be made, it needs a helpful public choice foundation before it can be properly built.

—-

**References**

Alan Blinder and Janet Yellen (2000), _The Fabulous Decade: Macroeconomic Lessons from the 1990s_ (New York: Century Foundation)

J. Bradford DeLong (2014), “Notes on Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Interest-Rate Environment” (Berkeley: UC Berkeley):

J. Bradford DeLong and A. Michael Froomkin (2000), “Speculative Microeconomics for Tomorrow’s Economy”, _First Monday_ 5:2 (February 7):

Claudia Goldin and Lawrence Katz (2009), _The Race Between Education and Technology_ (Cambridge: Harvard University Press) http://amzn.to/1M6Glbg

Richard Kogan et al. (2015), “Difference Between Economic Growth Rates and Treasury Interest Rates Significantly Affects Long-Term Budget Outlook” (Washington: CBPP):

Alicia Munnell (2015), “Falling Short: The Coming Retirement Crisis and What to Do About It” (Boston College: CRR)

Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff (2013), “Financial and Sovereign Debt Crises: Some Lessons Learned and Those Forgotten” (Washington, DC: IMF)

Kenneth Rogoff (2015), “Debt Supercycle, Not ecular Stagnation” (VoxEU)

Lawrence Summers (2011), “A Conversation on New Economic Thinking”

Lawrence Summers (2014), “U.S. Economic Prospects: Secular Stagnation, Hysteresis, and the Zero Lower Bound”, _Business Economics_ 49:2 (June)

Must-Read: Noah Smith: We’re All Smart. And Dumb. Sometimes

Noah Smith: We’re All Smart. And Dumb. Sometimes: “The good criticism of behavioral econ is that it’s very hard to go from the lab to the real world…

…The bad one [is] people are way, way too afraid of the soft paternalism of nudges…. William Easterly… expressed this fear when he tweeted: ‘Behavioral econ [Thaler] says we are too dumb to fix our own mistakes but smart enough to fix everyone else’s[.]’ Easterly… mischaracterized behavioral economics. Behavioral econ isn’t about smart people knowing what’s best for dumb people. It’s about all people being smart some of the time and dumb at other times. Or strong-willed some of the time and weak-willed at other times…. Critics of soft paternalism should realize that people are already being nudged all the time, and not by government. The true masters of behavioral economics are marketers in the private sector… and have never had any compunction about using it to take your money.

Ever wonder why prices in stores are $9.99 instead of $10? Behavioral economics. How about sales and discounts? Just raise the base price and treat the real price as a discount, and behavioral economics will make people more eager to buy. That yogurt that advertises itself as fat-free? Check out how many grams of sugar it has. And so on. Marketing is by far the biggest application of behavioral economics, it’s perfectly legal and it’s already everywhere. You are being nudged 24/7. If you stop to think about it, it’s ludicrous that behavioral econ skeptics are up in arms about government nudges, but blithely unconcerned about corporate nudges. But stopping to think about things is something we rarely do. And that’s why behavioral economics is important.

Must-Read: Nicholas Kaldor (1971): On The Common Market

Nicholas Kaldor (1971): On The Common Market: “Some day the nations of Europe may be ready to merge their national identities…

…If and when they do, a European Government will take over all the functions which the Federal government now provides in the U.S., or in Canada or Australia. This will involve the creation of a ‘full economic and monetary union’. But it is a dangerous error to believe that monetary and economic union can precede a political union or that it will act (in the words of the Werner report) ‘as a leaven for the evolvement of a political union which in the long run it will in any case be unable to do without’. For if the creation of a monetary union and Community control over national budgets generates pressures which lead to a breakdown of the whole system it will prevent the development of a political union, not promote it…

Must-Read: Mariana Garcia Schmidt and Michael Woodford: Are Low Interest Rates Deflationary? [No:] A Paradox of Perfect-Foresight Analysis

Must-Read: Mariana Garcia Schmidt and Michael Woodford: Are Low Interest Rates Deflationary? [No:] A Paradox of Perfect-Foresight Analysis: “Some… suggest that prolonged low nominal interest rates…

…and central-bank promises to maintain such policy–may bring about lower inflation (rather than higher)…. The “Neo-Fisherian” View (Cochrane, 2015b)…. Is it really true that “modern theory” — deriving aggregate demand and supply relations from intertemporal optimization — implies the neo-Fisherian view? Can one maintain the orthodox view — that maintaining a lower nominal rate for longer should cause higher inflation and capacity utilization — while having a view of expectations that implies that central-bank commitments regarding future policy should have any effect?…. The assumption of perfect foresight is… very strong…. PFE predictions are relevant only to the extent that
the PFE is the limit of an iterative process of belief revision… [that] converges fast enough for the limit to well approximate the outcome from a finite degree of reflection…. Temporary equilibrium (Hicks, Grandmont, etc.): endogenous variables determined by optimizing behavior of economic agents, under subjective expectations that are specified as part of the model (and need not be correct)…. Dixit-Stiglitz monopolistic competitors. Calvo-Yun… staggered price adjustment….

Cochrane (2015a) proposes a particular criterion for selecting one among this continuum of PFE solutions as the prediction of the model: the “backward stable” equilibrium…. But is this a reasonable view of what should follow from intertemporal optimization, and an ability to reason about the implications of the central bank’s policy commitments for future economic outcomes?… Consideration of the set of PF equilibria is especially misleading in the (somewhat artificial) thought experiment of a permanent interest-rate peg–a case in which none of the PFE paths approximate TE paths for finite n, even for very large n…. So we should not necessarily expect… that a long-enough lasting commitment to remain at the ZLB must eventually make inflation lower, rather than higher…. Especially for larger values of T, the approach recommended here leads only to a set of possible predictions for a given policy, but this still allows qualitative conclusions that remain very useful for practical policy analysis, and insisting on PFE analysis simply because it makes more sharply-defined predictions may lead to large errors.

Must-Must-Must Read in Its Entirety: Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas (2002): Comment on Blanchard and Giavazzi

Must-Must-Must Read in Its Entirety: The reason that I find the Princeton Economics Department’s refusal to tenure Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas in the early 2000s incomprehensible, save as the indicator of a massive collective cognitive disfunction:

Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas (2002): Comment on Blanchard and Giavazzi: “This is a very nice paper…

…It is simple and intuitive and elegantly fits an interesting fact to the theory. Blanchard and Giavazzi argue that large current account deficits in Portugal and Greece, two small and relatively poor members of the European Union, are exactly what the neoclassical growth model predicts should happen when such economies integrate their financial and goods markets with the rest of the world. And that these large deficits are not cause for worry.

Why should current account deficits in poorer countries increase with integration? Theory emphasizes two channels:

  1. Faster conditional convergence and catch-up: Financial market integration, coupled with monetary union, reduces the cost of capital and eliminates currency risk. Cheap capital stimulates investment, while low interest rates and increased future wealth lower saving. Meanwhile product market integration reduces the adverse terms-of-trade effect that accompanies the need to generate a given trade surplus in the future, effectively making borrowing even cheaper.

  2. Productivity catch-up: Through increased competition or better discipline, integration improves domestic total factor productivity (TFP), which increases the country’s growth prospects.

The authors present evidence that largely supports the theory: the dispersion of current account deficits across European countries has increased in the last five years. Poorer European countries tend to run larger deficits, and more so now than in the past, so that, finally, the high correlation between national saving and private investment—the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle—has largely disappeared for this group of countries. The authors provide detailed evidence for Portugal and Greece that emphasizes the importance of financial integration working through a decline in real interest rates (Portugal) or through an easing of the credit constraints on firms (Greece).

The paper provides a very convincing account and delivers a welcome piece of good news. After all, many emerging market economies have experienced a rather bumpy ride as they liberalized their goods and financial markets. Globalization, it seems, has not been a smooth process. Evidence that the standard theory performs well, at least for some European countries, is therefore reassuring. It leads to the natural conclusion that the gains from integration are there and that they should be driven by the channels mentioned above: conditional convergence and productivity catch-up. It also underlies the authors’ normative conclusion that the recent current account developments are—to a first order—optimal.

My comments will address each point in turn.

First, I will argue that conditional convergence and productivity catch-up have quite different welfare implications. In particular, the estimated welfare benefits from conditional convergence are relatively small for Portugal and Greece compared with the potential benefits from productivity catch-up.

Second, I will show that more is at play than the simple conditional convergence story. Productivity growth in Greece and Portugal has been faster than in other European countries. More generally, poorer OECD countries have experienced faster TFP growth. This strengthens the argument for laissez-faire, since productivity growth provides first-order welfare gains.

Third, to the extent that income per capita converges among members of the European Union, a central implication of the theory is that greater cross-country dispersion in current accounts should be matched by lower income inequality. Here the data do not oblige: the evidence indicates that income inequality has increased, not decreased, over the recent past. This casts some doubts on the mechanism that the paper emphasizes.

All this indicates that the normative conclusions that the authors reach may not be warranted. Large current account deficits, even when a consequence of credible financial integration, may lead to situations of illiquidity. Some strictly positive amount of insurance, in the form of a government surplus, may be necessary.

Conditional convergence and the benefits of open capital markets: The paper emphasizes the benefits of both product and financial market integration. Yet it should be clear that financial integration is the key ingredient. Product market integration is only relevant in the paper insofar as it facilitates intertemporal lending and borrowing.

So we may ask a simple question: how much benefit can a small, open economy like Portugal or Greece reap from financial integration? In the standard neoclassical growth framework, open financial markets bring about faster convergence toward a country-specific steady state. How beneficial is this conditional convergence? As it turns out, this simple question has a simple answer: not very.

To understand why, consider two extreme scenarios. First, consider a small, open economy under financial autarky, with no intertemporal trade. Alternatively, think of the same economy as a financially integrated economy with perfect and frictionless capital mobility. The latter scenario, of course, involves potentially very large current account deficits. The welfare difference between the two scenarios should set an upper bound on the true welfare gains that can accrue to a country like Portugal or Greece; after all, neither country was in a state of financial autarky before adopting the euro, nor is either currently experiencing unfettered capital flows.

To measure this upper bound, one needs only some estimate of the current and steady-state levels of physical and human capital per capita. Such estimates are provided and discussed in work I have done with Olivier Jeanne.1 Using these estimates, table 1 below reports compensating variation for twenty OECD countries as of 1995. Compensating variation measures the constant fraction of annual consumption that the typical household would have to give up to be indifferent between financial integration and financial autarky. For Greece this compensating variation is about 0.76 percent of annual consumption. The figure for Portugal is larger, at 2.67 percent. Those numbers are quite representative: compensating variation averages 0.91 percent of consumption for all countries in the sample, and it ranges from 0.10 percent for Norway to Portugal’s 2.67 percent.

Www brookings edu media Projects BPEA Fall 202002 2002b bpea blanchard PDF

How should we think of these numbers? I would argue that they are quite small. First, they are upper bounds on the true welfare benefits, and they are likely to be considerably smaller after adjustment costs, incentives, and intertemporal terms-of-trade effects are factored in. Second, even when taken at face value, they are small compared with the welfare benefits from, for instance, productivity improvements or the elimination of domestic distortions.2 These small numbers reflect the fact that, taken alone, financial integration is unlikely to remove domestic distortions or inefficiencies. This result weakens Blanchard and Giavazzi’s claim: if this is all that is going on, we should not worry about large current account deficits because they do not matter much for welfare, just as it does not matter much for welfare whether the capital account is open or closed.

Domestic efficiency gains in Portugal and Greece: Of course, conditional convergence is not the whole story. EU members exhibit convergence in income per capita. Equivalently, we observe a productivity catch-up. A simple look at labor productivity and TFP over the second half of the 1990s confirms that productivity growth is an important part of the story. Table 2 reports labor productivity for 1991–95 and 1996–2000 as well as TFP for 1990–95. There is clear evidence that both Portugal and Greece experienced strong labor productivity growth (at least 3 percent a year) between 1996 and 2000. When one compares 1991–95 with 1996–2000, it is also clear that Portugal and Greece (and Ireland) did break away from the pack. TFP also rose sharply in Ireland and Portugal, but less sharply in Greece.3

Www brookings edu media Projects BPEA Fall 202002 2002b bpea blanchard PDF

More systematic analysis finds strong evidence that productivity growth in OECD countries is linked—negatively—to the initial level of development. Regressing TFP growth from 1965 to 1995 on the initial level of output per capita, I obtain the following results:

Www brookings edu media Projects BPEA Fall 202002 2002b bpea blanchard PDF Www brookings edu media Projects BPEA Fall 202002 2002b bpea blanchard PDF

These results indicate that low initial levels of output per capita are associated with faster TFP growth among the OECD countries. No such pattern is present for the non-OECD countries. This evidence in favor of productivity gains reinforces the message of the paper: after all, if poorer countries are also catching up in terms of TFP, so much the better, and the associated current account deficits should be even less of a concern.

One is left wondering, however, where these productivity gains are coming from. The paper mentions increased goods market competition and market discipline. Yet the discussion of Portugal and Greece does not revisit the issue as extensively. So we are left wanting more: is it purely a financial story whereby access to the international bond market (Portugal) or financial disintermediation (Greece) improves the efficiency of the domestic financial sector? Does it have to do with increased competition in goods markets? or with the discipline effect? These are important—and difficult—questions to answer.

Current account deficits, cross-country output, and catch-up: Take as given that the euro area countries are converging in terms of the level of GDP per capita, as suggested by the previous evidence. According to the neoclassical growth model, the cross-sectional variance for the logarithm of output per capita at time t, σ2t , should follow:

Www brookings edu media Projects BPEA Fall 202002 2002b bpea blanchard PDF

where σ2ut represents the variance of unexpected changes in preferences or production conditions across countries at time t, and β is the “speed of convergence” taken from the neoclassical growth model.4

This σ-convergence expresses the idea that we should expect to see less and less dispersion in output per capita as countries converge to their common steady state. For present purposes, observe that any factor that speeds up convergence (that is, increases β) should also lead to a faster decline in the cross-country dispersion of income. It is then a direct implication of the theory that financial and product market integration should lead simultaneously to an increasing dispersion, in the cross section, of the ratio of current account to GDP, and a decline in the dispersion of log output per capita.

Is this implication supported by the data? Figure 1 below reports the cross-country dispersion of log output per capita since 1975 for the OECD, the European Union, and the euro area, as defined in the paper. One can see a large decline in this measure of income inequality for all three groups, especially for the European Union and the euro area, where it has fallen from a peak of 0.32 in 1984 to a trough of 0.23 in 1997. At first glance, this massive reduction in income inequality appears consistent with the convergence hypothesis just described. Most of this decline can in fact be traced to the growth performance of only three countries: Ireland, Spain, and Portugal.

However, when we examine the joint evolution of output per capita and the ratio of the current account balance to GDP, the evidence appears less trenchant. Figure 2 is a scatterplot, for the euro area, of the cross-country dispersion in the ratio of the current account to GDP against income inequality. The figure shows three distinct phases. In the early 1980s the dispersion of current account balances was very large, reflecting the large budget deficits in Portugal and Ireland.

From 1985 to roughly 1995 there was a massive reduction in income inequality, without any significant change in the dispersion of current account positions. Lastly, from 1996 to 2001 there was a large increase in current account dispersion, accompanied by a modest yet significant increase in income inequality.5 This last segment is the focus of the paper. Yet the associated increase in income inequality contradicts the view that convergence is driving the process. A look at the time plot of log GDP per capita for the EU countries (figure 3) confirms that convergence seems to have stopped, except for Ireland, over the period when current account deficits were driven apart.

Www brookings edu media Projects BPEA Fall 202002 2002b bpea blanchard PDF

Of course, it is possible that country-specific shocks were sufficiently large to counteract the convergence process and drive incomes per capita apart over that period. However, one is left wondering what exactly these shocks were.6

Should we worry? This slowdown or even reversal in convergence suggests that we should look at the components of the current account for further insight. Blanchard and Giavazzi state that “The channel [for the increased external deficit] appears to be primarily a decrease in saving— typically private saving… rather than an increase in investment.”

According to the paper’s table 1, private saving in Portugal decreased by 5.6 percent of GDP from 1985–91 to 2000–01. In Greece private sav- ing decreased by 7.7 percent of GDP between 1981–91 and 2000–01 (table 2). By contrast, investment increased in Portugal by a modest 2.8 percent of GDP and remained more or less constant in Greece. In both countries public saving is not an essential part of the story.

Www brookings edu media Projects BPEA Fall 202002 2002b bpea blanchard PDF

The experience of these two countries—up to this point—is very reminiscent of that of many Latin American countries that have adopted exchange rate–based stabilization programs.7 Stabilization of the exchange rate, renewed access to international capital markets, and some euphoria at the prospect of steady future growth combined to generate a strong consumption boom—that is, a decline in saving—which may or may not have been accompanied by an investment boom. Growth was initially solid and everything looked benign. Over time, however, clouds gathered on the horizon: the currency appreciated in real terms, competitiveness plummeted, and foreign investors became worried as growth performance failed to meet expectations. The endgame is well known: with a fixed exchange rate, restoring competitiveness required an adjustment in relative prices. Often this was too little and too late. Eventually capital pulled out, forcing a devaluation.

Www brookings edu media Projects BPEA Fall 202002 2002b bpea blanchard PDF

European countries, too, have experienced similar dynamics in the past. For instance, France’s experiment with “competitive disinflation” presents a number of similarities: a strong peg, a currency that appreciated over time relative to the deutsche mark, sustained external imbal- ances, a failure of wage and price moderation to restore competitiveness, and eventually an abrupt adjustment at the time of the 1992 crisis in the exchange rate mechanism.8

How do these episodes differ from the current situation in Portugal and Greece, and what lessons do they offer? I see two important differences. First, the Latin American countries in the early 1990s and the European countries in the late 1980s had a checkered inflation record. As a conse- quence, the real appreciation was relatively rapid. Inflation inertia was key to that process. Portugal and Greece today are in a different situation: there is virtually no risk that inflation will get out of control. Yet their strong economic performance, as well as the impact of convergence on the price of nontraded goods (the Balassa-Samuelson effect), implies that one can expect higher inflation in both countries than in the rest of the euro area. Annual consumer price inflation in September 2002 was 3.7 percent in Portugal and 3.4 percent in Greece, against only 2.1 percent for the euro area as a whole.9

Taken together, these considerations imply that real overvaluation may happen relatively slowly in Portugal and Greece. But there are signs that it is coming. In time, this will require an adjustment in relative prices, which may prove painful.

Second, to the extent that both countries belong to European monetary union, there is no escape clause: the risk of devaluation is also nonexistent. This means fewer reasons for financial markets to worry. Indeed, the fact that neither Portugal’s nor Greece’s debt carries substantial spreads over that of other European countries can be taken as a sign of market confidence in these countries’ ability to honor their international obligations. But this does not mean that capital cannot or will not pull out. Even with a relatively evenly distributed maturity structure, markets could refuse to finance additional increases in debt. At current levels this would mean a sudden stop on the order of 5–7 percent of GDP, which would surely raise the specter of default. In other words, although a common currency may eliminate concerns that capital flight will force a devaluation, it does not ensure against situations of illiquidity.

What should governments do? Certainly, provision of full insurance is unwarranted. As the authors argue, this would completely eliminate the benefits of greater integration. But it seems that no insurance at all is not the answer either. This discussion teaches us that there is some, probably strictly positive level of insurance that governments should purchase: a buffer, in the form of a larger government surplus, would prove useful should markets become less confident.


The Future of the Euro: Presentation (August 7, 2015)

ABSTRACT: I have a problem here: This talk was supposed to take place after the spring 2015 revision of the Greek program. It was supposed to use that revision as a springboard to launch into (a) the extent to which the current macroeconomic difficulties of Europe are caused by the euro, (b) the difficulties of burden-sharing within the eurozone, and (c) what the political-economic options were for turning the euro zone into enough of an optimum currency area for the euro to make economic sense for the continent. Clearly, this is all now down the drain: On August 7, we will have to talk about… whatever we think we should talk about. It may be what I originally planned. It may by options for and consequences of Greek exit from the eurozone. It may be the road from 2010 to 2015…


READINGS


BIOGRAPHY

J. Bradford DeLong is Professor of Economics at U.C. Berkeley, and was Deputy Assistant Secretary for Economic Policy of the U.S. Treasury during the Clinton Administration. He is completing “Slouching Towards Utopia?”, an overly-long economic history of the world in the twentieth century.

He is best known for “Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets” (JPE, 1989), “Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy” (BPEA, 2012), “Did JP Morgan’s Men Add Value?” (book chapter, 1991), “The Survival of Noise Traders in Financial Markets” (JF, 1991), “America’s Peacetime Inflation: the 1970s” (book chapter, 1997), “Is Increased Price Flexibility Stabilizing?” (AER, 1986), “Speculative Microeconomics for Tomorrow’s Economy” (First Monday, 2000), “Meltdown to Moral Hazard: the International Monetary and Financial Policies of the Clinton Administration” (book chapter, 2001), “Have Productivity Levels Converged? Productivity Growth, Convergence, and Welfare in the Very Long Run” (AER, 1989), and “Should We Fear Deflation?” (BPEA, 1989).

He can currently be found on the internet at Twitter:@delong, http://www.facebook.com/brad.delong.77, Equitablog, Grasping Reality, and Bull Market on Medium.


Things to Read at Lunchtime on July 11, 2015

Screenshot 10 3 14 6 17 PM

Must- and Should-Reads:

Might Like to Be Aware of:

Must-Read: Matthew Yglesias: Here’s Some Thoughts about Europe

Must-Read: Matthew Yglesias: Matt! on Twitter: “I think sensible Americans are still asleep…

… so here’s some thoughts about Europe instead. The Greece issue highlights continued severe structural problems with the construction of the Eurozone. Anglo-Keynesians tend to focus on the lack of fiscal transfers, but the real issue is a lack of legitimate decision-making. There is too much inter-governmentalism, opacity, and reliance on ECB discretion rather than accountable decisionmakers. To work, more authority needs to be in the hands of the Commission and the parliament, with the Commission responsible to parliament. But with the UK & Sweden disconnected from the Euro, this raises a version of the West Lothian Question as well as normal resistance. In short, Europe’s political architecture still needs some serious work and there isn’t a totally obvious path forward.

Things to Read at Lunchtime on July 10, 2015

Must- and Should-Reads:

Might Like to Be Aware of: