Must-Read: Amir Sufi: Out of Many, One?: Household Debt, Redistribution and Monetary Policy during the Economic Slump

Must-Read: Amir Sufi: Out of Many, One?: Household Debt, Redistribution and Monetary Policy during the Economic Slump: “Monetary policy has been especially weak in advanced economies over the past 7 years…

…because the redistribution channels of monetary policy have been severely hampered. Standard representative agent-based macroeconomic models miss this key insight, and have therefore been an insufficient guide to policy decisions. A framework that recognizes the importance of redistribution channels of monetary policy can guide central bankers on what policies are most likely to be effective. The same policy may have different effects on the real economy depending on the distribution of debt capacity across individuals.

Noted for Your Lunchtime Procrastination for July 17, 2015

Must-Read: Joe Romm:

Hottest June Puts 2015 On Track For Hottest Year On Record By Far ThinkProgress

Must-Read: Joe Romm: Hottest June Puts 2015 on Track for Hottest Year on Record by Far: “It’s now all but certain 2015 will be the hottest year on record…

…probably by a wide margin–as what increasingly appears to be one of the strongest El Niños in 50 years boosts the underlying global warming trend.
Climate expert Dr. John Abraham amended this NASA chart to show how the first six months of 2015 compares to the annual temperatures of previous years….

There is a greater than 85 percent chance that the current El Niño lasts through May. As AccuWeather’s Anderson explains, ‘El Niño typically reaches its peak during the December through February period.’ If this pattern plays out, then 2016 would likely top whatever temperature record 2015 sets…

Weekend reading

This is a weekly post we publish on Fridays with links to articles we think anyone interested in equitable growth should be reading. We won’t be the first to share these articles, but we hope by taking a look back at the whole week, we can put them in context.

Links

Paul Krugman on what the new research on labor markets tell us about raising wages. [nyt]

Matt Bruenig digs into the data and shows U.S. workers put in more hours than we’d expect given productivity levels. [demos]

Timothy Taylor discusses new research about productivity and the seeming problem of diffusing new ideas to other firms. [conversable economist]

Dietz Vollrath tries to understand the diffusion models of productivity growth. [growth economics]

David Keohane on brokerage booms, hidden debt, and Chinese GDP data. [ft alphaville]

Friday figure

lfpr-testimony-03

 

Figure from “The Declining Labor Force Participation Rate: Causes, Consequences, and the Path Forward” by Elisabeth Jacobs

Must-Read: Karl Whelan: Alice In Schäuble-Land: Where Rules Mean What Wolfgang Says They Mean

Must-Read: Karl Whelan: Alice In Schäuble-Land: Where Rules Mean What Wolfgang Says They Mean: “Neither [John] Bruton nor [Simon] Nixon explains which eurozone rules Greece has been breaking that necessitated threats of expulsion…

…People can point to the under-statements of Greece’s debt that pre-dated the current crisis. But these events are long in the past and did nothing to contribute to the escalation of the current crisis this year. You can also point to the Stability and Growth Pact rules but keep in mind that these are being broken by the majority of euro area members. Nixon explains the real rule that Tsipras has broken:

Like Italy’s Matteo Renzi, France’s François Hollande and others before him, Mr. Tsipras has had to learn the rules of the European game: that you don’t gain leverage over other leaders simply by winning elections–they have all done that–but by winning their respect by showing you have the capacity to make tough decisions at home.

This gets it about right. The rules that Tsipras has broken are unwritten rules that reflect the power the euro area’s creditor states have to ruin any member states that don’t do as they are ordered. Accepting such a large loan from these states in 2010 was probably the biggest mistake in Greece’s economic history. Indeed, I would bet most Greeks wished now there really had been a no-bailout rule.

Stability of General Equilibrium and Monetary Policy: Baby Steps

The very sharp Nick Rowe has a useful piece today giving the baby-step intuition behind Schmidt and Woodford’s argument that, no, expected and actual inflation do not as a rule decline one-for-one when a central bank lowers nominal interest rates:

Nick Rowe: Understanding Schmidt and Woodford on Neo-Fisherianism: “Suppose you are really bad at algebra… can’t solve…

…X = 0.5X. So you make a tentative first guess at the answer, say X=1, plug your guess into the right hand side, get X=0.5, which is your second guess, which you plug into the right hand side again, to get X=0.25, which is your third guess, and so on. Eventually your guesses converge to X=0… tatonnement (groping) towards the answer, just like the Walrasian auctioneer who solves the supply and demand equations in micro by raising prices if there’s excess demand, and cutting prices if there’s excess supply. But… if the equation is X = 2X… your guesses will diverge further and further away from the right answer….

Now let’s look at the Neo-Fisherian question. Let P be actual inflation, let Pe be expected inflation, Y be the output gap, i the nominal interest rate set by the central bank, and r the natural rate of interest.: P=Pe+aY… a>0 (Phillips Curve). Y=-c(i-Pe-r)… c>0(IS Curve)…. P=(1+ac)Pe-ac(i-r). If the central bank holds i fixed… P=bPe+stuff… b>1. You can see the problem. If people try to solve for the rational expectations equilibrium using the tatonnement process, it won’t converge…. The rational expectations equilibrium does exist, and is unique, but there is almost zero chance the agents in the model will solve for it by tatonnement…. But if, by sheer fluke, they did guess lucky first time, the solution is: P=Pe=i-r. Yep, it’s the Neo-Fisherian result…. If we want to make 1>b, so the tatonnement does converge, the central bank needs to set the nominal interest rate as a function of actual (or expected) inflation. And it needs to ensure that the nominal interest rate increases more than one-for-one with actual (or expected) inflation. That’s the Howitt/Taylor principle….

We have to interpret this model as saying that the rational expectations equilibrium is implausible if the central bank pegs the nominal interest rate…. Most people are not very good at algebra, the real world is a lot more complicated than any macro model, and people are all different. It’s already stretching it to assume that people can solve the model by tatonnement in their heads, infinitely quickly, provided 1>b. Most of us mortals have to watch what happens, and revise our expectations in the light of experience…

Nick is right: a real model working in real time with real agents and real expectations is greatly, greatly superior either to a model that assumes a rational expectations equilibrium without inquiring into its stability, and greatly superior to a model that looks for a stable rational expectations under reasonable assumptions about expectation-revision tatonnement. But if you do not get there under reasonable assumptions about expectation-revision tatonnement, you will not get there under a a real model working in real time with real agents and real expectations either.

One of my interlocutors says that I should look at the so-called “neo-Fisherian” claim (which Irving Fisher would laugh it as revealing a truly awesome degree of stupidity) as performing not an economic knowledge-advancing but rather a community-sociological function. It allows most of the under briefed economists who didn’t do their homework to understand the situation in 2008-9 to climb down from the position that their nuttier members like likes of Clifford Asness, Niall Ferguson, and Douglas Holtz-Eakin are still clinging to–that the burst of inflation is coming any day now. And it allows them to do so without admitting that Paul Krugman, Mike Woodford, Gauti Eggertsson, and the rest of the dirty f—ing hippie new Keynesians were right about the state of the economy in 2008-9. And that is why they are so averse to requiring sensible stability-based selection rules for classifying model equilibria.

He may be right.

Alternatively, they may just still not have done their homework.

Beware of simple U.S. tax reform plans

Senator Russell B. Long, chairman of the Senate Finance Committee during the late 1960s and the 1970s, once remarked that efforts to reform the tax system worked under principle of “don’t tax me, don’t tax thee, tax the man behind that tree.” When U.S. politicians try to restructure the tax system, the pressure is always there to figure out a way to raise revenue on some ill-favored group or reduce the tax burden of citizens who have curried favor.

In order to combat this instinct, some economists and policymakers propose moving to a flat income tax, where every earner in the country pays a fixed percentage of his or her income, regardless of how much they make. Others argue that a consumption tax would be a better way to structure the tax code, with everyone paying taxes only on what they consume. A combination of these two plans are often bandied about, too.

But the straightforward and seemingly fair idea of taxing everyone at the same rate or for the same activity isn’t so simple. Having every earner pay the same share of their income seems fair at first glance, but abolishing the U.S.’s progressive tax structure would radically increase the amount of income inequality in the United States.

Today’s progressive tax structure helps reduce what economists call “post-tax-and-transfer income inequality” by taxing the wealthy at higher rates. That federal income is then used to pay for government programs that help alleviate economic inequality, among them supplemental nutrition assistance and medical insurance. Since the 1980s, however, the federal tax system has become less progressive, accomplishing less and less to reduce income inequality. These tax reductions on high-income earners are pitched as growth-boosting reforms. But, research shows that tax cuts targeted toward low- and middle-income earners are more effective, and that previous tax cuts for the wealthy have led to higher inequality, but not stronger growth.

There’s a distributional issue with consumption taxes as well. Again, taxing everyone at the same rate for the same activity also seems quite fair, but only if you don’t think too hard about it. Everyone might pay the same sales tax, for example, but low- and middle-income households consume a larger fraction of their income, so they would bear more of the burden of the taxation. We can see this playing out already in state tax systems, which rely more upon sales taxation. The government of Washington State uses sales and excise taxes quite a bit. The result is that households with incomes in the bottom 20 percent of earners pay, on average, 16.8 percent of their income in state and local taxes. The top 1 percent pays only 2.4 percent of their income to state and local government.

Sometimes flat-tax and consumption-tax plans are combined together. These ideas reached a recent apotheosis in the “9-9-9” plan proposed by former presidential candidate Herman Cain in 2011. His proposed reform would have created a tax system with three taxes all levied at 9 percent: a national sales tax, a business tax, and an individual tax. The combined three taxes would be equivalent to a 25 percent national sales tax, according to the Tax Policy Center. The result of such a plan, according to the think tank’s calculations, would be an incredibly regressive tax system. U.S. taxpayers with incomes below $200,000 a year, approximately 90 percent of the country, would see a tax increase on average, while those above would see a tax decrease.

Simple and elegant doesn’t necessarily mean efficient or fair, at least when it comes to tax systems. More research needs to be done by proponents of the flat tax and the consumption tax, taking into account whether and how such reforms would affect income inequality and economic growth.

Must-Read: Ryan Avent: Inequality and Growth

Must-Read: Ryan Avent: The Economist explains: How inequality Affects Growth: “INEQUALITY sits at the top of the political agenda…

…On June 15th economists at the IMF released a study assessing the causes and consequences of rising inequality…. Governments should be especially concerned about its effects on growth. They estimate that a one percentage point increase in the income share of the top 20% will drag down growth by 0.08 percentage points over five years, while a rise in the income share of the bottom 20% actually boosts growth…. Inequality could impair growth if those with low incomes suffer poor health and low productivity as a result, or if, as evidence suggests, the poor struggle to finance investments in education. Inequality could also threaten public confidence in growth-boosting policies…. Inequality could lead to economic or financial instability…. In moderation, redistribution seems to have benign effects—perhaps by reducing dependence on risky borrowing among poorer households. Over the past generation or two inequality has risen most in places where progressive policies, such as high top tax-rates, have been weakened. A little more redistribution now might improve the quality and quantity of economic growth—and reduce the demand for more aggressive state interventions later.

Must-Read: Charlie Stross (2007): The High Frontier, Redux

Must-Read: Charlie Stross (2007): The High Frontier, Redux: “When you get down to it, there’s not really any economically viable activity on the horizon…

…for people to engage in that would require them to settle on a planet or asteroid and live there for the rest of their lives. In general, when we need to extract resources from a hostile environment we tend to build infrastructure to exploit them (such as oil platforms) but we don’t exactly scurry to move our families there. Rather, crews go out to work a long shift, then return home to take their leave. After all, there’s no there there–just a howling wilderness of north Atlantic gales and frigid water that will kill you within five minutes of exposure. And that, I submit, is the closest metaphor we’ll find for interplanetary colonization. Most of the heavy lifting more than a million kilometres from Earth will be done by robots, overseen by human supervisors who will be itching to get home and spend their hardship pay. And closer to home, the commercialization of space will be incremental and slow, driven by our increasing dependence on near-earth space for communications, positioning, weather forecasting, and (still in its embryonic stages) tourism. But the domed city on Mars is going to have to wait for a magic wand or two to do something about the climate, or reinvent a kind of human being who can thrive in an airless, inhospitable environment. Colonize the Gobi desert, colonise the North Atlantic in winter–then get back to me about the rest of the solar system!