Must-reads: March 31, 2016


Must-read: Daniel Gross: “The Ties that Bind: Railroad Gauge Standards and Internal Trade in the 19th Century U.S.”

Must-Read: Really neat piece on technology standards and antitrust: On June 1, 1886, U.S. railroads converted the U.S. South to the national gauge… and increased their own profits enormously, but because they effectively colluded on freight rates there were no increases in railroad-sector consumer surplus generated by this advance in efficiency in the short run. The takeaways: standards matter a lot, and for the health of the overall market and for equitable growth market competition and antitrust policy matter even more:

Daniel P. Gross: The Ties that Bind: Railroad Gauge Standards and Internal Trade in the 19th Century U.S.: “Technology standards are pervasive in the modern economy…

…and a target for public and private investments, yet evidence on their economic importance is scarce. I study the conversion of 13,000 miles of railroad track in the U.S. South to standard gauge between May 31 and June 1, 1886 as a large-scale natural experiment in technology-standards adoption that instantly integrated the South into the national transportation network…. I find a large redistribution of traffic from steamships to railroads serving the same route that declines with route distance, with no change in prices and no evidence of effects on aggregate shipments, likely due to collusion by Southern carriers. Counterfactuals… suggest that if the cartel were broken, railroads would have passed through nearly 70 percent of their cost savings from standardization, generating a 20 percent increase in trade on the sampled routes. The results demonstrate the economic value of technology standards and the potential benefits of compatibility in recent international treaties to establish transcontinental railway networks, while highlighting the mediating influence of product market competition on the public gains to standardization.

Must-reads: March 30, 2016


Must-read: Jonathan Chait: “Oh, Good, It’s 2016 and We’re Arguing Whether Marxism Works”

Must-Read: Jonathan Chait: Oh, Good, It’s 2016 and We’re Arguing Whether Marxism Works: “[Tyler] Zimmer is articulating the standard left-wing critique of political liberalism…

…illiberal left-wing ideologies, Marxist and otherwise, follow the same basic structure… reject… free speech as a positive good enjoyed by all… conclu[de] that political advocacy on behalf of the oppressed enhances freedom, and political advocacy on behalf of the oppressor diminishes it.

It does not take much imagination to draw a link between this idea and the Gulag. The gap between Marxist political theory and the observed behavior of Marxist regimes is tissue-thin…. [The] party… [that is] the authentic representative of the oppressed… [can] shut down all opposition…. [And] Marxists reserve for themselves the right to decide ‘which forms of expression deserve protection and which don’t,’ [so] the result of the deliberation is perfectly obvious…

Watching as the Federal Reserve juggles priceless eggs in variable gravity…

Is it necessary to say that we hold Ben Bernanke, Mervyn King, Mark Carney, Janet Yellen, Stan Fischer, Lael Brainard, and company to the highest of high standards–demand from them constant triple aerial somersaults on the trapeze–because we have the greatest respect for and confidence in them? It probably is…

Back in 1992 Larry Summers and I wrote that pushing the target inflation rate from 5% down to 2% was a very dubious and hazardous enterprise because the zero-lower bound was potentially a big deal: “The relaxation of monetary policy seen over the past three years in the United States would have been arithmetically impossible had inflation and nominal interest rates both been three percentage points lower in 1989. Thus a more vigorous policy of reducing inflation to zero in the mid-1980s might have led to a recent recession much more severe than we have in fact seen…”

This does seem, in retrospect, to have been quite possibly the smartest and most foresightful thing I have ever written. Future historians will, I think, have a very difficult time explaining how the cult of 2%/year inflation targeting got itself established in the 1990s. And they will, I think, have an even harder time explaining why the first monetary policymaker reaction to 2008-2012 was not to endorse Olivier Blanchard et al.’s call for a higher, 4%/year, inflation target in the coded terms of IMF speak:

The great moderation (Gali and Gambetti 2009) lulled macroeconomists and policymakers alike in the belief that we knew how to conduct macroeconomic policy. The crisis clearly forces us to question that assessment….

The crisis has shown that large adverse shocks do happen. Should policymakers aim for a higher target inflation rate in normal times, in order to increase the room for monetary policy to react to such shocks? Are the net costs of inflation much higher at, say, 4% than at 2%, the current target range? Is it more difficult to anchor expectations at 4% than at 2%? Achieving low inflation through central bank independence has been a historic accomplishment. Thus, answering these questions implies carefully revisiting the benefits and costs of inflation.

A related question is whether, when the inflation rate becomes very low, policymakers should err on the side of a more lax monetary policy, so as to minimize the likelihood of deflation, even if this means incurring the risk of higher inflation in the event of an unexpectedly strong pickup in demand. This issue, which was on the mind of the Fed in the early 2000s, is one we must return to…

But instead we got a very different reaction. Sudeep Reddy reported on it back in 2009:

Sudeep Reddy (2009): Sen. Vitter Presents End-of-Term Exam For Bernanke: “Earlier this month, Real Time Economics presented questions from several economists…

…for the confirmation hearing of Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke…. Sen. David Vitter (R., La.) submitted them in writing and received the responses from Bernanke….

D. Brad Delong, University of California at Berkeley and blogger: Why haven’t you adopted a 3% per year inflation target?

[Bernanke:] The public’s understanding of the Federal Reserve’s commitment to price stability helps to anchor inflation expectations and enhances the effectiveness of monetary policy, thereby contributing to stability in both prices and economic activity. Indeed, the longer-run inflation expectations of households and businesses have remained very stable over recent years. The Federal Reserve has not followed the suggestion of some that it pursue a monetary policy strategy aimed at pushing up longer-run inflation expectations.

In theory, such an approach could reduce real interest rates and so stimulate spending and output. However, that theoretical argument ignores the risk that such a policy could cause the public to lose confidence in the central bank’s willingness to resist further upward shifts in inflation, and so undermine the effectiveness of monetary policy going forward.

The anchoring of inflation expectations is a hard-won success that has been achieved over the course of three decades, and this stability cannot be taken for granted. Therefore, the Federal Reserve’s policy actions as well as its communications have been aimed at keeping inflation expectations firmly anchored.

This sounds like nothing so much as the explanations offered in the 1920s and 1930s for returning to and sticking with the gold standard at pre-WWI parities, and the explanations offered at the start of the 1990s by British Tories for sticking to the fixed parities of the then-Exchange Rate Mechanism. The short answer is that real useful positive credibility is not built by attempts to stick to policies that are in the long run destructive–and hence both incredible and stupid. As we learn more about the economy and as the structure of the economy changes, the optimal long-run policy strategy changes as well. Credibility arising from a commitment that the Federal Reserve will seek to follow an optimal long-run policy framework and to accurately convey its intentions but will revise that framework in light of knowledge and events is worth gaining and maintaining. Credibility arising from a commitment to stick, come hell or high water, to a number that Alan Greenspan essentially pulled out of the air with next to no substantive analytical backing in terms of optimal-control analysis is not.

Now, however, we have another answer from Janet Yellen: that the zero lower bound is not, in fact, such a big deal:

Janet Yellen: The Outlook, Uncertainty, and Monetary Policy: “One must be careful, however, not to overstate the asymmetries affecting monetary policy at the moment…

…Even if the federal funds rate were to return to near zero, the FOMC would still have considerable scope to provide additional accommodation. In particular, we could use the approaches that we and other central banks successfully employed in the wake of the financial crisis to put additional downward pressure on long-term interest rates and so support the economy–specifically, forward guidance about the future path of the federal funds rate and increases in the size or duration of our holdings of long-term securities.10 While these tools may entail some risks and costs that do not apply to the federal funds rate, we used them effectively to strengthen the recovery from the Great Recession, and we would do so again if needed.

Over on the Twitter Machine, the very-sharp Tim Duy–I take it from his picture that there is ample snowpack for the ski resorts in the Cascade Range–is impressed by how different the tone of this speech is with the get-ready-for-liftoff speeches of last fall:

And Dario Perkins and Mark Grady have chimed in in support: “suddenly she’s realised the rest of the world matters!…” and “lots of common messages, but emphasis v[ery] diff[erent] on the risks. And no mention of lags or falling behind the curve at all…”

I, by contrast, am still struck by the gap that remains between where she seems to be and where I am.

For there is a natural next set of questions to ask anyone who says that the zero lower bound and the liquidity trap are not big deals. That set is:

  • Then why isn’t nominal GDP on its pre-2008 trend growth path?

  • Why is the five-year ahead five-year market inflation outlook so pessimistic?

  • Why hasn’t the Federal Reserve pushed interest rates low enough so that investment as a whole counterbalances the collapse in government purchases we have seen since 2010?

Gross Domestic Product FRED St Louis Fed Graph 5 Year 5 Year Forward Inflation Expectation Rate FRED St Louis Fed FRED Graph FRED St Louis Fed

I cannot help but be struck by the difference between what I see as the attitude of the current Federal Reserve, anxious not to do anything to endanger its “credibility”, and the Greenspan Fed of the late 1990s, which assumed that it had credibility and that because it had credibility it was free to experiment with policies that seemed likely to be optimal in the moment precisely because markets understood its long-term objective function and trusted it, and hence would not take short-run policy moves as indicative of long-run policy instability. There is a sense in which credibility is like a gold reserve: It is there to be drawn on and used in emergencies. The gold standard collapsed into the Great Depression in the 1930s in large part because both the Bank of France and the Federal Reserve believed that their gold reserves should never decline, but always either stay stable of increase.

It was Mark Twain who said that although history does not repeat itself, it does rhyme. The extent to which this is true was brought home to me recently by Barry Eichengreen’s excellent Hall of Mirrors

I tell you, I have a brand new set of lectures to write for a large monetary-policy module in American Economic History…

Must-read: Janet Yellen: “The Outlook, Uncertainty, and Monetary Policy”

Must-Read: Back in 1992 Larry Summers and I wrote that pushing the target inflation rate from 5% down to 2% was a very dubious and hazardous enterprise because the zero-lower bound was potentially a big deal: “The relaxation of monetary policy seen over the past three years in the United States would have been arithmetically impossible had inflation and nominal interest rates both been three percentage points lower in 1989. Thus a more vigorous policy of reducing inflation to zero in the mid-1980s might have led to a recent recession much more severe than we have in fact seen…”

Now we have an answer from Janet Yellen: that the zero lower bound is not, in fact, such a big deal:

Janet Yellen: The Outlook, Uncertainty, and Monetary Policy: “One must be careful, however, not to overstate the asymmetries affecting monetary policy at the moment…

…Even if the federal funds rate were to return to near zero, the FOMC would still have considerable scope to provide additional accommodation. In particular, we could use the approaches that we and other central banks successfully employed in the wake of the financial crisis to put additional downward pressure on long-term interest rates and so support the economy–specifically, forward guidance about the future path of the federal funds rate and increases in the size or duration of our holdings of long-term securities.10 While these tools may entail some risks and costs that do not apply to the federal funds rate, we used them effectively to strengthen the recovery from the Great Recession, and we would do so again if needed.

The natural next question to ask then is: Then why isn’t nominal GDP on its pre-2008 trend growth path? Why is the five-year ahead five-year market inflation outlook so pessimistic? Why hasn’t the Federal Reserve pushed interest rates low enough so that investment as a whole counterbalances the collapse in government purchases we have seen since 2010?

Gross Domestic Product FRED St Louis Fed Graph 5 Year 5 Year Forward Inflation Expectation Rate FRED St Louis Fed FRED Graph FRED St Louis Fed

The gig economy? Or the fissured workplace?

The growth of online apps like Uber has ignited a debate about the “gig economy,” in which people don’t hold regular jobs in traditional workplaces but rather work in some “alternative arrangement.” Research on the gig economy, however, finds that it reaches much deeper into the labor market than most observers realize.

If there were a measure that showed the ratio of hype to actual impact on the U.S. economy, the rise of online “gig economy” companies like Uber would certainly rank quite high on it. Uber and its ilk have been hailed as companies that will usher in a new kind of work that will have a significant impact on the employer-to-employee relationship. But until now, the data haven’t shown that much about the kind of employment we’d see at these firms. And any sign of increased contracting work in the data show that the rise in contracting far precedes the advent of app-based ride sharing companies. New research, however, shows that the online gig economy may have distracted us from the importance of the rise of another major trend in the labor market.

Anna Louie Sussman and Josh Zumbrun of the Wall Street Journal highlight research by economists Larry Katz and Alan Krueger on the changing employment relationships that U.S. workers find themselves in these days. For a period of time, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics conducted the Contingent Worker Survey, which asked workers about the amount of contingent or temporary work that they were doing. Such a survey could tell us more about how much firms contract out labor, but it hasn’t been conducted since 2005. (Fortunately, the Department of Labor plans on bringing the survey back in 2017.)

With some help from the RAND Corporation, though, Katz and Krueger replicated the survey for 2015 and found a significant increase in the amount of non-standard work, or work where a laborer isn’t a direct employee of the firm they work for. According to the two economists, the share of U.S. workers in these “alternative arrangements” grew significantly from 10 percent in 2005 to 16 percent in 2015. The increase was across a wide number of industries such as manufacturing, health and education, and public administration. Online gig economy companies had quite a small impact, however, as they account for less than 0.5 percent of the U.S. labor force. And there’s a pretty good chance that the “online gig labor force” is a synonym for “Uber drivers.”

So if apps aren’t the main driver of the rise in non-standard work, then what’s behind this transformation? Sussman and Zumbrun note that this increase could be the result of the “fissured workplace,” a trend highlighted by David Weil who’s now at the U.S. Department of Labor as the Administrator of the Wage and Hour Division. Weil’s story has less to do with disruptive technology and more with companies outsourcing many jobs that would usually be inside the firm to focus on their “core competencies.”

As part of the fissuring of the workplace, workers and roles that were not at the heart of the firm’s particular strength were shed, and contractor firms were formed to provide these jobs. As many of these contracted-out jobs were lower-paying jobs, this may explain some of the increase in inter-firm inequality as low- and high-wage workers ended up working at different firms.

As such, the term “gig economy” is probably not the best way to describe the actual increases in contingent and alternative work in the U.S. labor market. The Uber driver who can control when they drive by opening and closing an app is not the poster child for this trend. Rather, it seems the trend reaches much further in the U.S. labor market than most observers realize

Must-read: Branko Milanovic and Suresh Naidu: Branko Milanovic’s New Approach to Global Inequality

Must-Read: Branko Milanovic and Suresh Naidu: Branko Milanovic’s New Approach to Global Inequality: “Convergence and Divergence Across Nations Reinforced or Damped by Kuznets Waves within Nations…

…Global inequality can be broken down into inequality between countries (btw US & Mexico) & within them (among US citizens). Within-country inequality is driven by “Kuznets waves” & between country by economic growth convergence. Real income growth has been quite strong for the global middle class (Vietnam, China, etc), but weak for 80th-90th percentile (US lower MC)…. Migration is the most powerful tool for the reduction of global poverty and inequality

Must-Read: Matthew Yglesias: “Brian D. McKenzie’s ‘Political Perceptions in the Obama Era

Must-Read: Racial animosity, myths of betrayal, and fear of poverty and economic insecurity all combined together in a cocktail–but at least it’s an ethos!

Matthew Yglesias: “Brian D. McKenzie’s ‘Political Perceptions in the Obama Era: Diverse Opinions of the Great Recession and its Aftermath among Whites, Latinos and Blacks’…

…The Kaiser Family Foundation and the Washington Post working with some scholars from Harvard to look at race and the recession… included one question asking whether Obama has done ‘too much’ in terms of ‘ looking out for the economic interests of African Americans’ and another one asking which racial groups had been hardest hit by the recession. The results….

Numerous whites overlook the economic evidence that blacks were substantially harmed on multiple fronts during the recession and instead believe this group was unfairly aided by a sitting black president. These perceptual biases shape whites’ political opinions and are associated with feelings of financial frustration and higher levels of blame toward the government…. Interestingly, while many whites believe that African Americans are the beneficiaries of favorable economic policies from the Obama administration, blacks themselves do not feel they have been uniquely assisted financially (Harris 2012; Harris and Lieberman 2013).

This ties together white nationalist themes, economic anxiety themes, and populist anti-establishment themes nicely–a large bloc of white voters believes they are suffering economically because their elected representatives in Washington betrayed their interests in order to help nonwhites….

Following Mitt Romney’s defeat in 2012, the leadership of the Republican Party decided that they wanted to go in the exact opposite direction… the GOP would present itself as a modern, cosmopolitan, forward-thinking vehicle for right-of-center economic policy. Conservatism would be an ideology for everyone, not just for white people terrified that all their money was going to be spent on Obamaphones and hip-hop barbecues…. This sent… the wrong message to an important element of the GOP base… that their own party’s leaders were planning to betray them….

Resentful white people perceive themselves to be in a zero-sum clash for resources and opportunities with African Americans and Latinos, and want candidates who will champion their interests rather than throw them overboard in pursuit of a broader electoral coalition.