Must-read: Jim Zarroli: Raj Chetty et al.’s Life Expectancy Study: It’s Not Just What You Make, It’s Where You Live

Must-Read: Jim Zarroli: Life Expectancy Study: It’s Not Just What You Make, It’s Where You Live: “Poor people who reside in expensive, well-educated cities such as San Francisco…

…tend to live longer than low-income people in less affluent places, according to a study of more than a billion Social Security and tax records…. The poor tend to have shorter lifespans…. But it also says that among low-income people, big disparities exist in life expectancy from place to place, said Raj Chetty, professor of economics at Stanford University. ‘There are some places where the poor are doing quite well, gaining just as much in terms of life span as the rich, but there are other places where they’re actually going in the other direction, where the poor are living shorter lives today than they did in the past,’ Chetty said…. Low-income people in Birmingham, Ala., live about as long as the rich, but in Tampa, Fla., the poor have actually lost ground…. ‘Men in the top 1 percent distribution level live about 15 years longer than men in the bottom 1 percent on the income distribution in the United States…. Men in the bottom 1 percent have life expectancy comparable to the average life expectancy in Pakistan or Sudan.’

Since 2001, life-expectancy has increased by 2.3 years for the wealthiest 5 percent of American men and by nearly 3 percent for similarly-situated women. Meanwhile, life expectancy has increased barely at all for the poorest 5 percent…. What accounts for the disparity isn’t clear, Chetty says. It may be that some cities such as San Francisco may be better at promoting healthier lifestyles, with smoking bans, for example, or perhaps people tend to adopt healthier habits if they live in a place where everyone else is doing it, he says. The study suggests that the relationship between life expectancy and income is not iron-clad, and changes at the local level can make a big difference. ‘What our study shows is that thinking about these issues of inequality and health and life expectancy at a local level is very fruitful, and thinking about policies that change health behaviors at a local level is likely to be important,’ he says…

Raj Chetty et al.: The Association Between Income and Life Expectancy in the United States, 2001-2014

Must-read: Noah Smith: “101ism in Action: Minimum Wage Edition”

Must-Read: Noah Smith waxes wroth about really lousy economics perpetrated by Alex Tabarrok, Mark Perry of the invariably-execrable American Enterprise Institute (sorry Norm Ornstein: you inhabit a really bad neighborhood), and a guy who puts things on the internet while remaining anonymous. It need not to be said that randomly tweeting art put on the internet by guys who do not have real names rarely ends well…

But it does need to be said that, for Noah, “Econ 101ism” involves pretending that Econ 101 says things that it does not–that it involves getting the elementary economics 180 degrees wrong, all the while claiming that you are merely parroting elementary economics.

I suggest renaming it: “False-Flag Econ 101ism”. But Noah is right on the big point. This one is a beauty, for Econ 101–the real Econ 101–tells us that the first-order effect of a minimum wage is to transfer wealth from consumers and business owners to low-wage workers…

Noah Smith: 101ism in Action: Minimum Wage Edition: “American Enterprise Institute scholar Mark J. Perry tweeted the following

Noahpinion 101ism in action minimum wage edition

…I was annoyed by the word ‘actually’…. So I started giving Mark a hard time about ignoring the empirical evidence on the minimum wage question. That’s when Alex Tabarrok jumped in and defended the cartoon, saying that it’s just a basic supply-and-demand model…. But that’s not right…. While the cartoon and the D-S model both predict that minimum wage causes job loss, it’s only a coincidence–they’re not the same model at all… some sloppy political crap made by a cartoonist who doesn’t remember his intro econ class very well…

Must-read: Matthew Klein: “Private Equity’s Mark-to-Make-Believe Problem”

Must-Read: Matthew Klein: Private Equity’s Mark-to-Make-Believe Problem: “No asset is inherently worth anything…

…just some multiple of the income you think it will produce over time. Both the earnings forecast and the multiple can change at a moment’s notice–sometimes because the outlook for the future has genuinely changed, but often for other reasons…. One sensible response is nihilism: the great appeal of buy-and-hold passive investing is you don’t need to have any opinions…. Others… still try to earn a living betting some of today’s market prices will change, often but not always because they think the average opinion is improperly interpreting the available information. Then there are those, such as private equity firms, who invest in illiquid assets. ‘Illiquid’ in this case means ‘thing that’s almost never traded’, which in practice means ‘we won’t pretend to know what it’s ‘worth’ in the absence of a market, but here’s a number if it makes you feel better’. (This is distinct from the other meaning of ‘illiquid’… which is ‘oh of course we’re good for the money, we just don’t have it on us right now’, usually in response to questions such as ‘I’m not getting back what I lent you because you blew it retaining junior tranches in subprime mortgage bonds, am I?’)…

Must-read: Susan Dynarski: “Why Talented Black and Hispanic Students Can Go Undiscovered”

Must-Read: Susan Dynarski: Why Talented Black and Hispanic Students Can Go Undiscovered: “Broward County…. More than half of its students are black or Hispanic…

…Yet, as of 10 years ago, just 28 percent of the third graders who were identified as gifted were black or Hispanic…. Broward County introduced a universal screening program, requiring that all second graders take a short nonverbal test, with high scorers referred for I.Q. testing…. David Card… and Laura Giuliano… studied the effects of this policy shift…. The share of Hispanic children identified as gifted tripled, to 6 percent from 2 percent. For black children, the share rose to 3 percent from 1 percent. For whites, the increase was more muted, to 8 percent from 6 percent…. Teachers and parents were less likely to refer high-ability blacks and Hispanics, as well as children learning English as a second language, for I.Q. testing. The universal test leveled the playing field….

Broward requires that schools with even one child who tests above the I.Q. cutoff devote an entire classroom to gifted and high-achieving children. Since a school in Broward rarely had enough gifted children to fill a class, these classrooms were topped off with children from the same school who scored high on the district’s standardized test. These high achievers, especially black and Hispanics, showed large increases in math and reading when placed in a class for the gifted, and these effects persisted…. All of these gains came at little financial cost….

Despite these positive results, Broward County suspended its universal screening program in 2010 during a spate of budget cutting in the aftermath of the Great Recession. Racial and ethnic disparities re-emerged, as large as they were before the policy change…

Notes on the global economy as of early April 2016

A Note on the Likelihood of Recession: With global inflation currently more than quiescent, there is no chance that global recovery will be—as Rudi Dornbusch used to say—assassinated by inflation-fighting central banks raising interest rates.

As for recovery being assassinated by financial chaos, we face a paradox here: Financial risks that policymakers and economists can see are those that bankers can see and hedge against as well. It is only the financial risks that policymakers and economists do not see that are truly dangerous. Many back in 2005 saw the global imbalance of China’s export surplus and feared disaster from a fall in the dollar coupled with the discovery of money-center institutions having sold massive amounts of unhedged dollar puts. Very few, if any–even among those who believed US housing was a massive bubble likely to pop—feared that any problems created thereby would not be rapidly handled and neutralized by the Federal Reserve.

The most likely danger of recession is thus absent, and the second most likely danger is unknowable.

That leaves the third: a global economy that drifts into a downturn because both fiscal and monetary policymakers sit on their hands and refuse to use the stimulative demand management tools they have.

Here there is, I think, some reason to fear. A passage from a recent speech by the nearly-godlike Stan Fischer was flagged to me by Tim Duy:

If the recent financial market developments lead to a sustained tightening of financial conditions, they could signal a slowing in the global economy that could affect growth and inflation in the United States. But we have seen similar periods of volatility in recent years–including in the second half of 2011–that have left little visible imprint on the economy, and it is still early to judge the ramifications of the increased market volatility of the first seven weeks of 2016. As Chair Yellen said in her testimony to the Congress two weeks ago, while “global financial developments could produce a slowing in the economy, I think we want to be careful not to jump to a premature conclusion about what is in store for the U.S. economy”…

And Tim commented:

This… again misses the Fed’s response to financial turmoil…. I really do not understand how Fed officials can continue to dismiss market turmoil using comparisons to past episodes when those episodes triggered a monetary policy response. They don’t quite seem to understand the endogeneity in the system…

However, anything that could be called a “global recession” in the near term still looks like a less than 20% chance to me. But that is up from a 5% chance nine months ago.


A Note on China: I do not understand China. And I know I do not understand China. Perhaps that gives me an advantage in analyzing China, perhaps not. The relevant long-run fundamentals of China seem to me to be two:

  1. Your typical wealthy Chinese plutocrat-political clan seeks in the long run to have perhaps 1/3 of its wealth outside of China as insurance against political risks, and thus seeks an opportunity to export capital from China.
  2. Your typical North Atlantic business or investment group sees returns from further massive investments in China as uncertain and sees political risks as large but as capable of resolution over the next decade, and so will delay investing in China.

That means renminbi weakness as a background trend behind shorter-term financial- and political-business cycles. And that has to shape what the real risks are (large) and opportunities (smaller).

A Note on the Non-Need for a New Plaza Accord: I would say that international monetary affairs in the Global North high now need not an accord but, rather, the right kind of discord.

At my Berkeley office I dwell in the zone of influence of the truly formidable Barry Eichengreen. His strongly, and I believe correctly, argued view is essentially that he set out in Eichengreen and Sachs (1986): that what we need is not an accord but a currency war. Global North blocs—the U.S., Britain, the Eurozone, Japan—leapfrogging each other with aggressive competitive devaluations every four months or so are likely to produce positive monetary spillovers as large as anything that monetary policy could now produce.

But what could monetary policy now produce?

My career analytical nadir was my memo to my Treasury bosses in 1993 that NAFTA was likely to put upward pressure on the peso. My second-worst was my confident prediction at the end of 2008 that within three years North Atlantic nominal demand would be back to its pre-2008 trend. My third has been my prediction that Abenomics would be an obvious and substantial success. That third prediction was based on my reading of the 1930s, in which four aggressive reflationary régime changes—that of Neville Chamberlain as Chancellor of the Exchequer in 1931, that of Takahashi Korekiyo as Finance Minister in 1932, that of Hjalmar Horace Greeley Schacht as Reichsbank President in 1933, and that of Franklin Delano Roosevelt as President in 1933—had been substantial successes. The mixed success of Abenomics thus tells me that my views of what monetary policy tools would work and how well they would work are almost surely wrong, and that I need to rethink.

Thus as far as monetary policy is concerned I am at sea.

With respect to fiscal policy, however, I am much more confident: Blanchard and Leigh (2013) is convincing. DeLong and Summers (2012) is correct. Coordinated North Atlantic fiscal expansion—unless the money is spent in a truly perverse fashion—is highly likely to boost production with North Atlantic-wide multipliers of around 3 and to reduce debt-to-GDP ratios. Whether it will generate enough inflation to be unwelcome hinges on the state of aggregate supply in the North Atlantic. And there we are so far outside the bounds of previous experience that I do not think anyone can or should speak with confidence.

A Note on Negative Interest Rates: Cash should be a very attractive asset vis-a-vis Treasury bonds at any negative or, indeed, slightly positive interest rate. Containers full of durable, storable commodities should be a very attractive asset vis-a-vis cash—and more so vis-a-vis Treasury bonds and even cash at a wider range of interest rates up to nearly the long-term expected rate of inflation. The only way I can understand current strong demand for the interest-bearing securities and, indeed, the cash of reserve currency-issuing sovereigns possessing exorbitant privilege is that 2008-9 and the political reaction thereto has cast the existence of the Bagehot lender-of-last-resort into grave doubt. Thus we not only have East Asian and other sovereigns desperate for reserves to avoid another 1998, we have every major financial institution desperate to avoid another fall of 2008. These economic agents seem to me to be no longer pursuing sensible risk-return optimization strategies. Instead, they seem to seek enough reserves to surmount any possible future crisis so that they can stay in the game and then earn profits whenever normalization and the future come.

As to dysfunctionalities—so far I see no signs of massive malinvestments in physical or organizational capital that will pay large negative societal returns, and I see no taking of extraordinarily risky large positions by too-big-to-fail entities. I feel that dysfunctional asset prices that produce dysfunctional investments and dysfunctional portfolios. But I cannot see what they are…

Must-read: Robert B. Reich: “Saving Capitalism: For the Many, Not the Few”

Must-Read: Gene Smolensky says Bob Reich’s latest book is truly excellent:

Robert B. Reich: Saving Capitalism: For the Many, Not the Few: “The New Property…

The New Monopoly… The New Contracts… The New Bankruptcy… The Enforcement Mechanism… The Meritocratic Myth… The Hidden Mechanisms of CEO Pay… The Subterfuge of Wall Street Pay… The Declining Bargaining Power of the Middle… The Rise of the Working Poor… The Rise of the Non-Working Rich…

Saving Capitalism For the Many Not the Few Robert B Reich 2015385350570 Amazon com BooksSaving Capitalism For the Many Not the Few Robert B Reich 2015385350570 Amazon com BooksSaving Capitalism For the Many Not the Few Robert B Reich 2015385350570 Amazon com BooksSaving Capitalism For the Many Not the Few Robert B Reich 2015385350570 Amazon com Books

Must-read: Barry Eichengreen: “The Case for a Grand Bargain”

Must-Read: Barry Eichengreen: The Case for a Grand Bargain: “What would it take for all this to happen?…

…First, there would have to be a reassertion of non-ideological economic common sense in U.S. and German policy making circles. One doesn’t have to be a Keynesian to believe that record low interest rates in both countries create a once-in-a-lifetime opportunity for infrastructure spending or to acknowledge that there are aspects of public infrastructure in both countries desperately in need of repair.

Second, central banks in countries lacking fiscal space would have to do more. This means not just talking down the exchange rate as a way of enhancing competitiveness but taking steps to encourage domestic spending, for example ramping up domestic [financial] security purchases still further, and ignoring domestic opposition.

Third, emerging markets and Southern European countries would have to make a credible commitment to structural reform. The need is there, quite independent of international coordination. But without this commitment, international coordination is off the table.

Skeptics will say that I am a dreamer for imagining this grand bargain. But the alternative to this dream is an ongoing economic nightmare.

Weekend reading: “Rewiring the labor market” edition

This is a weekly post we publish on Fridays with links to articles that touch on economic inequality and growth. The first section is a round-up of what Equitable Growth has published this week and the second is work we’re highlighting from elsewhere. We won’t be the first to share these articles, but we hope by taking a look back at the whole week, we can put them in context.

Equitable Growth round-up

Family income growth in the United States over the past 30 or so years has been relatively tepid. This same time period has also seen increased labor market participation from women. Heather Boushey and Kavya Vaghul show that the growth in family incomes would have been much slower if not for women’s increased work hours and earnings.

Equitable Growth released our second set of working papers this week. This month’s batch of papers cover income and earnings mobility, the effect of student loans on the U.S. labor market, the labor market shock due to Chinese imports, and corporate profit shifting.

The leak of the Panama Papers—documents detailing the extensive use of shell corporations based in Panama—has brought more attention to the role of offshore wealth. While many of the headlines around the leaks were about the activities of individuals, it’s worth looking at the global system that lets these havens exist.

In the second interview in the “Equitable Growth in Conversation” series, Heather Boushey talked with Byron Auguste, Managing Director of Opportunity@Work. The two discussed current problems with the U.S. labor market, how these problems may be mostly on the demand side, and how we might “rewire” the labor market.

Speaking of current problems with the labor market, the shift in the Beveridge Curve—the relationship between job openings and the unemployment rate—has sparked concern about structural problems in the labor market. A look at some of the other Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey data should assuage those concerns.

Non-compete agreements might have some justification in making sure workers don’t jump to a competitor with trade secrets. But they seem to have expanded far beyond that original intent and become tools of employers to reduce workers’ bargaining power.

Links from around the web

The United States has experienced a bit of an urban revival in recent decades. But Americans with high incomes are the disproportionate benefactors of this revival. Paul Krugman calls for a reduction in housing construction constraints to help make “cities for everyone.” [ny times]

Alex Taborrak argues that restrictions on land use have reduced mobility in the United States.  “On a national level,” he writes, “land restrictions mean less mobility, lower national productivity and increased income and geographic inequality.” [marginal revolution]

Universal high-quality child care has become an increasingly popular policy proposal as the high price of care and its potential benefits for children have become more clear. As Danielle Paquette details, however, ramping up a universal high-quality program may be difficult. [wonkblog]

According to new figures from the U.S. Department of Education, 43 percent of Americans with federal student loans are behind on their payments, and one in six are in default. Josh Mitchell runs through the numbers. [wsj]

Structural reforms to help boost the long-run, supply-side potential of the economy have long been a key component of the International Monetary Fund’s advice to countries. But Shawn Donnan highlights a new study by IMF economists showing that the effectiveness of those reforms often depends on the macroeconomic conditions at the time of the reforms. [ft]

Friday figure

Figure from “JOLTS and another look at the health of the U.S. labor market” by Nick Bunker