Must-read: Peter Praet: Interview with La Repubblica

Must-Read: SOCIAL CREDIT!! The helicopters are not in the air, not on the runway with rotors spinning, not on the tarmac, but they are in the hangar undergoing maintenance checks…

Peter Praet: Interview with La Repubblica: “External shocks can easily trigger a vicious circle, with further downward pressure on inflation…

…We wanted to ensure that this did not happen, in line with our mandate. It was decided by the vast majority in the Governing Council, that we had to act very forcefully to ensure an even more accommodative monetary policy stance…. We decided in favour of a package which still made use of changes in the ECB interest rates but increased the weight of measures aimed at credit easing…. The measures we took should bring us close to the 2 per cent target at the end of 2018. But don’t forget, the measures we take like the APP are supposed to remain in place as long as inflation has not reached a sustainable adjustment….

There has been a lot of skepticism recently about monetary policy, not only in delivering but in saying ‘your toolbox is empty’. We say, ‘no it’s not true’. There are many things you can do. The question is what is appropriate, and at what time. I think for the time being we have what we have, and it is not appropriate to discuss the next set of measures…. [But] you can issue currency and you distribute it to people. That’s helicopter money. Helicopter money is giving to the people part of the net present value of your future seigniorage…. The question is, if and when is it opportune to make recourse to that sort of instrument…

Must-read: Dean Baker: “The Fed and the Quest to Raise Rates”

Must-Read: Dean Baker: The Fed and the Quest to Raise Rates: “The justification for raising rates is to prevent inflation from getting out of control…

…but inflation has been running well below the Fed’s 2.0 percent target for years. Furthermore, since the 2.0 percent target is an average inflation rate, the Fed should be prepared to tolerate several years in which the inflation rate is somewhat above 2.0 percent… [and] allow for a period in which real wage growth slightly outpaces productivity growth in order to restore the pre-recession split between labor and capital…. The most recent data provide much more reason for concern that the economy is slowing more than inflation is accelerating….

There are many other measures indicating that there continues to be considerable slack in the labor market despite the relatively low unemployment. There are no plausible explanations for the sharp drop in the employment rate of prime-age workers at all education levels from pre-recession levels, apart from the weakness of the labor market. The amount of involuntary part-time employment continues to be unusually high…. And the duration measures of unemployment spells and the share of unemployment due to voluntary quits are both much closer to recession levels than business cycle peaks…

Must-read: Jared Bernstein: “The Fed’s Pause and the Dollar’s Retreat”

Must-Read: Jared Bernstein: The Fed’s Pause and the Dollar’s Retreat: “The linkage between the more dovish U.S. Fed and the recent decline in the dollar…

…is notable…. Last year, net exports subtracted 0.6 of a percentage point from real GDP growth and manufacturing job growth slowed sharply: factory jobs were up 208,000 in 2014 compared to 26,000 last year…. The value of the dollar moves roughly with the odds of a higher Fed funds rate. The decision not to raise at this week’s meeting and the somewhat dovish shift in their statement, which referenced global risks to the US outlook, contributed to a sharp decline in the dollar. In my view, that’s smart policy at work…

Must-read: Nick Rowe: “It’s easier to have a sensible fiscal rule with an NGDP level-path target”

Must-Read: Nick Rowe: It’s easier to have a sensible fiscal rule with an NGDP level-path target: “Even if you are skeptical about the feasibility of a formal fiscal rule…

…it’s a useful thought-experiment to help us be conceptually clear about what we want fiscal policy to look like…. One thing we want… is sustainab[ility] in the long run…. whether we think fiscal policy is or is not needed to help monetary policy stabilise aggregate demand. A sensible fiscal rule would not let the debt/GDP ratio wander off over time towards plus infinity or minus infinity…. We are talking about a ratio of debt to nominal GDP…. A (say) 5% Nominal GDP level-path target… would make it a lot easier to write down a sensible fiscal rule…. If you don’t have an NGDP level-path target, nobody know what NGDP will be be over the coming decades. So nobody knows what average deficit would be sustainable…. Sure, an NGDP level-path target only fixes one problem with getting fiscal policy right. But every little bit helps.

Must-read: Tim Duy: “Stanley Fischer and Lael Brainard Are Battling for Yellen’s Soul”

Must-Read: Tim Duy: Stanley Fischer and Lael Brainard Are Battling for Yellen’s Soul: “Stanley Fischer sits on Chair Janet Yellen’s left shoulder, muttering:

…we may well at present be seeing the first stirrings of an increase in the inflation rate…

Fed Governor Lael Brainard perches on the right, whispering:

…there are risks around this baseline forecast, the most prominent of which lie to the downside.

Yellen is caught in a tug of war between Fischer and Brainard. At stake is the Fed chair’s willingness to embrace a policy stance that accepts the risk that inflation will overshoot the U.S. central bank’s target. At the moment, Brainard has the upper hand in this battle. And she has a new weapon on her side: increasing concerns about the stability of inflation expectations….

Fischer’s not alone. In his group sit Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco President John Williams, Kansas City Fed President Esther George, and Cleveland Fed President Loretta Mester. And Yellen is believed to be reasonably sympathetic to this camp. She’s repeatedly voiced her support of a Phillips curve view of the world—or the idea that, after accounting for the temporary impacts of a strong U.S. dollar and weak oil, inflation will rise as unemployment rates fall…. Indeed, a Phillips curve view is fairly common among monetary policymakers….

So, given the Phillips curve framework’s consistency among policymakers, why delay further rate hikes?… The challenge for further rate hikes is that recent financial instability has exposed the downside risks to the forecast… New York Fed President William Dudley, Philadelphia Fed President Patrick Harker, and Boston Fed President Eric Rosengren…. Financial instability certainly gives the Fed reason to stand still this week. And it gives reason for the Fed to continue to be cautious…

Must-read: David Wessel: “Are We Ready for the Next Recession?”

Must-Read: David Wessel: Are We Ready for the Next Recession?: “Financial markets seem to be anxious that a U.S. recession is on the horizon…

…even though economic forecasters disagree. When the next recession arrives, will fiscal and monetary policy be able to respond? If so, how? The Federal Reserve is holding short-term interest rates near zero and faces resistance, internally and externally, to reviving large-scale purchases of assets. The federal debt is larger, as a share of the economy, than at any time since the end of World War II and is projected to climb further. On March 21, the Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy will consider which fiscal and monetary policy tools will be available in the event of a recession—and which won’t—and how effective additional fiscal and monetary stimulus is likely to be, along with new ideas to make fiscal policy more effective…. David Wessel… Wendy Edelberg… Ben Spielberg… Phillip Swagel… Richard Clarida… Jon Faust… Louise Sheiner… Jared Bernstein

Ordoliberalismus and Ordovolkismus

At the zero lower bound on safe nominal short-term interest rates, an expansionary fiscal policy impetus of d percent of current GDP will:

  1. raise current output by (μ)d,
  2. raise future output by (φμ)d, and
  3. raise the debt to GDP ratio by a proportional amount ΔD = (1 – μτ – μφ)d,

where [mu] is the Keynesian multiplier, τ is the tax rate, and φ is the hysteresis coefficient.

It will then require a commitment of (r-g)ΔD percent of future output the service the additional debt, where r is the real interest rate on government debt and g is the growth rate of the economy. The debt service can be raised through explicit and fiscal deadweight loss-inducing taxation, through inflation–a tax on outside money balances accompanied by disruption of the unit of account–or through financial repression–a tax on the banking system but also imposes financial distortions.

That is the simple arithmetic of expansionary fiscal policy in a liquidity trap.

The question of whether and how much expansionary fiscal policy a government facing a liquidity trap should engage and then becomes a technocratic one of calculating uncertain benefits and uncertain costs. Why uncertain? Because our knowledge of the parameters of the economy is uncertain. And we are particularly uncertain not just of the outcome of the key debt- amortization parameter r-g but of its ex-ante distribution as well. There is this an element of radical, almost Knightian, uncertainty here in the benefit-cost calculation. But it remains a benefit-cost calculation. And rare these days is the competent economist Who has thought through the benefit-cost calculation and failed to conclude that the governments of the United States, Germany, and Britain have large enough multipliers, strong enough hysteresis coefficients for infrastructure investment programs, and sufficient fiscal space–favorable likely distributions of r-g–to make substantially more expansionary fiscal policies than they are currently following almost no-brainers.

It is against the backdrop of this situation that we find aversion to fiscal expansion being driven not by pragmatic technocratic benefit-cost calculations but by raw ideology. And so we find Barry Eichengreen being… shrill:

Barry Eichengreen: Confronting the Fiscal Bogeyman: “The world economy is visibly sinking, and the policymakers who are supposed to be its stewards are tying themselves in knots…

…Or so suggest the results of the G-20 summit held in Shanghai…. All that emerged… was an anodyne statement… structural reforms… avoiding beggar-thy-neighbor policies. Once again, monetary policy was left… the only game in town…. Someone needs to do something to keep the world economy afloat, and central banks are the only agents capable of acting. The problem is that monetary policy is approaching exhaustion….

The solution is straightforward. It is to fix the problem of deficient demand… by boosting public spending. Governments should borrow to invest in research, education, and infrastructure…. Such investments cost little given low interest rates… [and] enhance the returns on private investment [as well]…. Thus it is disturbing to see… particularly… the US and Germany [refusing] to even contemplate such action, despite available fiscal space….

Barry blames Germany’s derangement on the ideology of Ordliberalism:

In Germany, ideological aversion to budget deficits… is rooted in the post-World War II doctrine of ‘ordoliberalism,’ which counseled that government should enforce contracts and ensure adequate competition but otherwise avoid interfering in the economy…. The ordoliberal emphasis on personal responsibility fostered an unreasoning hostility to the idea that actions that are individually responsible do not automatically produce desirable aggregate outcomes…. It rendered Germans allergic to macroeconomics….

Barry blames the U.S. derangement on a somewhat analogous ideological formation—call it Ordovolkism:

[In] the US… citizens have been suspicious of federal government power, including the power to run deficits, which is fundamentally a federal prerogative.… That suspicion was strongest in the American South… rooted in the fear that the federal government might abolish slavery…. During the civil rights movement, it was again the Southern political elite that opposed the muscular use of federal power…. The South [became] a solid Republican bloc and leave its leaders antagonistic to all exercise of federal power except for the enforcement of contracts and competition—a hostility that notably included countercyclical macroeconomic policy. Welcome to ordoliberalism, Dixie-style. Wolfgang Schäuble, meet Ted Cruz.

And Barry concludes by asking:

Ideological and political prejudices deeply rooted in history will have to be overcome to end the current stagnation. If an extended period of depressed growth following a crisis isn’t the right moment to challenge them, then when is?

Barry intends this last as a rhetorical question: It is the great Hillel’s “If not now, when?”, to which the proper answer is: “Then now!”

But it is quite possible that the best answer is, instead: “Never!”

While Austerian fear and suspicion of countercyclical monetary policy is rooted in the same Ordoliberal and Ordovolkist ideological fever swamps as objections to countercyclical fiscal policy, it is much weaker. It is much weaker because fundamentalist cries for an automatic monetary system—whether based on a gold standard, a k%/year percent growth rule, or John Taylor’s interest-rate rule—have crashed and burned so spectacularly so many times that they lack even the barest surface plausibility. History has definitively refuted Henry Simons’s call for rules rather than authority in monetary policy. The near-consensus agreed-upon task of institution design for monetary policy is not to construct rules but, instead, to construct authorities with technocratic competence and sensible objectives and values.

Thus one way around the Ordoliberal and Ordovolkist ideological blockages is to redefine a sufficient quantum of countercyclical fiscal policy as monetary policy. I call this “social credit”. Others call it “helicopter money”. Move the central bank’s seigniorage revenue stream outside of the government’s consolidated budget. Assign the disposition of this revenue stream to the central bank. It is not first-best. It may be good enough to do the job.

Another way of attempting to finesse the problem is to construct a fiscal council of some sort. Such an institution, assigned responsibility for the government’s investment budget, may attract the technocratic competence and status of the central banks, and so outflank Ordoliberal and Ordovolkist ideological blockages. Are haps.

But if neither of these expedients—neither social credit or helicopter money on the one hand nor fiscal councils on the other—will serve, then Barry Eichengreen is completely right: it is long past time for a frontal intellectual assault on the dangerous and destructive ideologies of Ordoliberalism and Ordovolkism.

And that assault would be, itself, part of a broader intellectual struggle. The major point of Steve Cohen’s and my Concrete Economics is precisely that ideology is a very bad guide the economic policy. This is simply another—albeit an unusually important—instance.

Must-read: Stan Fischer: “Reflections on Macroeconomics Then and Now”

Must-Read: Stan Fischer: Reflections on Macroeconomics Then and Now: “In 1961, at the end of my school years, on the advice of a friend…

…I read Keynes’s General Theory for the first time. Did I understand it? Certainly not. Was I captivated by it? Certainly, though ‘captured’ is a more appropriate word than ‘captivated.’ Does it remain relevant? Certainly. Just a week ago I took it off the bookshelf to read parts of chapter 23, ‘Notes on Mercantilism, the Usury Laws, Stamped Money and Theories of Under-Consumption.’ Today that chapter would be headed ‘Protectionism, the Zero Lower Bound, and Secular Stagnation,’ with the importance of usury laws having diminished since 1936.

There is an old joke about our field…. ‘But this is exactly the same as the exam I wrote over 50 years ago.’ ‘Ah yes,’ says the professor. ‘It is the same, but all the answers are different.’ Is that really the case? Not really…. The basic framework we learned a half-century ago remains extremely useful. But also yes: Some of the answers are different because… the problems they deal with were not evident fifty years ago…. Learn as much as you can, for most of it will come in useful at some stage of your career; but never forget that identifying what is happening in the economy is essential to your ability to do your job, and for that you need to keep your eyes, your ears, and your mind open, and with regard to your mouth–to use it with caution.

Must-read: Draghi Day

Must-Read: FastFT: Draghi Day: “Rabobank describes the wild market moves that followed the European Central Bank rates decision and press conference as ‘carnage’…

…Whether that’s the ECB’s fault or the markets’ depends on who you speak to. Here’s a taste…. Jim Reid at Deutsche Bank sees signs of a strop in the market…. “Imagine you were expecting a trip during school holidays in a caravan around the country but instead you can take 2 weeks off school, fly first class to Disneyworld, have a go in the cockpit on the way, stay at a hotel made of chocolate, and then be able to go on every ride every day without queuing and have a private play session with the real Mickey Mouse as each day draws to a close. However if the market was the same kid its reaction yesterday was ‘do I not get unlimited spending money, and where are we going for our summer holidays then?’”…

Frederik Ducrozet at Pictet says ‘don’t fight the ECB’: “Such a policy package designed to boost bank lending and to improve QE implementation should lead to a significant easing of monetary and financial conditions. We are positive on the net impact….” Peter Schaffrik at RBC: “We do not share the negativity and could well imagine that the initiative to engage in risky assets will find more coverage going forward.”… And the economics team at BNP Paribas….

Now for the critics…. Lutz Karpowitz from Commerzbank says the central bank is ‘firing blanks’. He has issues with TLTRO 2, where the banks can effectively fund their lending at negative rates from the ECB…. Grant Lewis from Daiwa…. “The cost of finance is only one consideration for banks when deciding whether to lend or not – of at least equal importance is how the underlying economy, and hence the loan itself, is expected to perform. And on that measure it’s far from certain that today’s announcements will prove transformative to the economic outlook. Indeed, the ECB’s own forecast for 2017 sees growth of just 1.7% and inflation well below target at just 1.3%.” Rabobank’s Piotr Matys says ECB can forget about talking the euro down: “The damage to bearish bets against the euro, however, has been done. Those market participants, including yours truly, who went into the ECB meeting with a bearish view on the euro ended Thursday’s session calculating their losses instead of celebrating profits… after such a massive blow as on Thursday Draghi and other ECB officials may find it even more difficult, if they choose to do so, to talk the euro down.”

Citi‘s rates team says Draghi’s bazooka has ‘backfired’: “The bazooka backfired because the ECB is taking rate cuts off the table. We expect easing to be priced out. The measures do little to convince us that realised inflation will move higher any time soon.” That said, the same bank’s emerging-markets team says ‘the ECB delivered’: “There is now an incentive to move away from a policy fully centered on negative rates, to a toolset centered on further relief of financing in the banking sector. The markets should be cheering that, rather than reacting in a negative way.”

Must-read: John Maynard Keynes (1936): General Theory, chapter 23: “Notes on Mercantilism, the Usury Laws, Stamped Money and Theories of Under-consumption”

Must-Read: John Maynard Keynes (1936): General Theory, chapter 23: “Notes on Mercantilism, the Usury Laws, Stamped Money and Theories of Under-consumption”: “It is impossible to study the notions to which the mercantilists were led by their actual experiences…

…without perceiving that there has been a chronic tendency throughout human history for the propensity to save to be stronger than the inducement to invest. The weakness of the inducement to invest has been at all times the key to the economic problem. To-day the explanation of the weakness of this inducement may chiefly lie in the extent of existing accumulations; whereas, formerly, risks and hazards of all kinds may have played a larger part. But the result is the same. The desire of the individual to augment his personal wealth by abstaining from consumption has usually been stronger than the inducement to the entrepreneur to augment the national wealth by employing labor on the construction of durable assets….

For in an economy subject to money contracts and customs more or less fixed over an appreciable period of time, where the quantity of the domestic circulation and the domestic rate of interest are primarily determined by the balance of payments, as they were in Great Britain before the war, there is no orthodox means open to the authorities for countering unemployment at home except by struggling for an export surplus…. Never in history was there a method devised of such efficacy for setting each country’s advantage at variance with its neighbors’ as the international gold (or, formerly, silver) standard….

It is the policy of an autonomous rate of interest, unimpeded by international preoccupations, and of a national investment programme directed to an optimum level of domestic employment which is twice blessed in the sense that it helps ourselves and our neighbours at the same time. And it is the simultaneous pursuit of these policies by all countries together which is capable of restoring economic health and strength internationally, whether we measure it by the level of domestic employment or by the volume of international trade. The mercantilists perceived the existence of the problem without being able to push their analysis to the point of solving it. But the classical school ignored the problem, as a consequence of introducing into their premisses conditions which involved its non-existence; with the result of creating a cleavage between the conclusions of economic theory and those of common sense. The extraordinary achievement of the classical theory was to overcome the beliefs of the “natural man” and, at the same time, to be wrong….

I remember Bonar Law’s mingled rage and perplexity in face of the economists, because they were denying what was obvious. He was deeply troubled for an explanation. One recurs to the analogy between the sway of the classical school of economic theory and that of certain religions. For it is a far greater exercise of the potency of an idea to exorcise the obvious than to introduce into men’s common notions the recondite and the remote…