Morning Must-Read: Michael Hiltzik: When a State Blocks Obamacare, ERs Close: The Lesson of Louisiana

Michael Hiltzik: When a State Blocks Obamacare, ERs Close: The Lesson of Louisiana: “Baton Rouge… is about to lose one of its crucial hospital emergency rooms….

…Gov. Bobby Jindal has refused to expand Medicaid under the Affordable Care Act, and won’t put up any other money to keep the facility open. Because of the scheduled closure of the ER of Baton Rouge General Medical Center-Mid City, patients needing emergency treatment will have to travel as much as 30 minutes longer…. Jindal has tried to position himself as the last stalwart Republican opponent of the ACA, but his state’s experience shows that his position is folly…. In the expectation that Medicaid would pick up the slack, the ACA reduced so-called disproportionate share hospital payments, which went to hospitals serving a large number of the uninsured. So institutions in states that have refused to expand Medicaid, like Louisiana, have faced a double-whammy–they still have to serve a large number of uninsured patients, but they have less money to do so. The ACA has reduced uncompensated care costs… by $5.7 billion in fiscal 2014 compared with what they would have been otherwise…

Morning Must-Read: Barry Eichengreen: Cassandras and Currency Wars

Barry Eichengreen:: Cassandras and Currency Wars: “Economic analysis, it seems…

…is the art of recycling old ideas under new names. So it is with the debate over currency wars, which parallels exactly the 1930s debate over competitive currency devaluation. David Woo, meet Ragnar Nurkse. Nurkse, in… 1944… [argued that] competitive devaluation was a negative-sum game. These are exactly the arguments made by today’s Cassandras of currency wars…. Subsequent scholarship shows, however, that the main reason monetary policy didn’t work more powerfully in the 1930s was that it wasn’t tried…. Central banks in the 1930s were reluctant to utilise their newfound monetary freedom… failed to make open-ended commitments to raise prices… effectively transform expectations… supplement the new monetary regime with supportive fiscal action… failed to convince investors that they were committed to a fundamentally new policy regime…. And because they failed to coordinate their monetary and exchange rate policies internationally, haphazard exchange rate changes only created volatility and uncertainty, as argued here. Today, in contrast, central banks like the Bank of Japan and European Central Bank are making open-ended commitments to do what it takes…. Without that action and those steps, however, the Cassandras of currency wars will be right.

Morning Must-Read: Tim Duy: On The Fed Credibility Gap

NewImage

Mark Thoma sends us to

Tim Duy: On The Fed Credibility Gap: “David Wessel opines….

The markets think Fed officials and staff economists are overly optimistic about the U.S. economy, as they have been in the past….

I will suggest another framework: Financial markets are pricing in a ‘secular stagnation’ scenario that is at odds with Federal Reserve thinking…. Suppose that the short term equilibrium real rate has fallen to zero…. Change the estimate of NAIRU from 5.6% to 5%… close to pre-recession Fed estimates. The results… [are] fairly close to market expectations…. It thus appears reasonable to argue that financial market participants are pricing in a secular stagnation story combined with a pre-recession level of NAIRU. In contrast, the Fed is not seriously contemplating such a story…. The biggest risk to the expansion is a dogmatic view… on the part of the Federal Reserve…. Financial market participants are saying the Fed has less room to maneuver than monetary policymakers believe. The Fed, I fear, is not taking sufficient heed of those signals. Would it be outrageous to think that the Federal Reserve could find itself backtracking after just 200bp of rate hikes? Not if Sweden serves as any example…. The Fed… risk[s] tightening too aggressively and turning an expansion that should last at least four more years into one with only two left.

Big data and price discrimination

Many reasonable concerns about the rise of Big Data—the collection of very large amounts of data generated by digital activity—seem to be coming to a head due to worries about privacy as more and more information is collected on individuals. One particular concern is that businesses may use collected data to charge different prices to different individuals depending on the information businesses have access to. But could potential price discrimination fueled by big data be more benign? A recent analysis by the President’s Council of Economic Advisers looks into that very question.

Despite the connotation of the word discrimination, price discrimination is not necessarily a bad thing. Consider movie tickets. Movie theatres often charge differential prices to different groups for showings. Customers over 65 get senior discounts, for example, because theatres are using age as a proxy for sensitivity to prices as retirees often have a tighter budget than working people. By giving the elderly a discount, the theatres get more business and increase their profits by getting customers you might not have attended at the regular price. And those customers gain because they go to a movie that they wouldn’t be able to attend at the higher price.

This type of price discrimination is what economists call third-degree price discrimination, the kind where prices are based on demographics groups. Other examples include when e-commerce companies or travel reservation websites adjust their prices according to users’ computers or phones. Second-degree discrimination is when the price of a product goes down the more of it a consumer purchases, which happens all the time in a market economy.

But big data may give rise to the kind of price discrimination known as first-degree discrimination. In these cases, businesses can tailor prices to ensure each customer pays the highest price she is willing to pay for the product. The Council of Economic Advisers report uses the example of cars as a consumer good where prices are individualized. Anyone who’s bought a car at a new or used car dealership knows the sticker price is just a starting point and one-on-one haggling is expected. The use of this kind of discrimination when businesses have access to data on customers, such as their individual earnings profile and credit history, is fairly clear.

But here’s perhaps more telling example: If book sellers know that a potential customer has been sharing articles on a certain topic on social media they might be able to charge a higher price for a related book. The book seller gets a higher profit off the sale, but the customer might be left a lower consumer surplus as they were charged a higher price than a market targeted at the whole population might bare.

After talking to researchers and others using big data The Council of Economic Advisers report says the use of first-degree price discrimination doesn’t seem to have caught on. Internet companies appear to have held off on personalizing prices for now. But the report does note that companies do seem to be using tests on websites to figure out the demand curves for different goods. While not exactly price discrimination, this process does provide companies with information on what prices the market can bare.

So big-data-fueled price discrimination of the first degree doesn’t look like a reality in the present. But we are just at the beginning of the use of these kinds of large data sets for business use. In the meantime, as the authors suggest, policy may be better focused on enforcing existing regulations concerning privacy, consumer protection, and discrimination. Given the speed of technology, policy makers should keep an eye on this area.

Things to Read on the Afternoon of February 9, 2015

Must- and Shall-Reads:

 

  1. Mark Thoma sends us to: Lawrence Summers: Only Raise Rates when Whites of Inflation’s Eyes are Visible: “I cannot recall a moment when the gap between what markets expect the US Federal Reserve to do and what the Fed itself has forecast it will do has been as large. Markets predict that the Fed will raise rates only to 1.6 per cent by the end of 2017; the Federal Open Market Committee’s average forecast is 3.5 per cent. Such a divergence raises the risk of volatility and poses a communications challenge for the Fed. More important, it raises the question of what should guide future policy…. Available inflation data suggests little cause for concern. The core consumer price index has averaged 1.1 per cent over the past six months; if housing costs were stripped out it would be zero. Wages actually fell in December and over the past year employment costs have risen 2.25 per cent…. In such circumstances efforts to reduce demand and growth require a compelling justification. Yet the idea that below normal unemployment will necessarily lead to accelerating inflation as suggested by the so called Phillips curve is very uncertain…. [Moreover,] if inflation were to accelerate a bit this would be a good thing…. A plane that accelerates too rapidly as it takes off may cause passengers discomfort while a plane that accelerates too slowly may crash…. The US has never been more intertwined with the global economy…”

  2. Ezra Klein and Matthew Yglesias: Interview Barack Obama: Teaser: “Ezra Klein: How had we gotten to the point where we can have high corporate profits and businesses can be doing so well, but the workers don’t necessarily share in that prosperity? Barack Obama: Well, this has been at least a three decade-long trend. There are a whole bunch of reasons for that. Some of it has to do with technology and entire sectors being eliminated–travel agents, bank tellers, a lot of middle management. A lot of it has to do with globalization–the rest of the world catching up. Post-World War II we had just some enormous structural advantages because our competitors had been devastated by war and we had made investments that put us ahead of the curve–education and infrastructure. Those advantages went away at the same time that workers had increasingly less leverage because of changes in labor laws. You combine all that stuff and it puts workers in a tougher position. So some people who just control enormous amounts of wealth–we don’t resent their success, but, just as a practical matter, we’re going to have problems making sure that we are investing enough in the common good to move forward.

  3. Sam Gerstenzang: Knowledge Units: “There are two models of online education: Preparatory knowledge, in the form of course-based video-delivered teachings: Coursera, Udacity, Thinkful, etc. On demand knowledge: Wikipedia, StackOverflow, Genius, etc. Of the two, the latter has been much more widely spread and far more influential… pull based… in digestible chunks… Wikipedia and StackOverflow are the knowledge you need, now…. Khan Academy fits somewhere in between… original[ly]… each video solved the problem at hand…. The platforms that lean towards smaller on demand units of knowledge are the ones that are created collaboratively…. There is, of course, something fundamentally missing when we only have on demand knowledge…. We do not want engineers whose only mode problem solving is searching StackOverflow instead of working from their own understanding of the data structures. This is the difference between an education… and… the solution…. A really great model would be one that combined small on-demand knowledge units with a laddered system. Khan Academy is the closest to this that I’ve seen, but I think they have gone too far down the class model…”

  4. Simon Wren-Lewis: The Divine Coincidence: “The Divine Coincidence is the idea that by controlling inflation we also bring the output gap to zero, so we do not need separate targets for both…. Imagine a parallel universe where the monetary authority targeted the output gap, and not inflation…. In this parallel universe they too had a Great Recession, and (being parallel and all) their recovery was of a very similar shape to ours. How would the output gap-targeting monetary authority in this parallel universe perceive its performance? The story would be one of complete failure. After six years of trying, the output gap had still not been closed. A huge amount of resources had been wasted as a result…. I do not think, in our inflation targeting world, the monetary authorities have this view…. They believe performance over the last six years has not been too bad…. Over the last six years, the Divine Coincidence has been distinctly unholy…. I suspect in thirty years students will look back on this period with the same disbelief that we look back on the 1930s. How could they have allowed the recession to continue for so long, they will ask, when they had the tools to do much better? Part of the answer will be inflation targeting.”

Should Be Aware of:

 

  1. Stephanie Mencimer: Meet the Unusual Plaintiffs Behind the Supreme Court Case That Could Destroy Obamacare: “Three of the four plaintiffs are nearly eligible for Medicare, meaning their objections to Obamacare will soon be moot. Two of them appear… not forced to acquire insurance… so it’s unclear how Obamacare had burdened them. These two plaintiffs seemed driven by their political opposition to President Obama; one has called him the ‘anti-Christ’ and said he won election by getting ‘his Muslim people to vote for him.’… One of the plaintiffs did not recall exactly how she’d been recruited for the case and seemed unaware of the possible consequences if she wins. Told that millions could lose their health coverage if the Supreme Court rules in her favor, she said that didn’t want this to happen…”

The connection between shadow banking and secular stagnation

Why are global investors in European bonds snapping up the corporate debt of Switzerland-based Nestlé SA at more than their face value, paying more than they are worth for the privilege of owning the bonds? And what does this have to do with the European Central Bank as well as growing economic inequality?

The easy answer is “it’s complicated,” but the more telling explanation has to do with the so-called shadow banking system. Shadow banking, simply put, includes banking activities (turning savings into loans) done by institutions that aren’t banks. Examples of shadow banks include certain kinds of hedge funds and money market mutual funds.

These shadow banks channel the savings from large pools of money that now slosh around outside of traditional banking. So where are these large pools of savings come from? Research by economist Zoltan Pozsar, a director of global strategy and research at Credit Suisse, sheds light on the more recent macroeconomic forces that have created the global shadow banking system. According to Pozsar, there are two major sources of what he calls “cash pools.”

The first is the large amount of foreign exchange reserves held by developing countries. China, Southeast Asian nations, and oil exporting countries are the primary driver of this increase in these reserves. Think sovereign wealth funds. As Pozsar put it, the source of this cash pool can be thought of as the imbalance in incomes between countries that run trade surpluses, such as China, and trade-deficit countries, such as the United States.

The second major cash pool is corporate cash balances, or the amount of savings held by corporations. The reasons for the increased savings of corporations are myriad. Globalization, according to Pozsar, is one part of the answer as international competition drove down U.S. wages. Another is that many companies can spend less than before, due to cheaper capital goods and the fact that leading companies spend less on equipment overall. Compare General Motors, which has to build factories, to Facebook, which deploys computer code.

Pozsar says this corporate cash pool is the result of the imbalance between income going to capital and labor. We can see this in the United States as the share of income going to labor has declined.

Now back to the European Central Bank and Nestlé bonds. All of these shadow banking players boast keen appetites for safe bonds, such as German government debt, just as the European Central Bank prepares to wade into the bond market buying European government bonds as part of its new quantitative easing program. Matthew Yglesias at Vox takes a deeper look at the resulting shifts in demand and supply of government bonds. And Matt O’Brien argues at The Washington Post that the shadow banking financial system desperately needs safe assets as the supply of government debt declines so investors are moving into corporate debt.

Now if these sources of savings sound familiar, it’s because you’ve heard of them in the context of another recent economic hypothesis. They are the same trends that Harvard University economist Larry Summers highlights as driving his concept of secular stagnation. The very forces that appear to have pushed down interest rates and fostered debt bubbles are the ones that created the shadow banking system. Secular stagnation and shadow banks are two sides of the same coin.

These forces, which are primarily about the distribution of income—between countries, factors of production, individuals and across time—may be at the heart of not only our current macroeconomic situation but the structure of our financial system, too.

Nighttime Must-Read: Lawrence Summers: Only Raise Rates when Whites of Inflation’s Eyes are Visible

Mark Thoma sends us to: Lawrence Summers: Only Raise Rates when Whites of Inflation’s Eyes are Visible

I cannot recall a moment when the gap between what markets expect the US Federal Reserve to do and what the Fed itself has forecast it will do has been as large. Markets predict that the Fed will raise rates only to 1.6 per cent by the end of 2017; the Federal Open Market Committee’s average forecast is 3.5 per cent. Such a divergence raises the risk of volatility and poses a communications challenge for the Fed. More important, it raises the question of what should guide future policy…. Available inflation data suggests little cause for concern. The core consumer price index has averaged 1.1 per cent over the past six months; if housing costs were stripped out it would be zero. Wages actually fell in December and over the past year employment costs have risen 2.25 per cent…. In such circumstances efforts to reduce demand and growth require a compelling justification. Yet the idea that below normal unemployment will necessarily lead to accelerating inflation as suggested by the so called Phillips curve is very uncertain…. [Moreover,] if inflation were to accelerate a bit this would be a good thing…. A plane that accelerates too rapidly as it takes off may cause passengers discomfort while a plane that accelerates too slowly may crash…. The US has never been more intertwined with the global economy…

Evening Must-Watch: Ezra Klein and Matthew Yglesias: Interview with Barack Obama: Teaser

Ezra Klein and Matthew Yglesias: Interview with Barack Obama: Teaser:

Ezra Klein: How had we gotten to the point where we can have high corporate profits and businesses can be doing so well, but the workers don’t necessarily share in that prosperity?

Barack Obama: Well, this has been at least a three decade-long trend. There are a whole bunch of reasons for that. Some of it has to do with technology and entire sectors being eliminated–travel agents, bank tellers, a lot of middle management. A lot of it has to do with globalization–the rest of the world catching up. Post-World War II we had just some enormous structural advantages because our competitors had been devastated by war and we had made investments that put us ahead of the curve–education and infrastructure. Those advantages went away at the same time that workers had increasingly less leverage because of changes in labor laws. You combine all that stuff and it puts workers in a tougher position. So some people who just control enormous amounts of wealth–we don’t resent their success, but, just as a practical matter, we’re going to have problems making sure that we are investing enough in the common good to move forward.

Ezra Klein: Has this put us in a place long-term where redistribution becomes in a sense a positive in and of itself?

Barack Obama: I don’t think that is entirely new. Relative to our post-World War II history taxes now are not particularly high or particularly progressive compared to what they were in say the late 1950s or 1960s. There has always been this notion that for a country to thrive there are some things that, as Lincoln said, we do better together than we can do for ourselves, whether that is building roads or setting up effective power grids or making sure that we have got high-quality public education or that teachers are paid enough. The market will not cover those things, and we have to do them together. Basic research falls in that category. That has always been true. Part of what has changed is that a lot of that burden for making sure that the pie was properly shared took place before government even got involved. If you had stronger unions than you had higher wages. If you had a corporate culture that felt a sense of place and commitment, so that the CEO felt a real affinity for the community to reinvest in that community and to be seen as a corporate citizen. Today what we have is quarterly earning reports, compensation levels for CEOs that are tied directly to those quarterly earnings, you have international capital that is demanding short-term profits, and so what happens is that a lot of the distributional questions that used to be handled in the marketplace through decent wages or health care or defined-benefit pension plans–those all are eliminated, and the average employee–the average worker–doesn’t feel any benefit…

Afternoon Must-Read: Sam Gerstenzang: Knowledge Units

Sam Gerstenzang: Knowledge Units: “There are two models of online education…

…Preparatory knowledge, in the form of course-based video-delivered teachings: Coursera, Udacity, Thinkful, etc. On demand knowledge: Wikipedia, StackOverflow, Genius, etc. Of the two, the latter has been much more widely spread and far more influential… pull based… in digestible chunks… Wikipedia and StackOverflow are the knowledge you need, now…. Khan Academy fits somewhere in between… original[ly]… each video solved the problem at hand…. The platforms that lean towards smaller on demand units of knowledge are the ones that are created collaboratively…. There is, of course, something fundamentally missing when we only have on demand knowledge…. We do not want engineers whose only mode problem solving is searching StackOverflow instead of working from their own understanding of the data structures. This is the difference between an education… and… the solution…. A really great model would be one that combined small on-demand knowledge units with a laddered system. Khan Academy is the closest to this that I’ve seen, but I think they have gone too far down the class model…

Afternoon Must-Read: Simon Wren-Lewis: The Divine Coincidence

Simon Wren-Lewis: The Divine Coincidence: “The Divine Coincidence is the idea that by controlling inflation…

…we also bring the output gap to zero, so we do not need separate targets for both…. Imagine a parallel universe where the monetary authority targeted the output gap, and not inflation…. In this parallel universe they too had a Great Recession, and (being parallel and all) their recovery was of a very similar shape to ours. How would the output gap-targeting monetary authority in this parallel universe perceive its performance? The story would be one of complete failure. After six years of trying, the output gap had still not been closed. A huge amount of resources had been wasted as a result…. I do not think, in our inflation targeting world, the monetary authorities have this view…. They believe performance over the last six years has not been too bad…. Over the last six years, the Divine Coincidence has been distinctly unholy…. I suspect in thirty years students will look back on this period with the same disbelief that we look back on the 1930s. How could they have allowed the recession to continue for so long, they will ask, when they had the tools to do much better? Part of the answer will be inflation targeting.