The Debate Over the TPP

From last week:

And now:

So I guess I should write something else in addition to this.

Here it is: A rant on the TPP debate revoked by a Twitter exchange.

As one of the people who did the NAFTA economic impact estimates for the Clinton Administration. I definitely have some explaining to do.

Our models showed NAFTA as:

  • a small plus for the American manufacturing sector, including manufacturing workers;
  • a larger but still small plus for American consumers;
  • a substantial plus for Mexico; and
  • a minus for other developing countries that were potential competitors with Mexico for the American market.

In reality, it turned out to be:

  • a substantial short-run minus for Mexico (the 1994–95 financial crisis;
  • a long-run plus for Mexico that I still hope Will be larger than the short-run minus (guaranteed tariff- and quota-free access to the US market is worth a good deal);
  • a bigger plus then I expected for Wall Street;
  • a plus for American consumers;
  • a small minus for American manufacturing; and
  • a minus for other developing countries that were potential competitors with Mexico for the American market.

It turned out that the most important aspect of NAFTA was not the increase in balanced trade from lower trade barriers, and was not the increase in factory construction in Mexico because of increased confidence in Mexico’s government and in US willingness to except Mexican exports and in US manufactured equipment exports to enable that construction.

It turned out that the most important aspect of NAFTA was the Mexican financial liberalization that allowed Mexico’s rich to cheaply purchased political risk insurance from Wall Street by getting their money into New York.

That experience–my personal analytical nadir as an economist, I might add–convinced me that analyzing modern trade agreements as if they were primarily Ricardian deals is likely to lead one substantially astray. One has to think, and think deeply, creatively, and subtly, about all the potential general equilibrium effects. One has to work hard to bound their magnitude.

Thus arguments saying that a Ricardian analysis tells us that the Trans-Pacific Partnership is a good thing tend to undermine my confidence in it. Those making such arguments seem to me either to have not done their homework, or to not particularly care whether the arguments they set forth for it are actually the true arguments for it.

I am ready to believe that dispute settlement is not a threat to American governance. I am ready to believe that regulatory harmonization will be at the top rather than a race to the bottom. I am ready to believe that increase in intellectual-property protection will actually be the benefit of the world–and if not of the world for the United States. I am perhaps willing to believe that America’s obligation to be a benevolent hegemon should not control.

But each time the Ricardian argument is made a chance to make the real arguments is lost. And my confidence that the real arguments are strong ones becomes weaker…

Thus much more effective than yet-another-Ricardian-argument is something like this from Gary Hufbauer:

Gary Hufbauer: Senator Warren Distorts the Record on Investor-State Dispute Settlements: “ISDS provisions enable a foreign investor to seek compensation in an amount determined by an impartial panel of arbitrators…

…if a host government expropriates its property, or regulates its business in an arbitrary or discriminatory manner. Such protections have been deemed necessary in agreements going back at least to a Germany-Pakistan accord in 1959…. Starting with the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) in 1994, the United States has also included ISDS in the investment chapters in nearly all its free trade agreements (FTAs), now numbering 20. Given this rich history, Senator Warren should be able to cite actual examples of the multiple abuses that she claims have occurred. She has not done so, because she cannot. Senator Warren makes a big deal about the hypothetical outcome of the old Methanex case against California’s regulations on gasoline additives, but the case was decided against the Canadian corporation….

Over the decades, only 13 ISDS cases have been brought to judgment against the United States.  The United States has not lost a single case. Why? Because the United States does not expropriate private property without compensation, and the United States does not enact arbitrary or discriminatory laws against foreign firms. Contrary to what the Senator implies, American taxpayers have not had to cough up millions and even billions of dollars in damages. They have not had to cough up anything. To be blunt, Senator Warren has no facts…. Her op-ed… resorted to hypothetical scenarios that had no basis in 50 years of ISDS history….

Senator Warren… warns that plaintiffs may succeed in suing such countries as Egypt, Germany, and the Czech Republic to overturn their laws. But these are hypothetical scenarios. The cases have not been decided and the countries in question may well prevail. Her descriptions of these lawsuits overlook something that Senator Warren should know as a former law professor: Lawyers often bring cases seeking huge damages precisely when the facts are against their claims. Just look at the 13 ISDS cases brought against the United States and dismissed, or the 175 cases dismissed worldwide. Sounding like a Tea Party politician railing against the United Nations, Senator Warren contends that international courts might replace the US legal system. Again she has the story backwards. The United States has been the chief architect of ISDS and other forms of international dispute settlement precisely because the United States has been able to export its legal principles to other countries….

Since NAFTA was ratified two decades ago, ISDS provisions have been amended to ward off frivolous claims involving environmental, health, and safety regulation of corporate practices. We do not yet know the precise terms of the ISDS provisions in TPP. A good guess is that they will follow the template found in the Korea-US FTA. That template might be further improved by requiring briefs to be published at a suitable time and establishing an appeals mechanism. But just because the existing ISDS template falls short of perfection is no reason to jettison the concept. It is even less of a reason to reject the entire TPP, though that seems to be Senator Warren’s objective.

But I can find nothing analogous and useful on the intellectual-property side…


Greg Ip:

Greg Ip: Obama’s Uphill Push for Free Trade – WSJ: “As American consumers gorged on a flood of cheap Chinese imports…

…American workers took a beating. A study by Gordon Hanson of the University of California at San Diego and four others think the surge cost the U.S. 2 million to 2.4 million manufacturing jobs between 1999 and 2011…. It wasn’t just the WTO at work; because China kept its currency artificially low, it limited the growth of U.S. exports to China, and the American trade deficit ballooned. “It’s entirely understandable that people have a hangover from the recent trade experience of the last two decades,” Mr. Hanson says. “But TPP isn’t about manufacturing. Globalization in that sector is a fait accompli.” The future of trade liberalization, he says, is in agriculture and services where the U.S. advantage is strongest….

Negotiators say it will lay down rules for the rest of the world in sectors such as services and intellectual property where nontariff barriers are especially onerous. This should benefit the U.S. insofar as services are a growing part of U.S. exports…. It would seek to curb new forms of hidden protection such as subsidies provided via state-owned enterprises…. If TPP lives up to its hype, it should demand far less adjustment from the U.S. than it does of other signatories that are expected to meet U.S. standards for how foreign investment, intellectual property, imports and subsidies should be treated…

Over at Grasping Reality: Hoisted from the Archives: “The Uses of the University” Alma Mater Blogging

Over at Grasping Reality: Hoisted from the Archives: “The Uses of the University” Alma Mater Blogging: Let me put it this way: i

In 1960, the University of California–then overwhelmingly UCB and UCSF and UCLA–was about four times the size of Harvard, 5000 vs. 1200 undergraduates a year, with graduate students and faculty roughly in proportion. Clark Kerr, as president of the University of California in the 1960s, took a look at space constraints in Berkeley and Westwood, took a look at the rising population of California, took a look at increasing wealth, took a look at increasing educational attainment, took a look at the increasing attractiveness of American universities to people abroad, and conclude that the number of undergraduate students who could and would want to take full advantage of a UC education was going to grow eightfold over the next fifty years. So he decided to go all-out to clone UCB and UCLA.

And he did it… READ MOAR

Must-Read: Richard Thaler: The Beauty Contest Game

Must-Read: Richard Thaler: http://en.m.wikiversity.org/wiki/Economic_Classroom_Experiments/Guessing_Game: “If you pick zero in the ‘Beauty Contest’ game…

…you are smart enough to solve the game for the Nash equilibrium. And you are dumb enough to think everyone else can solve for the Nash equilibrium. And dumb enough to think everyone else will think everyone else will think everyone else will solve for the Nash equilibrium. Infinite regress–you are a singularity of dumb…

Today’s big U.S. economic trade-off isn’t equality or efficiency

This year marks the 40th anniversary of the publication of the late economist Arthur Okun’s book, “Equality and Efficiency: The Big Trade-Off.” Rereading Okun in 2015, however, feels about as relevant to my work as an economist as does reading Hilary Mantel’s “Wolf Hall,” about 16th century Britain. Both are interesting and enjoyable swings through the historical past–and I highly recommend them–but neither should be used as a roadmap for today’s policymakers.

Okun’s purpose in 1975 was to give political leaders guidelines for how to think about economic policy based on his understanding gleaned over the previous 40 or so years. In his view, policymakers face a trade-off between addressing economic inequality and promoting economic efficiency, which is to say, addressing inequality threatens the foundation for a competitive economy. He uses the idiom “we can’t have our cake and eat it too” to frame his fundamental concern, saying, “We can’t have our cake of market efficiency and share it equally.”

This question led him to steer social scientists toward a narrow focus on the whether and how of the “big trade-off.” He ends his book with this plea: “I do, however, hope to persuade others to share my views about the preconditions for optimization—a more focused public dialogue on the intensities of preferences for equality and a greater research effort by social scientists on the measurement of the leakages. In short, I am pleading for us all to face up to the tradeoff between equality and efficiency.”

Today’s policymakers might pick up Okun’s book as a roadmap for coping with today’s rising inequality. After all, his concern was when and how policymakers should tax the rich to give to the poor. As Okun put it then: “Because the bottom end of the income scale is at the top of my priority list, I shall concentrate largely on the tax-transfer options.” I would argue that this is not today’s question. Focusing on technocratic solutions for helping those at the bottom of the income ladder diverts our attention from what’s really going on in our economy and society today.

“The Big Trade-Off” examines a United States where “the relative distribution of family income has changed very little in the past generation,” and where Okun could argue that the most pressing question was how much equality was enough. Problem is, in the 40 years since Okun’s book was published, the gains of U.S. economic growth have not been shared as widely as they were in the post-war era that Okun examined. While our economy has grown and productivity has improved—that is, American workers produce more goods and services per hour worked—wages and incomes have failed to keep pace. The middle class has seen little growth and the bottom has seen no growth, while incomes at the top have exploded.

According to data from economists Emmanuel Saez at the University of California-Berkeley and Thomas Piketty at the Paris School of Economics, between 1976 and 2007 the bottom 90 percent saw their income grow by an annual rate of ¼ of 1 percent, adjusted for inflation, while the top 1 percent saw theirs grow by 4.4 percent. Put another way—and pulling forward to the most recent year of data—from 1975 to 2013, the top 10 percent of households have accrued 109 percent of all the income gained.

This wasn’t Okun’s economy. Between 1933 and 1975, the top 10 percent took home only 29 percent of the income gains. Certainly, that’s more than their equal share, but the bottom 90 percent did get 70 percent of the growth and saw their incomes rise at a pace of 3.9 percent per year.[i] Okun pondered a trade-off between equality and efficiency just when those at the top of the wealth and income ladder began hauling off all the gains of economic growth.

Our political discourse today is also strikingly different than in Okun’s time. In the era he lived in, there was broad agreement about the role of policy. It’s a world unrecognizable to those of us steeped in the severe partisanship of the Bush and Obama years. Okun could blithely write, “I do not know anyone today who would disagree, in principle, that every person, regardless of merit or ability to pay, should receive medical care and food in the face of serious illness or malnutrition” That is not America today, where lawmakers in Congress and in statehouses around the country push to cut spending on the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program and seek to limit the availability of Medicaid made available recently under the Affordable Care Act.

Okun was—as we all are—a product of his time. Specific economic and political realities led him to conclusions that are inapplicable to today’s economy. He argues that our society accepts more inequality in economic assets than sociopolitical assets. He boldly begins his book by saying, “American society proclaims the worth of every human being. All citizens are guaranteed equal justice and equal political rights.” That’s an audacious statement to make 40 years ago and remains so today.

I live on U Street, in Washington, DC, and over the past week protestors have marched through my neighborhood loudly proclaiming, “All lives matter. Black lives matter.” They are marching because citizen-documentarians across the nation have shown the sad truth of police brutality. To point to just one statistic: The unemployment rate for African Americans has held steady at twice the rate of whites for decades. This was true in 1975 and it’s true today.

It’s hard to reconcile today’s political reality with Okun’s bold beginning in “The Big Tradeoff.” Fundamentally, it comes down to whether the lack of economic inclusion for African Americans directly affects their political and social power. If we cannot separate economic and political rights as neatly as Okun does, there’s no other conclusion than that today’s policymakers should be wary—very wary—of taking this book as a roadmap.

Okun’s analysis leads him to dismiss the notion that those at the top can buy political and social power. In his view, we don’t need to worry about the power of those with money because the state has ample strictures in place to keep the “Howard Hughes’s”—who in his day was one of the richest men in the world—from controlling the political process. Of course, he was writing immediately after Watergate and a sense of optimism that campaign finance reform would be effective clearly shaped his thinking. He concluded that such regulation was far better than tax policy for curbing the power of the rich: “If the uses of fat checkbook in the political process can be tightly regulated, the plutocracy will lose much of its political punch.”

We cannot be so sanguine today. Thomas Piketty’s book “Capital in the 21st Century” soared to the top of the best-seller list no doubt because we are a nation looking for answers to what’s happened to our economy and our political system. U.S. economists haven’t been asking those questions or providing those answers in no small part to Okun’s dismissal of the notion that we need to focus on incomes (and power) at the top.

Indeed, Okun missed what would become the biggest question of our times. When Okun was writing, the typical CEO earned about 25 times the typical worker. How could he know that today, they earn nearly 300 times the typical worker? [ii] Given the era he lived in—long before the Supreme Court’s 2010 ruling in Citizens United v. Federal Election Commission that enabled unlimited campaign contributions by multimillionaires and billionaires—perhaps his conclusion was reasonable. Yet Okun’s thinking still dominates economic and political discourse. While policymakers argue whether government aid for the less fortunate in our society is more or less efficient for our economy, the big economic trend of the long-term of a growing gap in productivity and wages and the top income earners pulling further and further away from the rest are not thoroughly examined for their consequences on future U.S. economic growth. It’s taken the work of Piketty—and his many co-authors—to focus us on these larger questions. Piketty’s conclusion is that we need to take swift action, but so long as we remain trapped in Okun’s trade-off, we’re not having the right conversation.

Because Okun began from a premise that assumed that his status-quo economy would continue for the foreseeable future, he focused us on the wrong questions. He asked us to focus on society’s preferences for equality, rather than society’s preferences for a strong middle class. He asked researchers to focus on measuring the “leaky budget”—his term for what is lost to an economy when government tries to ease economic inequality—a technocratic focus that has not served us well. He dismissed the big questions and left us with technocratic debates over how much we should give the poor, rather than how strong and vital our middle class should be.

But, my critique goes deeper. It’s hard not to see Okun’s legacy as the problem rather than the solution. His view that we needn’t focus our energies thinking about the effects of rising top incomes and that the real problem was ensuring that we didn’t veer too far into ensuring equality steered us in the wrong direction. Had we not listened, would we be here today.

[i] Data are computations from the updated Excel files provided by Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez, based on this research: Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez, “Income Inequality in the United States, 1913–1998,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, no. 1 (February 2003): 1–39.

[ii] “CEO Pay Continues to Rise as Typical Workers Are Paid Less,” Economic Policy Institute, accessed May 3, 2015, http://www.epi.org/publication/ceo-pay-continues-to-rise/.

Must-Read: Martin Wolf: The British economy after the coalition

Must-Read: Martin Wolf thinks, rightly, that the Tory-LD coalition should face an accountability moment for making its huge bet on austerity, and thus getting economic policy wrong. But, unfortunately, it seems that they are not: if the Tory-LD coalition loses, it will be for other reasons.

This is very bad news for the long-run rationality of economic policy in the North Atlantic.

Martin Wolf:

Martin Wolf: The British economy after the coalition: “Why should one be desperate to avoid a free loan?…

…Growth-promoting borrowing is needed** In what condition does the coalition government leave the UK economy?… In the last quarter of 2014, UK real gross domestic product per head was 4.8 per cent higher than it had been in the second quarter of 2010…. But it was much the same as in the first quarter of 2007… below its pre-crisis peak… [and] close to 16 per cent below where it would have been if the 1955-2007 trend had continued. Moreover, this huge shortfall cannot be explained by a pre-crisis boom. On the contrary, the economy was close to its long-term trend in 2007…. In the short run, stagnant productivity [has] allowed the economy to combine weak expansion of overall output with decent jobs performance. In the long run, however, productivity determines standards of living….

The necessary ingredient is buoyant demand…. The coalition’s fiscal bite was less bad than its bark. The argument [the coalition] offered for tightening faster than Labour had promised was that it was necessary to stop the UK from being… Greece…. This was wildly exaggerated…. Despite failing to hit its fiscal targets, interest rates on UK public debt have remained astonishingly low: 30-year and 50-year gilts yield 2.4 per cent, while yields on comparable index-linked gilts are close to minus 1 per cent. Why should one be desperate to avoid a free loan? What is needed instead is growth-promoting borrowing…

Must-Read: Josh Brown: Funds Aren’t Cutting Fees, Investors Are

Must-Read: Josh Brown: Funds Aren’t Cutting Fees, Investors Are: “There is absolutely zero data that links high fund costs with outperformance…

… Investors are leaving higher cost funds and gravitating toward lower cost funds. I would surmise that the education they are getting on financial blogs and from their advisors is helping to drive this trend.

A new Morningstar study released today shows that the asset-weighted expense ratio across all funds (including mutual funds and exchange-traded products, or ETPs, but excluding money market funds and funds of funds) was 0.64% in 2014, down from 0.65% in 2013 and 0.76% five years ago. The trend is being driven more by investors seeking low-cost funds than it is by fund companies cutting fees.

The data is undeniable: the investor class is learning…. There are many more clients now being served by fee-based financial advisors than pure transactional brokers…. With less brokers, there is the commensurate decline in the type of funds brokers favor (the ones that pay them most). Broker-sold or “load” funds are going the way of the dodo…

I am much less optimistic than Josh Brown is. We have a long, long way to go before we have a financial system in which investment-managing intermediaries are truly paid proper fees for performance. If a century and a half of modern financial markets is not enough to teach people that buy-and-hold, continuous commitment, diversification, and rebalancing are the keys, what length of time would be long enough?

The importance of addressing the U.S. racial and ethnic wealth gap

Last week, economists, advocates, and organizers from across the country joined each other at the Center for Global Policy Solutions’ Color of Wealth Summit to examine wealth inequality and economic growth in the United States through a racial lens. A recent essay by Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis economists’ Ray Boshara, William Emmons, and Bryan Noeth does an excellent job of illustrating the problem.

The essay shows that minorities—African Americans and Hispanics in particular—tend to hold their wealth in illiquid assets (or those assets that can’t be turned quickly into cash and have lower asset diversification) compared to whites and Asians. They also find that African Americans and Hispanics were more likely to have high levels of debt relative to Asians and Whites. Their findings, while not entirely surprising, are incredibly important for future U.S. economic stability and growth.

These disparities could stem from a number of causes, including disparate access to financial services, low wages for African American and Hispanic workers, and the relative lack of intergenerational wealth transfers. But the implications for individual African American and Hispanic families, as well as for U.S. economic growth and stability more broadly, cannot be overstated.

For these individual households, lower asset diversification means they are less able to smooth their consumption during economic shocks that affect their primary investment—their housing. Writ large, what happens when a large number of American families can suddenly no longer afford to spend their incomes on the goods and services that keep our economy running?  According to economists Atif Mian at Princeton University and Amir Sufi, at the University of Chicago, these kinds of disparities in wealth and debt accumulation, especially prevalent among communities of color, led to the Great Recession of 2007-2009.

In their 2014 book “House of Debt,” Mian and Sufi show that counties with the largest decline in total net worth due to falling housing prices cut back most on spending. Those were the households that probably did not hold other assets that could quickly be turned into cash. Essentially, their research shows that families who hold more debt are less likely to spend money to help sustain or grow the economy.

Prince George’s County in Maryland is an all too real example of the economic consequences of plummeting housing prices that have failed to rebound. The predominantly black suburban county near Washington, D.C. is recovering from the housing crisis more slowly than nearby mostly white communities.

By 2044, however, more than half of the U.S. population is expected to belong to a minority group. Policymakers would do well to consider the effects on the U.S. economy if large swaths of U.S. families are constrained by limited diversification and high levels of debt.  Efforts to end still pervasive racial and ethnic discrimination in pay and hiring, increase access to quality financial tools, and forgive high levels of debt amid sharp economic downturns may be critical to future economic growth. ​

The Great Depression and the Great Recession in the North Atlantic

The Great Depression and the Great Recession in the North Atlantic

2015 McKenna Lecture :: Claremont-McKenna College

Back in 1959 Arthur Burns, lifelong senior Republican policymaker, Chair of the Council of Economic Advisers under President Eisenhower, good friend of and White House Counselor to President Nixon, and Chair of the Federal Reserve from 1970 to 1978 gave the presidential address to the American Economic Association. In it, he concluded that the United States and a lot of choices to make as far as its future economic institutions and economic policies were concerned. And, he said:

These… choices will have to be made by the people of the United States; and economists–far more than any other group–will in the end help to make them…

That’s you. “Economists”, that is. And I am glad to be here, because I am glad that you are joining us. For we–all of us in America–need you. Arthur Burns was right: you are better-positioned than any other group to help us make the right choices, at the level of the world and of the country as a whole, but also at the level of the state, the city, the business, the school district, the NGO seeking to figure out how to spend its limited resources–whatever.

So why did Arthur Burns say this? And why was he right? Two blocks away over at Harvey Mudd college, people will say that they understand technologies–and that you, we, like Jon Snow of “Game of Thrones” (who I strongly believe is really Jon Targaryen-Stark, but let that pass), know nothing.

I would say:

  • While the engineering principles they know over at Harvey Mudd will endure, the knowledge of actual technologies they have will be largely obsolete in one decade and completely obsolete in two.
  • Economists know about systems, and how systems work:
    • Supply and demand
    • Opportunity cost
    • General equilibrium
    • Incentives and behavior
  • Get how the system works wrong, and your technological knowledge points in the wrong direction–is worse than useless.
  • Get how the system works right, and there will be many opportunities to figure out how to use and apply the technologies–not least because people will learn that they can make money by offering to teach you.

But while your heads should swell, I don’t want your heads to swell too much. So let me tell you a story of today–and of how economists as a group, definitely including me, got it very wrong.

Let us return to Arthur Burns and his presidential address. In it, his first and his main point was that a business-cycle episode like the one we have just been through was not a realistic possibility. I quote, at extended length:

More than twenty-five years have elapsed since we last experienced a financial panic or a deep depression of production and employment. Over twenty years have elapsed since we last had a severe business recession…. There is no parallel for such a sequence of mild… [cycles] at least during the past hundred years…. The character of the business cycle itself appears to have changed….

The evolution of corporate practice, as well as the growth of corporate enterprise itself, has served to reduce the influence of a cyclical decline… on the flow of income…. The expansion and the means of financing of governmental enterprise… have had a similar effect…. In the classical business cycle… once business investment began declining… a reduction of consumer spending soon followed….

The specific measures adopted by the government in dealing with the recessions of the postwar period have varied…. In all of them, monetary, fiscal, and housekeeping policies played some part… [with] the most nearly consistent part of contracyclical policy… in the monetary sphere… influence… exerted only in part through lower interest rates. Of greater consequence… credit becomes more readily available… the money supply is increased… [and] the liquidity of financial assets is improved….

The net result has been that the intensity of cyclical swings of production has become smaller…. It seems reasonable to expect that the structural changes… which have served to moderate and humanize the business cycle will continue to do so…. Of late, many economists have been speaking… persuasively,though not always as grimly, of a future of secular inflation. The warning is timely…

That is the end of the quote.

Between 1959 and 2007–for nearly half a century–the overwhelming majority of economists would have endorsed Arthur Burns’s conclusions. In fact, things got better from the perspective of unemployment. After two moderate recessions in the middle and just after the end of the 1970s, the size of the business cycle in employment and production shrunk again, giving rise to what was called the “Great Moderation”. Arthur Burns’s warning that the big economic threat had become inflation was nearly a decade too soon to be properly timely, but it was correct. And as of 2007 the overwhelming bulk of economists were still keeping their weather eye on inflationary problems of too-much money chasing too-few goods: exchange-rate depreciation provoked by shifts in desired capital flows, legislatures that could not muster the nerve either to cut programs and benefits to what could be properly-funded by taxes or raise taxes to what was needed to properly-fund programs and benefits, or simply central banks that fell victim to growth optimism and so failed to properly raise interest rates in a boom.

Thus what happened after 2007 in the North Atlantic came to nearly all economists as an astonishing surprise. Economists like Nouriel Roubini, my co-author Paul Krugman, and me would have said “we told you so” if a drying-up of the flow of finance from China led to a crash of investment spending in the U.S., a steep fall in the dollar, the bankruptcy of underregulated large New York banks that had bet their futures on a stable dollar, and an outbreak of inflation that caused a painful stagflation episode of high unemployment, high interest rates, and a rise in inflation that left the government with only painful policy options. Economists like my teacher Marty Feldstein and Michael Boskin would have said “we told you so” if failures to either raise taxes or enact entitlement reform had given the Federal Reserve an unpleasant choice between raising interest rates to prevent inflation and accepting higher unemployment or lowering interest rates to preserve employent at the price of higher inflation. Only a very few–like my co-author Dean Baker–saw the housing sector as a potential source of serious danger. And what has happened since 2007 has been an order of magnitude worse than even Dean envisioned in his worst nightmares.

Even today, 8% of the wealth that back in 2007 we confidently expected the North Atlantic to have has simply vanished. Our workers have fewer jobs, and are less productive. Our businesses have idle capacity. Productive links in the global division of labor that would in the normal course of events have been made since 2007 have not been. Productive links in the global division of labor that existed back in 2007 have been broken. This year I can still say that those of you graduating who are male still face the worst job market for newly-minted male college graduates in American history–albeit slightly better than 2012-2014, and somewhat better than 2009-2011, but worse than in any other year or years.

The total properly-discounted losses from the Great Depression cumulated to 1.4 times the initial year’s GDP in the United States and half that in Western Europe–and perhaps that total is a mammoth underestimate, if one believes that in the absence of the Great Depression Europe’s downfall into Naziism and World War II would have been avoided. 40 million people were killed or left to starve during World War II in Europe–six million of them Jews. 10 million people were killed or left to starve during World War II in Asia–seven million of them Chinese. Restrict ourselves to the narrower totals, however. Assume that in the absence of the financial crisis of 2007-8 and what followed production in the entire North Atlantic would have followed its pre-2007 trend. Then sometime next year the total losses from the current unpleasantness in Europe will pass the Great Depression as a share of GDP. And if we stay on our current trajectory in the United States rather than finding some way to restore pre-2007 trends of growth, come 2026 the Great Depression will no longer be America’s greatest depression.

Diagnoses of how we got into this mess and why we are still mired in it–albeit to a substantially less degree than in 2009, and to a much less degree than in 2009 we feared we would be in 2010–vary. Let me give you my take–which is disputable, and indeed often disputed. I follow my next-door office neighbor at Berkeley, Barry Eichengreen, and find that one of the many important factors that has led to our current situation was the intellectual success of a book: Milton Friedman and Anna Jacobsen Schwartz’s A Monetary History of the United States. You can read Barry’s version of the argument in his excellent and brand-new book, Hall of Mirrors. Here is mine:

In the 1960s and 1970s monetarist economists drawing their analysis from Friedman and Schwartz’s Monetary History of the United States advanced their particular economic-historical interpretation of the causes of the 1930s Great Depression as due to an improper and not-neutral–a contractionary–monetary policy. They were opposed by others. Some others, call them Keynesians, focused on fluctuations in the irrational “animal spirits” of businesses and thus of business willingness to engage in investment spending, on the limited power of monetary policy to counter coordinated shifts in psychology, and thus saw the Great Depression as originating in an unstable private sector and an unwillingness or inability of the government to directly direct and command the flow of spending through the economy. Still other others–call them Minskyites, but they were always a small sect–saw the private-sector instability as a financial-sector instability driven by a failure to properly regulate, control, and limit credit: as my Minskyite friend Bill Janeway of Warburg-incus says: give the banking system too much unregulated credit and you know what they will eventually do–you just do not know against which wall they will do it.

The Great Depression, Friedman and his co-author Anna Jacobson Schwartz had argued, was at its root a failure of government. It was due solely and completely to the failure of the 1929-1933 Federal Reserve to properly and aggressively expand the monetary base in order to keep the economy’s money stock stable. Seeing the money stock stable is a neutral monetary policy. And no decline in the money stock, no Great Depression. It was the government’s failure to follow a “neutral” monetary policy–the active disturbance by government incompetence of what was by nature a stable full-employment market economy–that was the only reason the 1930s downturn became the Great Depression.

This interpretation was coherent sense. However, it rested on a particular premise: that the so-called velocity of money, the speed with which people spent the cash in their pockets and the demand deposits in their banking accounts, would vary little with changes in interest rates. And this interpretation involved some fast talk and fast dancing as to what a “neutral” monetary policy was. What Friedman and Schwartz called a “neutral” monetary policy in the Great Depression would have required that the Federal Reserve flood the zone with liquidity and buy bonds and print cash at a rate never before imagined, and that in fact the Federal Reserve in the Great Depression did not imagine.

But would a “neutral” monetary policy be enough? Suppose the velocity of money was interest-elastic. Then the open-market operations undertaken to expand the money supply would have pushed down interest rates. They would so cause a further fall in monetary velocity. And so that would have made Freedman and Schwartz’s cure impotent. And if Keynesian psychological shifts in the animal spirits of businessmen or fears provoked by a Minskyite financial crisis were to push interest rates down far enough and if the elasticity of money demand was high enough, the Great Depression would have come even had the money supply remained stable–even had monetary policy been “neutral” on Friedman and Schwartz’s definition. Then to have successfully stopped the Great Depression in its tracks would have required Keynesian expansionary fiscal and Minskyite supportive credit-market policies.

The monetarists won the economic-historical and macroeconomic debate in the 1960s and 1970s. My teacher Peter Temin’s Did Monetary Forces Cause the Great Depression did point out convincingly that there was no great contractionary surprise in anything the Federal Reserve did–no place where interest rates jumped up as it deviated from what people were expecting–and at most minor and irregular downward pressure on liquidity. Others picked away at the Friedman-Schwartz thesis on other details. But that didn’t matter.

Why not? I think it did not matter because the debate wa really two debates:

At one level, the debate between monetarists, Keynesians, and Minskyites was a simple empirical matter of reading the evidence: Was the interest-elasticity of money demand in a serious downturn low, as Milton Friedman claimed, or high, as in John Maynard Keynes’s and John Hicks’s liquidity trap? Were financial markets a near-veil because the money stock was a near-sufficient statistic for predicting total spending, as Milton Friedman claimed, or was the credit channel and its functioning of decisive importance, as Minsky warned?

At the second level, however, the debate was over whether market failure or government failure was the bigger threat.

The Great Depression had, before Friedman and Schwartz’s Monetary History, been seen as an unanswerable argument that market failure was potentially so dire as to require the government to take over direction of the whole economy. And that created a presumption that there might be other, smaller market failure might require a government to be interventionist indeed not just in macro but in micro as well. But if the Great Depression could be understood as a failure of government, then the cognitive dissonance between its reality and right-of-center economists’ presumption that government failure was always the bigger threat could be erased.

And of course, the textbook Friedmanite cure was tried á outrance over 2008-2010 and proved insufficient. The monetary policy that Ben Bernanke pursued was Friedman-Schwartz to the max. It cushioned the downturn–the U.S. has done better than western Europe about to the degree that Bernanke was more aggressive in lowering interest rates and buying bonds for cash than his European counterpart Trichet. That is evidence that Friedman and his monetarists were wrong about the Great Depression as well. There are thus few people today who have properly done their homework who would say, as Ben Bernanke said to Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz in 2002:

You’re right, we did it. We’re very sorry. But thanks to you, we won’t do it again.

And right now Ben Bernanke, now at the Brookings Institution, has changed his mind. He is now calling for Keynesian cures–expansionary fiscal policy, especially infrastructure spending, as the bet road forward.

But, even in the 1970s, the empirical evidence did not weigh strongly enough on the monetarist side to account for its decisive victory. The completeness of the victory must, I think be attributed to the fact that economics is never technocratic economics, it is always political economy, which is always politics. And that means, as British economist and moral philosopher John Stuart Mill lamented back in the 1800s, that there is no position so absurd that it has not been advanced by some political economist of note and reputation.

To admit that the monetarist cure was inadequate would be to admit that the Great Depression had deeper roots then a failure of technocratic management on the part of central banks charged with maintaining a neutral monetary policy.

Such deeper roots in severe market failures would not be fully consistent with a belief back in the 1970s and 1980s that social democracy had been oversold, and that government failure was almost invariably a worse danger than market failure. There was thus an extremely strong elective affinity between a mainstream economics profession caught up in the gathering neoliberal currents of the age and the Friedmanite interpretation of the Great Depression.

And because the intellectual victory in the 1970s and 1980s was complete, policymakers in 2008-2010 were hesitant and unwilling to apply the Keynesian and Minskyite cures to severe downturns enthusiastically enough and on a large enough scale to adequately deal with the problems that emerged. When the collapse came, the economists advising the North Atlantic’s governments and central banks were not ready.

Why did the collapse come? Start with the huge rise in wealth among the world’s richest 0.1% and 0.01% from the 1970s into the 200s, and the consequent pressure for people, governments, and companies to take on increasingly unsustainable levels of debt. Continue with policymakers lulled into complacency by the widespread acceptance of the “efficient-market hypothesis”–believing that investors in deregulated financial markets were relatively good judges of risk. CEnd with hubris: the confidence in the Federal Reserve and elsewhere that grew because the Penn Central collapse of 1970, the Latin American financial crisis of 1982, the stock market crash of 1987, the S&L crisis of 1991, the Mexican crisis of 1995, the East Asian crisis of 1997, the Russian/LTCM crisis of 1998, and the dot-com crash of 2000 had not caused the Federal Reserve problems that it could not handle well enough to keep the unemployment rate from going up by more than two percentage points.

Thus in 2008 the North Atlantic had a trend rate of inflation at 2%/year too low to make people feel they had to spend their cash even in a time of great uncertainty. It had a great deal of subprime debt, and an even greater degree of debt that might be subprime–because your supposedly investment-grade counterparty’s ability to pay you depended on its subprime creditors paying it. Add in the peculiar problems of Europe, which is now a single currency but not a single government, a single financial system, or a single people. These were not problems that could be solved by the simple Friedmanite cure.

So when the 2008 financial crisis erupted, and policymakers tried to apply the solutions Friedman had proposed for the Great Depression to the present day, those solutions were not sufficient. It is not that they were counterproductive. The policies were enough to prevent the post-2008 recession from developing into a full-blown depression.

But from our standpoint today, we have reason to fear that partial success may turn out to be Pyrrhic victory. Politicians–Obama, Cameron, Merkel, and others–declare that the crisis had been overcome and the economy is strong. Yet by the standard of the pre-2007 period we have a depressed level and anemic growth, combined with acceptance of these as the new normal. Thus the North Atlantic is on track to have thrown away 10% of their potential wealth. And there have been insufficient changes in financial-sector regulation or in automatic stabilizers or in other institutions to keep the North Atlantic from once again developing the vulnerabilities it turned out to have in 2007.

That is the end of my story.

The little lesson from this story? We should not be satisfied with the current state of the economy. We should be pressing for policies to not just stabilize the situation but reverse the damage, and pick the fruit that back in 2007 we thought we would have today but that is still hanging.

The big lesson from this story? That your ideology, like fire and (we hope) fusion, turns out to be a good servant but a terrible master. Ideologies make sense of the entire world. We need them–our brains cannot handle too much complexity, for we have barely evolved barely enough smarts to have made it this far. But they break in our hands precisely because they force the world to make sense, and make a single kind of sense, and the world may not–or may not make that particular kind of sense.

Thus we can accept the conclusion that decentralized market economies and private property as societal institutions are among our greatest blessings. This is what John Maynard Keynes called “individualism”. And he wrote:

the traditional advantages of individualism will still hold good. Let us stop for a moment to remind ourselves what [its] advantages are…. The advantage to efficiency of the decentralisation of decisions and of individual responsibility is even greater, perhaps, than the nineteenth century supposed…. Individualism… is the best safeguard of personal liberty in the sense that, compared with any other system, it greatly widens the field for the exercise of personal choice. It is also the best safeguard of the variety of life, which emerges precisely from this extended field of personal choice, and the loss of which is the greatest of all the losses of the homogeneous or totalitarian state. For this variety preserves the traditions which embody the most secure and successful choices of former generations; it colours the present with the diversification of its fancy; and, being the handmaid of experiment as well as of tradition and of fancy, it is the most powerful instrument to better the future…

But Friedman started there and built a bridge to the conclusion that therefore episodes like the Great Depression were impossible if only the central bank maintained a constant money stock and thus a neutral monetary policy, and that that neutral monetary policy would all by itself be sufficient to guard against big depressions. And that bridge was a bridge too far.

A post-May Day analysis of U.S. income inequality

May Day celebrations kicked off around the world late last week, with unionists in many countries decrying the rise of income inequality in their countries. The United States, of course, celebrates Labor Day in September. But in the spirit of adding an American voice to the larger international commentary, here’s a post-May Day analysis of what economists think about income inequality in this country.

Income inequality has increased in the United States over the past 30 years, as income has flowed unequally to those at the very top of the income spectrum. Current economic literature largely points to three explanatory causes of falling wages and rising income inequality: technology, trade, and institutions. The existence of different explanations points to the difficulty of pinning down causes of inequality.

Part of this difficulty is rooted in the complexity inherent in larger labor market inequalities. Falling labor force participation, stagnating median wages, and declining share of labor income, for example, are all part of current U.S. labor market trends. These trends are certainly connected, but they also have been studied through various research frameworks, which can inexorably lead to different policy implications. Acknowledging the complex and intertwined nature of these explanations is crucial to developing policy solutions that address the joint causes of inequality.

Of the three explanations for rising inequality, the so-called technology-and -education argument is the most prominent. This hypothesis focuses on the large wage premiums for workers with high levels of education and skills. According to Massachusetts Institute of Technology professor David Autor, demand for skills has consistently increased across developed countries. The skill premium, then, is a result of skills not being supplied at a rate to keep up with demand. The proposed solution to inequality driven by these trends is increasing education and job training opportunities for workers so they can get better paying jobs.

A second explanation is trade and globalization. Scholars, including Autor, point to increases in trade and offshoring as a cause of income inequality. According to this hypothesis, growing trade between the United States and the rest of the world, especially China, has increased the number of imports in the U.S. economy, which has led to job loss in industries that originally produced these goods in the United States. Offshoring has also affected jobs and wages. Both these trade phenomena lead to declining employment, falling labor force participation, and weak inflation-adjusted wage growth. Possible policy solutions for this trend include those that would make U.S. exports more competitive, among them the depreciation of the U.S. dollar.

The last explanation suggests that U.S. government policies created an institutional framework that led to increasing inequality. Since the late 1970s, deregulation, de-unionization, tax changes, federal monetary policies, “the shareholder revolution,” and other policies reduced wages and employment. This explanation would seem to call for policy changes such as increasing unionization, better supervision of Wall Street, raising the minimum wage, and maintaining a full-employment focus in monetary policy, to address inequality and declining wages.

These three main explanations for income inequality show the difficulty in pointing to one cause of inequality over others. Researchers’ emphasis on disentangling causes of income inequality is relevant to understanding the issue, but it also highlights the complexity of factors that contribute to labor market inequality. Income inequality has no one cause. As such, any policy solutions that address inequality must match this nuance and acknowledge the various factors that contribute to inequality.

—Olga Baranoff is an intern with the Washington Center for Equitable Growth and an economics major at Johns Hopkins University.

Must-Read: Erik Loomis: Ideology Creators of the New Gilded Age

Must-Read: Erik Loomis: Ideology Creators of the New Gilded Age: “I’m not surprised that people are creating ideological justifications for the New Gilded Age…

…I am surprised however that one of them is Eric Hobsbawm’s daughter…. Everyone knows that networking is in fact how people get jobs and how class distinctions get reinforced…. The problem is that rising in life because of who you know is pretty objectively a bad thing…. Selling the idea that networking is awesome and should be embraced is deeply problematic on a number of levels… repackaged bootstrapism. The finest will rise and the less competent of the elite will fall…. It’s all about elite, elite, elite in this article. What about those who aren’t elite?… And now for the winner:

Ironically, there’s a bootstrapping, almost American aspect to how Hobsbawm got here. Her father, Eric Hobsbawm, was a Marxist historian and one of the most renowned scholars of the 20th century, but young Julia didn’t excel in school. She credits her success to working harder than her more academically-gifted peers, taking on tasks they wouldn’t do, and refusing to coast on her last name. Some people think “there is a shortcut and you just ring the most powerful person on that Rolodex,” she says, but it’s not that simple, “and that’s a good thing.”’

Ha ha ha ha ha…. As we were just told, the British understand how to succeed because of their class system so now let me, scion of one of the most famous intellectuals in the world during the second half of the twentieth century, tell you, Oregon mill worker’s son, how to succeed in life through hard work and networking. Well, somehow I’m not buying any of this…