Must-Read: Nuno Palma: Sailing Away from Malthus: Intercontinental Trade and European Economic Growth, 1500-1800

Must-Read: Nuno Palma: Sailing Away from Malthus: Intercontinental Trade and European Economic Growth, 1500-1800:

What was the contribution of intercontinental trade to the development of the European early modern economies?…

Previous attempts to answer this question have focused on static measures of the weight of trade in the aggregate economy at a given point in time, or on the comparison of the income of specific imperial nations just before and after the loss of their overseas empire. These static accounting approaches are inappropriate if dynamic and spillover effects are at work, as seems likely. In this paper I use a panel dataset of ten countries in a dynamic model which allows for spillover effects, multiple channels of causality, persistence and country-specific fixed effects. Using this dynamic model, simulations suggest that in the counterfactual absence of intercontinental trade, rates of early modern economic growth and urbanization would have been moderately to substantially lower. For the four main long-distance traders, by 1800 the real wage was, depending on the country, 6.1 to 22.7% higher, and urbanization was 4.0 to 11.7 percentage points higher, than they would have otherwise been. For some countries, the effect was quite pronounced: in the Netherlands between 1600 and 1750, for instance, intercontinental trade was responsible for most of the observed increase in real wages and for a large share of the observed increase in urbanization. At the same time, countries which did not engage in long-distance trade would have had real wage increases in the order of 5.4 to 17.8% and urbanization increases of 2.2 to 3.2 percentage points, should they have done so at the same level as the four main traders. Intercontinental trade appears to have played an important role for all nations which engaged in it, with the exception of France. These conclusions stand in contrast with the earlier literature which uses a partial equilibrium and static accounting approach.

Persistent economic disadvantage and education inequality in the United States

The intersection of income inequality and education is one of the more troubling features of the U.S. economy. Research by Stanford University economist Sean Reardon shows a rising educational achievement gap between students from high-income backgrounds and those whose parents are lower-income earners. There’s plenty of evidence that policymakers should be paying attention to educational differences by income, but most of the data that researchers use to evaluate educational programs don’t directly measure income. Instead, they employ proxies, most often eligibility for subsidized school lunches, to determine the economic disadvantages faced by some schoolchildren compared to others.

Simply using current eligibility or non-eligibility for subsidized lunches, however, might not be the best way to look at the effects of income inequality on educational achievement. A new paper by economists Katherine Michelmore of Syracuse University and Susan Dynarski of the University of Michigan shows why. The two researchers use administrative data from the state of Michigan to look at how economic disadvantages affect standardized test scores. Many studies on this question will look at the achievement gap during a single year and use a measure of disadvantage such as being eligible for subsidized school lunches. But the administrative data Michelmore and Dynarski use lets them track students over time to discern how often students were eligible for school lunches mapped to their test scores.

What they find is that there’s a difference—a significant one—in test scores in the 8th grade between students who are occasionally eligible for subsidized lunches and those who have been  eligible every single year since kindergarten. The two economists consider students who have been eligible every year (14 percent of Michigan students) to be persistently disadvantaged. And they find that these students score a full standard deviation below kids who have never been on subsidized lunches (40 percent of students) and just under a quarter below students who are occasionally eligible for subsidized lunches (roughly 45 percent of students). (A standard deviation being further away from something than a quarter standard deviation.)

Why is there such a difference between students who are occasionally eligible for subsidized lunches and those who are persistently eligible? One possibility is that exposure year after year to low-income living adds up over time, pushing down test scores in the process. But Michelmore and Dynarski find that the vast majority of the gap between persistently eligible students is present early on in their schooling—3rd grade, to be precise—so the differences in exposure alone can’t explain the gap. Instead, the two researchers argue that the difference between persistently-eligible students and occasionally-eligible students is a sign that the former are from much lower-income backgrounds. It’s a story of income inequality, not income volatility.

These results, as the authors note, have important implications for the design and evaluation of education programs. Eligibility for subsidized lunches is an important metric in many datasets used by researchers and policymakers to compare students across income levels. The difference between students who are occasionally eligible for school lunches and those who persistently may have significant effects. Many federal, state and local education programs use the percent of students in a school eligible for subsidized lunches as a way of targeting school spending. Yet there’s a significant amount of variation among schools with the same amount of eligibility when it comes to persistently and occasionally eligible students. A more targeted program would want to consider this variation as well.

A similar dynamic potentially holds for so-called value-added models for evaluating teachers. Often these measures will use the share of subsided lunch eligible students in a classroom as a control for the economic disadvantage of students in classrooms in order to not give lower scores to teachers who have low-income students. But if persistently eligible students are concentrated in some classrooms but not in others, then it could bias these measures of teacher performance.

The extent of that bias hasn’t been investigated yet. But what is clear from this paper is the need to use more fine-grained data when thinking about the impact of differences in income on educational outcomes. Other administrative data, for example tax data (if properly used), could be quite helpful. If policymakers are going to implement programs and evaluate them, we might as well use the best tools possible.

Must-Read: Matthew Shapiro: How Economic Shocks Affect Spending

W Must-Read: Matthew Shapiro: How Economic Shocks Affect Spending:

Many consumers do not follow the standard advice by having a substantial cash buffer. Nonetheless, they are able to smooth consumption in the face of a temporary drop in income by changing their timing of payments….

The tax rebates of 2001 and 2008, the 2009–10 tax credit, and both the onset and expiration of the 2011–12 payroll tax holiday… have some strong common features…. the implied marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is between one-quarter and one-third… a non-negligible effect on aggregate spending…. The most common response to receiving extra income is to pay off debt. From the standpoint of aggregate demand, saving a rebate or using it to pay off debt…. To the extent that a fiscal stimulus results from an economic downturn where consumers are cutting back spending because of a debt overhang—as was certainly the case in 2008 and its aftermath—it is not surprising that consumers use a tax rebate for balance sheet repair…. There is no evidence that the MPC from tax rebates or temporary tax cuts varies with income…

Must-Read: Paul Romer: Professionalism and the Academic Division of Labor

Must-Read: Paul Romer: Professionalism and the Academic Division of Labor:

Ed Prescott has a new NBER paper (with a co-author I do not know) on monetary policy with negative nominal interest rates…

Other economists have written on this topic. None of the work I know in this area is mentioned in Ed’s paper…. Suppose that 100 readers of the Prescott paper pursue questions about negative nominal interest rates and that links to the literature could have saved each of them 10 minutes. Then 100 minutes invested could have saved 1000 minutes. How many other chances does any of us have to make an investment with a 10x payoff? So Ed, please. Demonstrate what it means to be a professional

Must-Reads: August 2, 2016


Should Reads:

Must-Read: David Lipton: The Key to Raising Business Investment: Keep Pushing the Accelerator

Must-Read: Yes, 130% of the shortfall in business investment in the Global North is due to slack demand and the accelerator. We can puzzle why exceptionally loose interest rate policy has not helped more to boost private investment. We can lament the shortage of risk-bearing capacity that has kept spreads elevated.

Slide11 jpg 700×522 pixels

We can even demand reform of housing market finance in order to make people feel secure enough to be willing to move out of their sisters’ basements: homeownership rates continue to drop like a stone:

FRED Graph FRED St Louis Fed

But none of these should distract our attention from the fact that weak economies, slack private investment, low capital formation, and retarded productivity growth are a self-reinforcing vicious circle:

David Lipton : The Key to Raising Business Investment: Keep Pushing the Accelerator:

Why have businesses in advanced economies not been investing more in machinery, equipment and plants?…

Some believe that the key to more business investment is less uncertainty about fiscal policy, regulation, and structural reforms. Some believe that it is providing better financing…. The facts suggest a much simpler answer: Business investment has been weak because economic activity has been weak. Ensuring a recovery in sales and sales prospects is the key.

A study we published in the April 2015 World Economic Outlook suggests that virtually all of the weakness in business investment in advanced economies since the crisis can be explained by the weakness in the economic environment… in line with the ‘accelerator effect,’ where investment responds to changes in output and sales….

Now, as we leave the crisis behind, with faster growth in advanced economies, longer-term forces related to aging and lower productivity growth continue to cloud the horizon…. Long-term growth in advanced economies is now about ½ percentage point lower than it was before the crisis…. There is a risk that these longer-term forces come together and further reduce incentives to invest. So, even as we see faster growth, policymakers need to remain focused on ensuring a sustained rise in private investment. Here, while policy advice must be country specific, some general principles apply…. The case for more infrastructure investment remains…

Must-Read: Nick Rowe: Anti Urban Economics

Must-Read: Smart theoretical point about agglomeration. Situations in which we have strategic complementarity and negative externality are prisoners’ dilemmas. But is there reason to think that such situations are in any sense typical in the case of human agglomeration? Isn’t the natural presumption otherwise?

Nick Rowe: Anti Urban Economics:

I’m just throwing this out there. Read at your own risk…

I don’t know what I’m talking about (even more than usual). I’m just thinking out loud, and being ornery. I will explain where I’m coming from after I’ve made my point. There’s a difference between “strategic complementarity” and “positive externalities”. Strategic complementarity is what creates cities. But cities don’t necessarily create positive externalities. “Network externalities” is a bit of a BS term that conflates two conceptually distinct things…

Must-Read: Andy Taylor: Failure To Expand Medicaid Adds To Stresses In Southeast Kansas County

 

Andy Taylor: Failure To Expand Medicaid Adds To Stresses In Southeast Kansas County:

Dr. Julie Stewart doesn’t want political candidates and elected officials to show up at her nonprofit medical clinic in Coffeyville for photo opportunities, grant announcements or organized tours.

Instead, the Coffeyville physician would like those officials to take a personal interest in the patients who have chosen Stewart’s Community Health Clinic of Southeast Kansas because they have no health insurance options.

“I want you to come help me take off their socks so you can see the sores of a diabetic patient who has no health insurance,” Stewart said. “And then I want you to get on the ground in front of them and wash their feet.”

Such medical procedures are more than commonplace for Stewart. In Coffeyville, medical providers and clinics have seen an increase in traffic since the October 2015 closure of Mercy Hospital in nearby Independence, Kansas…. After Mercy Hospital’s closure, Independence and the surrounding area have become ground zero for the debate over Medicaid expansion and what it means for rural health care…. 31 states and the District of Columbia have expanded Medicaid eligibility to adults earning up to 138 percent of the federal poverty level…. Kansas is one of 19 states that have not expanded eligibility for Medicaid…. In Kansas, only adults with dependent children are eligible for KanCare, the state’s privatized Medicaid program, and then only if their annual incomes are below 28 percent of the poverty level, which for a family of four is $9,216….

Sheldon Weisgrau, of the Kansas Association for the Medically Underserved in Topeka, said…. “At $4,229 per person per year… Medicaid expansion would have brought $5.9 million to Montgomery County”… 38 medical jobs…. Mark Woodring, CEO of Coffeyville Regional Medical Center, said the hospital continues to be challenged by the growing tide of uninsured persons who use its emergency room for medical care. It is the only hospital in Montgomery County. Additionally, the hospital only receives about 20 cents on every $1…. “Tell me any other business that is guaranteed a loss of 80 cents on the dollar while dealing with more patients and surrounded by more needs,” Woodring said…. Weisgrau encouraged Kansas residents to take their concerns to elected officials…

Federal budget deficits, U.S. interest rates, and rates of return

The rate of return on public infrastructure investments is quite high right now due to a lack of investment in the past.

In yesterday’s New York Times, Nelson Schwartz writes about a seeming area of agreement between the two presidential candidates: an increase in the budget deficit. As Schwartz notes, this potential bipartisan development is quite a change from recent years, when the consensus seemed to be that short-term budget deficits had to be decreased, which they were. So what’s behind this reversal? Or rather, what’s are the reason why this reversal might be a good public policy idea? Well, it may have something to do with declining interest rates and potentially high rates of returns on public investments.

Long-term interest rates in the United States and other high-income countries have been on the decline for decades now. The reasons behind the decline are myriad (aging populations, higher inequality, and a global savings glut), but the short story is that the global investors are demanding much more U.S. government debt than the federal government is supplying. If growth in demand for something outstrips the growth of supply, then the price is going to increase. And since the price of a bond and its yield (the amount of interest paid out by a bond divided by its face value) are inversely related, interest rates are going to go down. This means that the United States government can now borrow money from the rest of the world at a very low price: 2.24 percent over 30 years (before accounting for inflation).

But when policymakers make an investment decision, they’re not going to look just at the cost of borrowing but also the potential return on that investment. Luckily in this area of low interest rates, there’s an area where investment would give the federal government a decent return: public infrastructure. A variety of analyses, including one by the International Monetary Fund, show that the rate of return on public investments is quite high right now due to a lack of investment in the past. So the federal government could borrow money from the markets and put those funds toward infrastructure improvements that would earn a return at a higher rate.

Increasing the federal budget deficit to finance other projects, such as tax cuts, increases in government transfer programs such as Social Security would probably not have the same rate of return. But increasing the budget deficit would help push up the supply of government debt, which in turn would push down the price of bonds, boost consumption and investment, and increase economic growth. It’s just a matter of picking which government spending opportunities make the most sense for the economy as a whole.

“Concrete Economics”, Pragmatism, the Hamilton Tradition, the Evolution of Macroeconomics, and the Post-2008 Nominal Demand Shortfall

Brad DeLong and David Beckworth: Macro Musings Podcast:


And the transcript, very kindly paid for by David, but so far unchecked:

Macro Musings: Episode 17 – Brad DeLong on Hamiltonian Political Economy & Economic History

[00:00] [background music]

David Beckworth: [00:02] Welcome to Macro Musings, the podcast series where each week we pull back the curtain and take a closer look at the important macroeconomic issues of the past, present, and future. I’m your host David Beckworth of the Mercatus Center. We are glad you’ve decided to join us.

[00:18] Our guest today is Brad DeLong. Brad is a professor of economics at the University of California, Berkeley. He is also a research associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research and was formerly in the Clinton Administration as the Deputy Assistant Secretary of the U.S. Treasury.

[00:37] Brad’s work ranges from business cycle dynamics to the political economy to the history of economic thought. Brad is also the author of several books, including his 2010 book The End of Influence: What Happens When Other Countries Have the Money and his more recent 2016 book Concrete Economics: The Hamilton Approach to Economic Growth and Policy. Brad, welcome to the show.

Brad DeLong: [00:58] Thank you very much. I’m extremely pleased to be here. Whatever “here” is in some metaphysical Internet sense.

David: [01:05] That’s the beauty of this day and age, when I can have someone like you on the other side of the country on the show. I want to begin like I do with most of my guests by asking how you got into economics. This show’s about macro. You have broader interests than just macro, but how did you get into economics and into macro in particular?

Brad: [01:23] I suppose first it would be Rick Erickson, Soviet specialist, Soviet economic specialist. Assistant professor at Harvard at the end of the late 1970s, who taught the most mind blowing version of Econ 1 for those of us who had I would say relatively advanced math, that he wound up with an Econ 1 section which was a go faster, do more section, and which had a great many people in it who could handle partial derivatives. He took full advantage of that.

[02:00] That was a mind-blowing experience in terms of getting one interested in economics. Then that was followed by having John Geanokopolos for Intro to Micro. Which was also a mind blowing experience, because he also had a largely applied math major class and was willing to push the envelope.

[02:23] If you know John, you know he is the most dynamic, witty, engaged, enthusiastic person imaginable, as well as being one of the very smartest people on the planet and very much willing to share that.

[02:37] After that point, we were excited about economics. We were interested in pushing it more. We were uninterested in taking undergraduate courses, because they seemed to us to go too slow and not to use the mathematical toolkit that made things a lot easier and a lot clearer and allowed you to go a lot faster and do a lot more.

[03:00] At that point we we being me, my freshman roommate Andrei Shleifer, and our friend Steven Kaplan bullied ourselves into the graduate macro core course at Harvard in the spring semester of our sophomore year taught by Olivier Blanchard and Marty Feldstein. Their view was “If you want to come, come. You’ll probably die.”

[03:29] We came, we didn’t die. We’re all happy now. Steve at Chicago, Andrei at Harvard, me at Berkeley. Andrei with his Clark medal and so forth.

[03:43] Olivier and Martin were as inspiring, as smart, and as impressive as John and before him Rick Erickson had been. Then immediately after that Andrei hooked up with Larry Summers as a research assistant. From there it seemed that the social network was very well greased. The intellectual project was very well greased. The fact that we had the analytical tools made it a no brainer as to what we should do.

[04:22] That’s how I wound up here. That and the fact that when I graduated from college in 1982, the unemployment rate was 10.6 percent, and graduate school, especially one funded by the NSF, seemed a smarter thing to do than to go out into the private sector job market.

David: [04:46] It’s always good to hear that great teachers play a role in shaping one’s life. I think in economics, it’s one of those disciplines where you can either have a great teacher or a disappointing teacher and they make a big difference whether you thrive in it.

[05:01] I read a story about you as an undergrad. You mentioned your roommate Andrei. This story said he and another roommate I believe of yours were overwhelmed by your reading prowess. You would just blow through books incredibly fast. In fact I think at one point he called you a superhuman when it comes to reading. Can you share with us that little story?

Brad: [05:26] I actually don’t remember ever being called a superhuman.

David: [05:29] It’s in the Harvard Crimson, that’s right.

Brad: [05:31] I do remember being told, “How do you read so much?” I felt the shoe was on the other foot. That here is Andrei showing up in Cambridge, Massachusetts as someone who claimed not to have been by any means the strongest mathematic student that Moscow Science Mathematics High School Number Two. I had been well and expensively prepared. How many of us were there?

[06:09] I guess I was one of the four people in Washington, DC in 1978 to have graduated from high school with a second year of calculus expensively provided to me by the Sidwell Friends School to which I am grateful. Not all high schools would assign a teacher to teach a class of four.

[06:32] This way we’re very much willing to, but they were relatively well paid for it, so I’m grateful to them as well. I show up, my first semester at Harvard and wind up in advanced calculus math 55.

[06:46] I’m finding that math 55 has a syllabus, a third of which I had already covered, and so since I had since the first third of math 55 before, I’ll be at a much, much more elementary level in terms of the linear algebra curriculum, and Andrei hadn’t. The first two months impressed him with the false idea that I was a mathematical genius, I’d just seen this before.

[07:18] Ever since then, I have been in awe of how quickly he can grasp theoretical and quantitative arguments, and see where the mathematical argument is going and what will be possible and what won’t. I’ve been feeling like I’ve been running other false pretenses that he thinks I’m smarter than I am, but that’s because I was well prepared by Sidwell Friends.

David: [07:39] Let’s turn to your new book. It’s actually co authored with Stephen Cohen called Concrete Economics. Tell us the key arguments that you are making in that book. I know you have some historical examples, if you could draw in some of those as well.

Brad: [07:56] If you look at the United States since the late 1970s and if you look at where the economy has been going, you see we’ve been making a whole bunch of debts in terms of how the government structures the market place or de-structures the market place. We’ve been pouring a whole lot of economic resources into a large number of areas.

[08:27] We’ve been devoting a lot of resources to elite consumption in the belief that if we pay our elites, our top 1 percent, our top 0.1 percent, and our top 0.01 percent more a greater share of the total national product than we were from the 1940s to the 1970s, they’ll do a better job at corporate control, at corporate management, at allocating investments that’s spurring people to work hard.

[08:57] We’ve been pouring an absolute fortune into health care administration in an attempt to keep a private sector health insurance market place of one sort of another up and running, and we’ve been pouring a massive amount of money into finance that the way very smart Thomas Sclafani puts it.

[09:22] That we used to have financial assets of about two and a half times a year’s GDP, and we would pay all told in management fees, in commissions, in price pressure to market makers. Pay about one percent of asset value each year to finance for managing our stuff which makes two and a half percent of GDP plus a half percent of GDP to run the payment system, a financial sector of three percent of national product.

[09:56] Today, we have four times annual GDP in gross marketed market of all financial assets of one form or another and we seem to be paying two percent of GDP to Wall Street in a metaphorical sense, in commissions, in management fees, and in price pressure when we panic and sell, or get enthusiastic and buy from the professionals. That’s eight percent plus another half percent of GDP for running the payment system. That’s eight and a half percent.

[10:28] That’s a huge social investment in a sector that really does provide intermediate goods, the payment system, the corporate control, allocation of investment, and so forth.

[10:42] I think that the returns from all of these investments, whether it’s in a more unequal distribution of income and wealth and higher elite consumption in order to spur our overclass to actually put their nose to the grindstone and do the job, whether it’s devoting a fortune to healthcare administration.

[11:07] Uwe Reinhardt of Princeton, I think, has the statistic about how American doctors are 30 percent more cost effective than German doctors, but American healthcare administrators are only one sixth as effective as German healthcare administrators at output per cost and in the hypertrophy of finance.

[11:26] These are not really the industries of the future. These are not industries that lead to rising standards of living and economic growth in general. This is very different from the industries that America used to invest in. Whether it was aerospace, whether it was the initial waves of government support for the computer revolution, whether it was the interstate highway system.

[11:55] Before then, whether it was the decision to actually go for infrastructure, and also the Hamiltonian support for manufacturing and for what was then an advanced payment system and Indeed, an initial capital market back at the very early days.

[12:16] These are all political economic decisions. These are all produced by ways the government does or does not structure and restructure marketplaces. These are all the result of pushing and hauling by populist groups on the one hand, by technocrats on the other, by people who’ve managed to get a good thing going and are properly seeking rents on the third. Of course, it’s easier to get rents if what you’re doing is actually productive.

[12:49] Yet, it seemed to work quite well up until 1980 or so. By and large, the industries of the future, whether they were the Republican bet on land grant colleges in the 1870s, or the Jefferson Lincoln — on up to the 1890s — decision that we were going to sell off public lands cheaply to occupiers, rather than, with the exception of the railroads, allow land barons to engross them.

[13:24] The decision to give large and highly corrupt subsidies to build out a transcontinental railroad network that then enabled all kinds of not just extremely high scale mass production, but also high scale distribution. That is, the continental market for the Americas played a big role in producing America’s edge over Europe in the late 19th century.

[13:48] All of these seem to be smart, in the way that our decisions since 1980 really have not been, so we thought we should write a little book about why this was so. The elevator pitch takeaway message is that back before 1980, we were self interested, we were political, we were somewhat corrupt, but we were also pragmatic.

[14:19] We thought we should be in the business of growing the economic pie more than anything else, and we would take a look at what were the options open to us at any one point and say, “What’s going to grow this economic pie?” Given what’s actually happening on the ground without paying too much attention to grand theories.

[14:42] Then around 1980, somehow we lost the narrative and we began pulling ourselves much more toward grand theories, as in, “Ideology tells us that this cannot work. Ideology tells us that that cannot work.” It’s that loss of American pragmatism that we want to blame for the fact that we currently have an economy that’s grossly underperformed, except for our superrich over the past 35 years.

[15:22] We want a call to get back to a non ideological, but rather pragmatic approach to economic policy and political economy. Don’t say that fundamental principles tell us that this is a good thing to do. Tell us how this policy is going to make us richer on the ground, soon and now.

David: [15:45] Let me ask you about one of the original discussions in your book. That goes back to Alexander Hamilton. You referenced him earlier…

Brad: [15:54] Yes, we’re trying to sail as close as possible to the Hamilton boom without having an intellectual property misappropriation test case right now.

David: [16:02] You mentioned there’s this tension, that any student who’s had American History knows, between Alexander Hamilton’s view of where America should go versus Thomas Jefferson. Here’s a question I have that ties it to the point you mentioned about 1980. One of the things that’s happened since 1980, that maybe confounds this issue is globalization begins to take off.

[16:28] The world economy slowly opens up and that’s going to have some effect. I wonder. Today we see the rise of populism with certain candidates in different parts of the world. There seems to be a populist backlash. Does it hearken back to this debate between Alexander Hamilton and Thomas Jefferson? The elite versus the farmer philosopher…

Brad: [16:55] Thomas Jefferson is pretty damned elite.

David: [16:57] That’s true. Fair point.

Brad: [17:00] Thomas Jefferson is not your yeoman farmer, much as he idealized yeoman farmers and thought, very ideologically, that…One of the guys who’d learned a little too much and yet not enough history of the duration and collapse of the Roman republic.

[17:27] He had people who thought that Rome was a great society, as long as it was all yeoman farmers who believed in the republic and solidarity, and farmed their own land, but willingly contributed to public purposes, waging wars, and serving in office.

[17:45] You go to Washington, DC, and you see all of these buildings reminiscent of what the people in the late 18th and the early 19th Centuries thought classical Rome ought to have looked like. Classical Rome being the Rome before the empire. Jefferson heard that and he believed that, so he loathed banks, he loathed cities, he loathed merchants, he loathed manufacturers, he loathed an urban proletariat.

[18:18] He wanted a country of yeoman farmers with all the other corrupt stuff somewhere offshore, with the exception of those people who were his own personal slaves. He did, at least, manage to free those who were his own personal descendants.

[18:44] That was a very strongly ideological road that Jefferson and company wanted America to take after 1776, after 1787, and fortunately, we did not take that road.

David: [18:57] Let’s go to the example of the First Bank of the United States and the Second Bank of the United States. Hamilton clearly was a supporter of the First Bank of the United States which is our first central bank, and Jefferson was opposed to it. Then we see that lasted 20 years, and then a few years later the Congress charters the Second Bank of the United States which is our second central bank.

[19:21] Andrew Jackson comes into the picture, and he effectively shuts it down when he wins an election. What I want to point out about that period, though, is there is this tension again between at least perceived harm being done by the Second Bank of the United States by the elites. The president of the Second Bank was perceived as this elite, and it echoes to the present, I guess.

[19:46] Coming to the present, do you see any similarities between this debate between Hamilton, Jefferson, in terms of banks, in terms of elites, versus the Donald Trump supporters of the world, the people in Brexit, the rise of populism in Europe…Do you see that? Going back to your book, what proposals do you have to bring that tension down, to address it in a meaningful way?

Brad: [20:21] I say there are people who say that tension really isn’t there in any stronger sense than in the past. That the way Tyler Cowen puts it, that it was always the case that 20 percent of America was crazy, but it used to be that 20 percent was divided between the two political parties.

[20:44] That there were western and northern type of people who were fairly crazy, who were ensconced in the Republican Party because they feared immigrants and the immigrant Democratic machines of the cities, and crime, and so forth.

[21:01] There were the people on the southern side, but they were not in the Republican Party. They were in the Democratic Party because Lincoln had freed the slaves, and they weren’t going to forget that. The elements of Trumpism were always there, but they were marginalized because they were split between the two great coalitions of American politics, the right of center and the mostly left of center coalition.
[21:34] If you want to put it another way, as Truman’s Secretary of State Dean Acheson did, the party of enterprise, and the party of those who feared that enterprise is not going to give them their fair share of the stuff.

[21:50] Then we have this great partisan realignment starting in 1964, when Goldwater decides that there’s a political opportunity to throw overboard the Republican Party’s historic commitment to the American, African American population.

[22:06] Now we have everyone sorted, and so the Trumpists are still 20 percent of America, but they’re 40 percent of the Republican Party, and because they’re energized, they’re 60 percent of the Republican primary electorate. That’s Tyler’s view, and I think there’s a very strong case that that’s a correct view. That it’s a serious problem, and it’s a serious problem not just for the Republican Party, but for America as a whole.

[22:41] In some ways it reflects the problems of America and of the Democratic Party back in the 1850s when the southern slave power was a minority in the country as a whole, and a minority even in the south.

[22:57] Because they were energized and activist and concentrated the Democratic Party, effectively the southern slave power elite controlled the Democratic Party and then were able to win more than their fair share of national elections.

[23:15] A grave problem, but it’s not a big change in terms of the underlying economic interests and views of the people, or even of the underlying sociological interests and views of the American people. It’s just a concentrate not a weak point in our political system. I think that’s by and large likely to be correct.

[23:42] In Britain and elsewhere, other things are happening and the other things that are happening are produced largely by the fact that the Great Recession has now been significantly deeper in Europe than in the United States. As we know from the 1930s, European political systems and America, too, are very vulnerable to any form of economic distress.

[24:10] “Throw the bastards out and go for somebody who is not part of the establishment,” seems to be what they do. They can go left, they can go right, they can go into outer space, they can go deep underground. They’re just going to go somewhere.

[24:30] It’s a combination of politicians who are attempting to ride this wave, coupled with true believers, coupled with the fact that ex Prime Minister Cameron is a real idiot, has produced a situation in which Scotland and Wales are regarding non London England with horror and despair right now.

[24:57] In which case, the great cosmopolitan city of London is looking at the people surrounding them and just wondering what’s going to happen to them as their political destinies are settled by a bunch of politicians who are riding a wave composed of people who truly do not understand, who have not been briefed, who have been substantially misled as to what their proper relationship with Europe should be.

David: [25:32] I’m sympathetic to your argument about the deepness of the Eurozone crisis setting the stage for some of the challenges over there. That’s a fair point. The Great Depression, 1930s, we saw that same phenomenon occur across the world, particularly in Germany and Italy.

[25:51] I want to move on now to an article you wrote in “The Journal of Economic Perspectives” in 2000. It was titled, “The Triumph of Monetarism,” and you recently revisited it. I’d like you just to tell us the argument you made back then and what observations are you making now 15, 16 years later about that argument?

Brad: [26:12] I think that the germ of it, although I don’t know if I acknowledge it in the article, came from Matthew Shapiro, now at the University of Michigan, who said that he had an interesting time as he went through undergraduate at MIT and then through graduate school at MIT. As a freshman at Yale, he was taught that monetarists were bad because they believed that changing the money stock changed nominal GDP and changed output.

[26:44] This was why the Chicago school was a bad thing, and yet by the end of his last year of his graduate study at MIT, he was being taught that Chicago style economics was bad because they thought that changes in the money stock did not affect nominal GDP. Or maybe they affected nominal GDP, but they certainly did not affect output. [laughs] This was very weird. That is, to be a Keynesian in 1974 was to deny that monetary variables had an important role to play in the C + I + G = PY equation.

[27:32] By 1984, 1985, the Keynesians were saying, “Well, of course, the money stock is close to a sufficient statistic for nominal GDP. Velocity’s not very volatile, and you combine nominal GDP with some degree of price inertia at the aggregate level, and of course, most movements and business cycle frequencies are driven by changes in demand and spending. Money demand and money supply.”

[27:58] Money supply being partly exogenous and partly endogenous, and then saying this was truly weird. A very weird change in a very short time as to what one was supposed to say in order to a Keynesian in good standing.

[28:16] I decided I should go back and I should take a look at the intellectual history. The conclusion of “The Triumph of Monetarism” was that practically all modern Keynesians, as of 2000, were really monetarists.

[28:32] That is the only dispute they possibly had with Uncle Milton was on whether a key percent fixed nominal money stock growth rate rule was an adequate feedback rule for monetary policy, in order to do the best you could at stabilizing aggregate demand.

[28:55] That practically everyone agreed that fiscal policy planning and legislative implementation lags meant that fiscal policy really should be off the table except for automatic stabilizers, which were useful. With Paul Krugman whimpering off in the corners saying, “What if you happen to hit the zero lower bound and wind up in a liquidity trap like Japan?” Everyone also saying, “Nah, Japan’s weird. We won’t get there.”

[29:23] Fiscal policy should have automatic stabilizers but otherwise should be settled on classical terms. Monetary policy should be the primary economic stabilization tool, and the interesting research questions are all about what should replace the k percent growth rule as an intermediate target which the central bank should try to use in order to try to stabilize the ultimate variables that it cares about.

[29:53] Calvo pricing, price rigidity, the Euler equation, the new Keynesian IS curve, all of these things, all of these tools, all of these doctrines, all of these arguments, were simply an attempt to put an underlying rationale behind instincts that were generally Friedman like.

[30:18] That is that monetary policy was the key link, that the central bank had an awesome responsibility, that you didn’t want anything as fully automatic and rigid as the gold standard, but you did somehow want to effectively constrain the central bank so that it couldn’t misbehave the way that Richard Nixon had persuaded Arthur Burns to misbehave in 1972 and that Richard Nixon had failed to persuade Martin to misbehave back in 1960.

[31:00] This was the problematic within which the discussion was taking place outside of the real business cycle people, who were off on their own building tools and yet failing to build anything that could be estimated or even calibrated to actually match the data as it came through.

[31:21] How it was that a bunch of people who were essentially monetarists had decided they were really Keynesian seemed to be an interesting question.

[31:30] The fact that they were really monetarists, even though many of them didn’t know it and others claimed not to know it, that they were much closer to Friedman than they were to someone like Tobin seemed to me something that people should be taught and that should be underlined.

David: [31:48] What was the insights that you have looking back now at this 15 years later, 16 years later?

Brad: [32:03] Suppose you’re Milton Friedman. It’s just after World War II. You’ve managed to get an academic job at Chicago. You’ve had a relatively difficult time getting it because you’re not enthusiastic about socialist planning or even semi socialist planning. You’re a member in good standing at the Mont Pelerin Society.

[32:28] Simon Kuznets had given you a job at the NBER for a while, even though he’d worked you hard.

[32:34] Before then, your first attempt to have an academic career had flamed out when, as I understand it, the legislature at Wisconsin had told the administrators in Madison there were too many Jews on the faculty. We don’t want you tenuring, promoting any more young Jews. There are too many of them, especially for Wisconsin.

[32:52] This gives Friedman a very sensible and rational fear of an over mighty government, reinforces his predispositions to think that what we want is a competitive markets everywhere. Pigouvian taxes where they’re really necessary, but only where they’re really necessary, because the process of passing them is subject to rent seeking.

[33:20] Even a bias toward actively engaging in Pigouvian taxes is probably harmful, as much as the micro says you ought to have them. The best you can do is try to preserve competitive markets and let the market system rip. If monopolies do emerge, they’ll be eroded over time if they aren’t powerfully backed up by the government. The whole thing.

[33:44] The problem with this, though, is that people point and look at the Great Depression and say, “Isn’t this an absolutely mammoth market failure? Doesn’t the fact that the market failed here and badly needed correction by some public sector entity indicate that there are likely to be equally big and bad market failures elsewhere?”

[34:08] The one hand, macroeconomics is a weak point for the general Chicago/Mont Pelerin view of the world. Also, his allies, ideological and otherwise, in other parts of economics, they want to say, “Gee, we have to have a gold standard, because anything else is government intervention in the marketplace.”

[34:33] We see this today. Someone like John Taylor is confused, highly, highly confused, when he claims that somehow central bank opened market operations to shift the interest rate or like a minimum wage, and a market distortion, and create Harberger triangles. Never been able to figure out what the Harberger triangle is, because he’s simply wrong.

[34:58] Friedman decided he needed to sail a very narrow and very clever intellectual path through the clear ocean between these Scyllas and Charybdises.

[35:10] Which was to say the Great Depression was a government failure because the government has as one of its principle market structuring obligations to maintain a proper monetary standard, just as it has an obligation to maintain proper weights and measures so you know what you’re buying and selling.

[35:30] A proper monetary standard requires the avoidance of both deflation and inflation, requires a monetary policy. A k percent growth rule is an approximation to that. The policy of having the central bank massively intervene in the marketplace buying and selling high powered money in order to keep the money stock stable, that’s actually a neutral monetary policy.

[36:00] That’s government non intervention in the marketplace. The non interventionist government is the one that frantically buys and sells liquid assets in order to keep the supply of liquidity services flowing to the private sector through the banking system constant.

[36:17] At some level, this is insane. The money stock is, after all, a thing that is largely inside money. The money stock is largely a measure of the amount of liquidity services provided to the rest of the economy by the banking sector. Milton Friedman’s k percent rule is a quantity target for the output of the liquidity services industry.

[36:43] Is there any other industry for which the government has an obligation to obtain a quantitative target for the service flow? Do we have a Federal Electricity Board that follows a policy of trying to keep the path of kilowatt hours generated stable? Do we have a Federal Railroad Commission with the job of trying to keep the number of freight cars loaded per month stable?

[37:08] No, we don’t. Why are liquidity services, in some sense, the key link? Friedman never answered this. As long as he could maintain that his k percent rule or even a modified k percent rule, something that approached nominal GDP targeting, at least by the time Friedman was giving advice to Japan in the late 1990s…

[37:36] As long as he could maintain that that was actually the neutral monetary policy that was non interventionist, you could maintain the seamless garment of being a free market, libertarian economist who believes that competitive markets without government interference were ideal.

[37:56] Yet, avoid the vulnerabilities to financial chaos, collapse, and Great Depression that Friedman strongly believed had been generated by the interwar gold standard and, before then, by the fact that the pre Federal Reserve United States monetary system was extremely vulnerable to collapses of the money supply and financial crises.

[38:23] It turns out that that was a successful rhetorical line intellectual position to hold on for pretty much until Milton Friedman died. As soon as 2008 rolled around, all of a sudden the monetarist coalition that had understood, say, the types of policies that Friedman recommended for Japan in the 1990s and also for the US in the Great Depression…

[39:11] The right of center coalition willing to swallow that as a neutral monetary policy was simply not there. Maybe if Friedman, in his time, had still been in there arguing, it might have been able to maintain, but the number of people who confidently expected quantitative easing to produce massive inflation no later than 2011 was very, very large.

[39:42] Paul Ryan still doesn’t understand why all his economic advisers told him that Ben Bernanke was debasing the currency and needed to be stopped immediately.

[39:57] When then Texas governor Rick Perry went to Iowa and said that Bernanke’s monetary policies were almost treasonous and that if he came down to Texas, we would give him the hot reception that people in Texas used to give to Communists and civil rights leaders, he was pursuing, in some sense, what had become the mainstream of right of center opinion on monetary policy.

[40:36] Which is that somehow there’s something very wrong with having the government do the massive, large scale interventions in the money market that it has been doing ever since mid 2008, and this is bound to be a destructive interference with the free market somehow.

[40:57] That’s a very strange position for people who at least still bow to Milton Friedman as great libertarian economist ancestor to put themselves in.

David: [41:10] Let me switch topics, but in a similar vein, in the few minutes that we have left. That is you have mentioned several times in your writings how you thought prior to 2008 it was widely understood that macroeconomic policy, both fiscal and monetary policy, would be used to stabilize the growth path of nominal demand.

[41:33] It didn’t do that. It’s disappointing. I think we can both agree on that point. In the next five minutes we have left in the program, why do you think it’s come to this? What has led policymakers to settle for allowing past mistakes to have occurred and not to correct for them?

Brad: [41:54] Damned if I know.

David: [41:56] You think it’s inflation targeting? Is it commitment to low inflation?

Brad: [42:02] I really do not know. I’m supposed to do a paper for this for the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston in October, and I agreed because it’s still very much a mystery to me. That is, you have a consensus model, at central banks at least, that we have. We very much want to avoid deflation, because we fear Irving Fisher like debt deflation spirals.

[42:40] We believe in substantial amounts of nominal price rigidity in the short and medium run in labor and product markets, so we can’t count on rapid price adjustment, either downwards or upwards, in order to stabilize nominal GDP. As John Maynard Keynes said, inflation and deflation are really unjust, as well.

[43:07] It seemed to me that, given your belief in a world where there’s this macroeconomically significant market failure of short and medium run price rigidity, what you do is you use monetary policy to try to stabilize nominal GDP.

[43:23] If monetary policy won’t do the job, then you turn to your next tool, which is fiscal policy. After all, the purpose of macro policy is to make Say’s law true in practice given the market failures we have out there. This wage and price rigidity is the principle market failure.

[43:43] Yet, ever since late 2009, not just politicians in legislatures and in executives but central bankers, as well, have been reaching for reason after reason not to take the signal that decelerating growth in nominal GDP should lead one to think in the context of a world in which you think that stable inflation expectations and short and medium run price inertia are the key features that need to be handled.

[44:31] I really do not know why, especially with interest rates at their current level and thus with real debt service on the US national debt, not just zero but negative, that you don’t even need hysteresis of any form at current interest rates for fiscal expansion to reduce the debt burden, just the short run stuff. The short run tax offset will do it.

[45:04] Then, the long run, we’re borrowing at less than the nominal GDP growth rate of the economy.

[45:14] Why helicopter drops and infrastructure investment are not obvious no brainers across the political spectrum and also across the spectrum of economics as tools to get nominal GDP back onto its pre 2008 track remains an extraordinary mystery to me.

[45:37] As much as I try to listen to the Ken Rogoffs, and the Marty Feldsteins, and the others who are opposed to one or more of these tools, I simply cannot wrap my mind around what their arguments really are.

David: [45:48] I look forward to reading your paper for this conference, since you’ll be thinking about this issue for some time. Our guest today has been Brad DeLong. Brad, thank you for being on the show.

Brad: [46:00] You’re welcome. Thank you very much.

[46:02] [background music]

David: [46:05] Macro Musings” is produced by the Mercatus Center at George Mason University. If you haven’t already, please subscribe via iTunes or your favorite podcast app. While you’re there, please consider rating us and leave a review. This helps other thoughtful people like you find the podcast. Thanks for listening.

Transcription by CastingWords