Must- and Should-Reads: September 21, 2017


Interesting Reads:

Should-Read: Will Wilkinson: What Drives Opposition to Immigration? In-Group Favoritism, Out-Group Hostility, and Donald Trump

Should-Read: Will says: “The standard form of liberal civic nationalism is egalitarian within the in-group of shared citizenship…” There has been something more with American civic nationalism: it is a nationalism of people who have come and whose ancestors have come from all over the world to a place where they can live freely, work hard, raise each other up, and build a utopia to show the rest of the world how good things can be: “He shall make us a praise and glory that men shall say of succeeding plantations, ‘may the Lord make it like that of New England’. For we must consider that we shall be as a city upon a hill. The eyes of all people are upon us…”, in the words of my ancestor John Winthrop.

All that seems to be lost in the minds of an aging group of greedy white guys, scared that mysterious others are going to take away what they have somehow:

Will Wilkinson: What Drives Opposition to Immigration? In-Group Favoritism, Out-Group Hostility, and Donald Trump: “Friedman contrasts ‘xenophobia’ and ‘nationalism’, but I’d like to reframe… (To many of us, xenophobia and nationalism go hand in hand.)… https://niskanencenter.org/blog/drives-opposition-immigration-group-favoritism-group-hostility-donald-trump/

…In-group favoritism (“nationalism”) need not imply hostility to out-groups (“xenophobia”). He goes on to argue that opposition to immigration is driven mainly by in-group favoritism; out-group hostility is less important…. I think opposition to immigration is drive… at least as much by out-group antipathy as by in-group favoritism….

Voters know next to nothing about politics and policy, aren’t very ideological, and tend to vote in groups defined by personal and social identities—race, religion, class, etc…. Once we’ve assumed a partisan identity, usually on the basis of a more fundamental social identity (e.g., union member, African American, evangelical Christian, etc.), we mostly just go along with whatever our party happens to be currently saying—if… we happen to be sufficiently clued in to what our party is saying…. Policy positions of voters—and even politicians—can be quite malleable in response to new signals from respected group leaders….

This is pretty telling to me. Most Republicans seem to think you need to be a Christian non-immigrant to count as a full-fledged member of the national in-group, and these views were especially prevalent among Trump primary supporters….

Xenophobia… an aversion to foreignness and those who seem strangely other, is an element of nationalism, in the sense of “nationalism” currently under public discussion…. Xenophobic sentiment and a drive to exclude non-white, non-Christian, non-English-speaking Americans from full and equal membership in the political community seem obviously related…. Out-group hostility drives opposition to immigration. And, as Sides shows, it drove Democrats who had voted for Obama to support Trump. Comparing the determinants of the 2012 and 2016 presidential vote share, Sides writes: “What stands out most… is the attitudes that became more strongly related to the vote in 2016: attitudes about immigration, feelings toward black people, and feelings toward Muslims.”…

Trump’s nationalism is a form of in-group partiality, for sure. But the relevant in-group is, as Müller suggests, a subset of American citizens who approximate an exclusive populist conception of American national identity. The relevant out-group, then, includes other American citizens, as well as foreigners. The form of nationalism Friedman examines in his piece is more legalistic and less cultural, drawing the in-group/out-group distinction in terms of shared citizenship…. The standard form of liberal civic nationalism is egalitarian within the in-group of shared citizenship. Citizens get equal weight, period. Nativity, race, religion, languages spoken, etc. simply don’t matter…. In our current political context, that seems like a dream. Populist nationalism, in contrast, is inegalitarian within the in-group of shared citizenship…. You’ve got xenophobia, [and] nationalism comes along as part of the bargain.

Should-Read: Josh Barro: Graham-Cassidy healthcare bill has Alaska Purchase for Lisa Murkowski

Should-Read: Republicans: worse than you can imagine, even after you have compensated for the fact that they are worse than you can imagine: http://www.businessinsider.com/graham-cassidy-health-care-bill-alaska-purchase-lisa-murkowski-vote-2017-9

Josh Barro: Graham-Cassidy healthcare bill has Alaska Purchase for Lisa Murkowski: “Making things odder: Neither VerBruggen nor I could locate the provision in the bill…

…So I asked a staffer in Cassidy’s office…. The spreadsheet came down off the senator’s website after I inquired about it…

“Any Community… Flourishes only When Our Members Feel Welcome and Safe…”

Somehow I do think the New York Times could have put more thought into their questions for the community of the University of California at Berkeley https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2017/09/19/us/formacist-ucberkeley-callout.html?_r=0.

I think that they could have written better questions if only they had read the “Terms of Service” they require those of us answering their questions to agree to.

From the “Terms of Service”:

You shall not… [write]… any libelous, defamatory, obscene, pornographic, abusive, or otherwise illegal material.

Be courteous. You agree that you will not threaten or verbally abuse other Members, use defamatory language, or deliberately disrupt discussions with repetitive messages, meaningless messages or “spam.”

Use respectful language. Like any community, the online conversation flourishes only when our Members feel welcome and safe. You agree not to use language that abuses or discriminates on the basis of race, religion, nationality, gender, sexual preference, age, region, disability, etc. Hate speech of any kind is grounds for immediate and permanent suspension of access to all or part of the Services.

Debate, but don’t attack. In a community full of opinions and preferences, people always disagree. NYT encourages active discussions and welcomes heated debate on the Services, but personal attacks are a direct violation of these Terms of Service and are grounds for immediate and permanent suspension of access to all or part of the Service….

The NYT… is not responsible for the content of [yours it publishes, but] NYT reserves the right to delete, move, or edit Submissions that it, in its sole discretion, deems abusive, defamatory, obscene, in violation of copyright or trademark laws, or otherwise unacceptable…


Their questions and my answers:

Is there any type of speech you think should not be allowed on campus?

A university has three goals:

  1. A university is a safe space where ideas can be set forth and developed.
  2. A university is a safe space where ideas can be evaluated and assessed.
  3. A university is a safe space where young scholars can develop, and gain intelligence and confidence.

Speech whose primary goal is to undermine and defeat one or more of those three goals does not belong on a university campus.

If you come to Berkeley, and if your speech is primarily intended to—or even, through your failure to think through what you are doing, has the primary effect of (1) keeping us from developing ideas that may be great ones, (2) keeping us from properly evaluating and assessing ideas, or (3) driving members of the university away, your speech does not belong here.

 

Did U.C. Berkeley’s history as a beacon of free speech influence your decision to attend?

Of course.

 

Has the issue of free speech come up in any of your classes? If so, how was it raised and what was the context?

I raised it last spring in one of my lectures, at the start, when we could hear the helicopters and the sirens.

 

Are you concerned about campus safety during Free Speech Week?

Of course. There are lots of people who want to take advantage of free speech week to neither:

  1. develop ideas that may be great ones,
  2. thoughtfully and rationally evaluate and assess ideas, nor
  3. make the university a welcoming place for young scholars.

Some will want blood in the streets. Some will hope to take advantage of blood in the streets. Somebody may wind up dead, or maimed, as part of a game of political-cultural dingbat kabuki largely orthogonal to the three proper missions of the university.

It is a serious concern.

Must-Read: Ezra Klein: Graham-Cassidy could’ve been the GOP’s best Obamacare replacement

Must-Read: Stuart Butler is the person who knows something about health care who should, given his values and his analytical judgments, be most favorably inclined toward Graham-Cassidy. He is strongly opposed: “[a] high probability of really bad outcomes…” is his bottom line.

And nobody else of any reputation or note has even as favorable a judgment…

Ezra Klein: Graham-Cassidy could’ve been the GOP’s best Obamacare replacement: “Instead, Lindsey Graham and Bill Cassidy wrote the worst plan yet… https://www.vox.com/policy-and-politics/2017/9/20/16333384/graham-cassidy-obamacare-health-care

…Here’s where they went wrong.

It didn’t need to be this way.

Squint, and you can see how Graham-Cassidy, the latest Republican repeal bill, could have been the basis for a grand compromise on health care.

To hear Sens. Lindsey Graham and Bill Cassidy explain it, their bill takes Obamacare’s money and hands it over to the states to do with it as they will, unleashing them to be, in Louis Brandeis’s immortal phrase, the laboratories of democracy. Blue states can keep Obamacare or try to build on it — Obamacare-plus, single-payer, whatever. Red states can reject Obamacare and prove that they can get better results by going a different path.

“Instead of a Washington-knows-best approach like Obamacare, our legislation empowers those closest to the health care needs of their communities to provide solutions,” Graham said in a statement. “Our bill takes money and power out of Washington and gives it back to patients and states.”

This would be, as I’ve argued before, the smartest Republican approach to replacing Obamacare. It frees Republicans from making tricky decisions about subsidy levels and structures, about what gets covered and what doesn’t, about how insurers are regulated and how deductibles are managed.

Crafting legislation like this would take work, but Graham and Cassidy seemed ready to do that work. The hyperpartisan, truncated, underinformed, secretive process that led to the previous GOP bills repelled them. As Graham tweeted back in May, “A bill — finalized yesterday, has not been scored, amendments not allowed, and 3 hours final debate — should be viewed with caution.”

And both Graham and Cassidy have good relationships with Senate Democrats. Graham is known for bipartisan cooperation; Cassidy is known as the rare Republican who cared deeply about insurance coverage. If any two Republicans could run a process with hearings, with amendments, with analysis, with bipartisan negotiation, with the time and space to get the bill right, it would be them.

The ugly reality of Graham-Cassidy: But Graham-Cassidy, as it actually exists, doesn’t look anything like that bill, and it’s not going through anything like that process. Instead, it uses federalism as rhetorical cover for gutting spending on both Obamacare and Medicaid, punishing states that expanded health coverage, and violating virtually every policy and process argument Graham and Cassidy have made over the past year.

The legislation would lead to tens of millions of people losing coverage, insurance markets collapsing across the country, and yet more bitter fighting over health care policy. It would make protections for preexisting conditions optional and redistribute funding from states that expanded Medicaid to states that didn’t.

This isn’t a bill that gives states the resources they have now but hands over the control and the tools to innovate and make their health systems better. It’s a bill that slashes the resources states are getting now and leaves them responsible for managing the ugly aftermath. As a careful analysis produced by the left-leaning Center on Budget and Policy Priorities shows, the cuts envisioned in Graham-Cassidy reach $80 billion a year by 2026 — and states are left holding the bag. Making matters both worse and weirder, the bill’s entire funding stream expires in 2027, meaning Congress either needs to reauthorize it or the country’s entire health system falls into chaos:

Center on Budget and Policy Priorities: But the politics of Graham-Cassidy are uglier even than that graph suggests. The complex formula they use to redistribute their shrunken pool of funds punishes states that earnestly expanded Medicaid and tried to make Obamacare’s exchanges work. Asked about these disparities, the bill’s backers have repeatedly argued that it’s just math. “I like Massachusetts, I like Maryland, I like New York, I like California, but I don’t like them that much to give them a bunch of money that the rest of us won’t get,” Graham said.

Of course, that money is available to any state that chose to expand Medicaid, to any state that put real effort into enrolling the uninsured, and it still is. This redistribution from states that tried to make their health systems work to states that didn’t is the reason a number of Republican governors — including John Kasich of Ohio, Bill Walker of Alaska, Charlie Baker of Massachusetts, and Brian Sandoval of Nevada — have come out against the legislation.

Finally, the bill sends its lump-sum payments to the states with few standards or guardrails. States don’t have to build systems that insure more people or as many people; they don’t have to show better results or higher quality care. It’s easy to imagine these payments becoming a slush fund used to make state budgets easier to manage, as has happened in previous block grant programs.

Given these dangers, and given the difficulties of figuring out the right funding formulas and thinking through the needs of different states, you might imagine Graham and Cassidy would hold dozens of hearings, solicit feedback from governors across the nation, and seek amendments from senators representing diverse states. You would definitely assume they’d be working with experts to run deep, thorough analyses of their bill’s likely effects.

But none of that is happening. Graham and Cassidy aren’t even waiting for a full Congressional Budget Office score before moving forward with their legislation, which they’ve decided has to pass by next Saturday because they want it to qualify for the rapidly expiring reconciliation process.

This is a process without the information or the time to fully work out the consequences. No one, including Graham and Cassidy, has any real idea what this legislation would mean for America’s health care system, and they’re not waiting around to find out.

As my colleague Sarah Kliff wrote, Graham-Cassidy is “the most radical Republican health plan to date,” and they’re jamming it through the most bizarre, underinformed, truncated process yet.

A “waste of both of our time”: On Tuesday, I asked both Cassidy and Graham’s offices why they didn’t do this the other way. Why not create state flexibility without joining it to massive spending cuts? Why not go through the normal order and give legislators the time to work through the bill’s details, amend its approach, and build real support? Cassidy’s office never responded. Graham’s spokesperson Kevin Bishop pointed to previous Vox articles critical of Graham-Cassidy and said that answering these questions would be a “waste of both of our time.”

Bishop’s answer is unintentionally revealing: Since winning the White House, Republicans have treated the basic work of legislating on health reform as a waste of precious time. There has never been time to hold hearings, to consider amendments, to negotiate with Democrats, to explain provisions, to consider counterarguments, to work through details.

Republicans justify this mad dash by pointing to September 30, when their ability to use the 51-vote budget reconciliation process in 2017 ends. But that objection is hollow on two levels: They wouldn’t need reconciliation if they could win over Democratic votes, which they haven’t tried, and if that failed, they could spend a few months working on their bill and use reconciliation again next year, or the year after. There is no external force that justifies a process this slipshod and partisan. This is a choice Republicans are making, and it is the wrong one.

Graham-Cassidy is a sweeping, ambitious bill that will completely upend America’s health care system. It has the germ of a good idea in it, and you could imagine a legislative effort building on it toward a worthwhile result. But the bill as written is a mess and the process it’s being jammed through is a disaster. The idea that legislation like this must be passed by next Saturday, even in the absence of CBO analysis or time to discuss and amend, would be farcical if it weren’t so dangerous.

But don’t take it from me. Brookings’ health policy expert Stuart Butler has been pushing federalist health reforms for years. When I emailed him, I expected him to be enthused by Graham-Cassidy. But he wasn’t. “I am a conservative, not a radical, even if I want to see major reform,” he replied. “You just can’t transform the massive health system as quickly as the GOP is trying to do under Cassidy (and other previous approaches this year) without the high probability of really bad outcomes.”

Bad outcomes weren’t the only outcomes possible here. They’re just the ones Graham and Cassidy, for reasons known only to themselves, chose.

Should-Read: Kristie De Peña: Entrepreneurial Visas

Should-Read: It is hard for me to see why anybody who is not a white nativist would be opposed to this—and thus hard to see why it has not already become law—unless you take a very pessimistic view of the present and future shape of the Republican coalition indeed…

Kristie De Peña: Entrepreneurial Visas: “Some of the most powerful and effective innovators are immigrant entrepreneurs looking to capitalize on the unique opportunities the United States offers… https://niskanencenter.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/07/EntrepreneurialStartupVisas.pdf

…Immigrants are twice as likely to start a business, and immigrants and their children created 40 percent of the Fortune 500 companies. Forty-two spots on the Forbes 400 list are occupied by U.S. billionaires from 21 foreign countries, who have a combined net worth of $250 billion…. Unfortunately, the only opportunity for most foreign entrepreneurs to come to America to start is a business is to secure an H-1B visa and launch a venture on the side—a notoriously difficult endeavor—or to secure work authorization through a family visa. Just 85,000 H-1B visas—20,000 of which are reserved for master’s degree holders—are granted annually, but the past few years have seen increasing demand… for the fifth consecutive year, the cap was met within five days…. We need a new visa that makes it easier for entrepreneurs to contribute positively to the economy…

Should-Read: Nicholas Bloom, Charles I. Jones, John Van Reenen, and Michael Webb: Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?

Should-Read: “Harder”… I am not sure this is the way to look at it. Yes, it is becoming harder in the level-log specification they adopt. But why should that be the benchmark? And it is certainly true that innovations have less of an effect on human “utility” because we are so much richer. But why should that come as a surprise?

I have to think about this more…

Nicholas Bloom, Charles I. Jones, John Van Reenen, and Michael Webb: Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?: “In many growth models, economic growth arises from people creating ideas, and the long-run growth rate is the product of two terms… http://www.nber.org/papers/w23782

…the effective number of researchers and their research productivity. We present a wide range of evidence from various industries, products, and firms showing that research effort is rising substantially while research productivity is declining sharply. A good example is Moore’s Law. The number of researchers required today to achieve the famous doubling every two years of the density of computer chips is more than 18 times larger than the number required in the early 1970s. Across a broad range of case studies at various levels of (dis)aggregation, we find that ideas — and in particular the exponential growth they imply — are getting harder and harder to find. Exponential growth results from the large increases in research effort that offset its declining productivity…

Should-Read: Ben Thompson:The GDPR and Facebook and Google, Intelligent Tracking Prevention, Data Portability and Social Graphs

Should-Read: We seem to be headed toward a future in which governments—at least in Europe—both entrench and then heavily regulate Google and Facebook, with their information edge creating the possibility that they will be for the 21st century very much what AT&T in the United States was for the bulk of the 20th century:

Ben Thompson: THE GDPR AND FACEBOOK AND GOOGLE, INTELLIGENT TRACKING PREVENTION, DATA PORTABILITY AND SOCIAL GRAPHS: “Several folks have suggested that the GDPR’s requirements around data portability… https://stratechery.com/2017/the-gdpr-and-facebook-and-google-intelligent-tracking-prevention-data-portability-and-social-graphs/

…including that it be machine accessible (i.e. not just a PDF) will help new networks form, but in fact the opposite is the case…. It’s a reasonable regulation: my friend on Facebook didn’t give permission for their information to be given to Snapchat, for example. It does, though, make it that much more difficult to bootstrap a Facebook competitor…

Should-Read: Jeff Stein: GOP senators are rushing to pass Graham-Cassidy. We asked 9 to explain what it does

  • Should-Read: Republican Senators can find nobody who will, even in public (with private reservations), even pretend to agree with them that GC will not result in massive losses of health insurance coverage by tens of millions. Not even Avik Roy. Nobody. Literally nobody:

Jeff Stein: GOP senators are rushing to pass Graham-Cassidy. We asked 9 to explain what it does: “Republican senators are struggling to articulate why they are rushing to pass their last-ditch effort to repeal and replace Obamacare… https://www.vox.com/policy-and-politics/2017/9/20/16333876/republican-senators-graham-cassidy

The GOP senators insisted that the tens of billions in cuts to federal health spending proposed in the bill would not result in coverage losses because, they said, the states would have more flexibility. “They can do it with less money,” said Sen. Jim Inhofe (R-OK), who was unable to explain how or why…

New federal antitrust legislation recognizes U.S. workers are not only consumers

Sen. Amy Klobuchar of Minnesota on Capitol Hill in Washington, D.C.

The introduction of two new antitrust bills by Sen. Amy Klobuchar, D-MN, last week indicates that Democrats are serious about making antitrust enforcement a central plank in their economic policy platform. In July, congressional Democrats released “A Better Deal,” intended to be the jumping off point for their policy agenda for the 2018 elections, and antitrust was a major plank. Sen. Klobuchar’s bills would implement many of the antitrust policy issues highlighted in “A Better Deal.”

The increased interest in issues of competition and antitrust enforcement on the policy side is matched by that on the research side. As examples of market concentration mount, researchers are increasingly asking whether any number of the economic ills we’re experiencing—from the rise in inequality to decreased business investment, stagnant wages for less-educated workers, and the decline in startups—are perhaps all related to one underlying cause: the growth in market power of a small handful of “superstar” firms in their fields.

Equitable Growth has done a lot of work on the subject of competition and antitrust recently, including analyses of some of the most recent research on the subject, as well as a case study of the telecommunications industry and data analysis of merger enforcement actions. A critical question is what the relationship is between companies’ market power and inequality. There seem to be multiple channels through which greater market power and lower competition could increase economic inequality. While antitrust issues have generally been viewed from a consumer perspective over the past 30 years, focusing on the consumer price effects of mergers, this emphasis on whether sellers create monopolies for their products ignores that buyers can also create a monopsonic market for the prices they pay.

A monopsonic market is one in which a buyer of a good or service has the power to pay lower prices than he or she would have to in a competitive market. In the case of a labor market, monopsony refers to a firm or firms’ ability to restrict wages below what they would be in a competitive market. If an increasingly smaller handful of firms are dominating their industries, then they have fewer competing buyers for labor. The classic and most extreme example of this phenomenon is the “company town,” in which there is only one employer and therefore workers are easily exploited. Of course, that rarely happens today—though companies do have varying degrees of monopsonic power.

The Clayton Act of 1914—one of the foundational antitrust laws in the United States—bans mergers that would create a monopoly, but there is no explicit reference to monopsony. Sen. Klobuchar’s Consolidation Prevention and Competition Promotion Act of 2017 proposes to make explicit that monopsony should be treated the same way. By incorporating monopsony into Clayton’s legislative language, mergers that allow a company to unfairly lower the prices it pays its employees or suppliers would not be allowed.

The explicit incorporation of monopsony into an existing statute is an example of one of the central tensions in the debate among think tank scholars, policymakers, and federal antitrust enforcers. The question is whether policymakers already have the proper antitrust tools they need and just need to enforce them more strenuously, or whether new companies and business models in the 21st century economy demand new tools. Sen. Klobuchar’s bills seem to take a “both/and” approach, calling for greater resources for our existing enforcement agencies, as well as the creation of new antitrust tools. These tools include the explicit incorporation of “monopsony” into the Clayton Act’s text, as well as the creation of a new Office of the Competition Advocate along the lines of the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau.

More work is needed to understand how either updated or new antitrust policies could be implemented and might play out in the economy. That’s why Equitable Growth is proud to announce that we’re partnering with American University’s Washington College of Law to host an event on October 27, 2017, in Washington, D.C. “Unlocking the Promise of Antitrust Enforcement” will feature presentations by leading scholars in antitrust law and economics, along with discussion by prominent antitrust practitioners to explore whether there is scope for more vigorous enforcement of existing law. You can can register to attend and learn more here.