Things to Read on the Evening of January 23, 2014

Must-Reads:

  1. Jared Bernstein: Mark Schmitt on Inequality: “Mark Schmitt…[:] ‘…it’s not that [inequality is] anything less than “the defining challenge of our time”…. Rather, it’s too defining, too large…. too sweeping and cluttered to lead to useful solutions…. ‘Also… it’s not the case that any level of economic inequality is problematic. Every economic system distributes…. When someone raises the issue as problematic these days, they’re really saying something about historically high levels… [and] the impact of these levels on something else…”

  2. Justin Wolfers: Twitter / JustinWolfers: Explaining the big new Chetty…: “Explaining the big new Chetty mobility study: 1. No change in odds of moving higher or lower on the economic ladder than your parents. 2. But higher income inequality today means that the rungs of the income ladder are now much further apart than in the past. 3. Consequences of the “birth lottery” are larger now, because low mobility has bigger consequences. 4. Bottom line of mobility study: Kids, more than ever, be careful to choose the right parents.”

  3. Menzie Chinn: Econbrowser: Euro and Non-Euro Countries and Fiscal Policy: “Contractionary fiscal policy is… contractionary. There has been some dispute over the robustness of the findin… over the proper time horizon…. Here is the entire sample of advanced countries… cumulative growth rates 2009-13 plotted against cumulative change in the cyclically-adjusted budget balances…. The more contractionary the policy stance, the slower the growth…. It’s clear that eurozone countries are a special case, where monetary policy is out of the control of the individual countries; a question is whether countries with their own monetary policy could actually experience an expansionary fiscal contraction…. For the non-euro area group, the regression coefficient is less negative, and is only significant at the 17% marginal significance level…. See this New Palgrave Encyclopedia of Economics chapter for an examination of why one would expect to see relatively large multipliers in the current economic conditions of ZLB and excess capacity.”

  4. Paul Krugman: Everything New Is Old Again: “There have been two big revolutions in macro…. The Keynesian revolution… tied to the Great Depression; then the new classical counterrevolution… loosely tied to stagflation in the 1970s…. Keynes offered a way to understand what was happening, and a solution…. Stagflation was predicted by Friedman and Phelps, using models that attempted to derive wage and price-setting behavior from rational choice… the effect… was to give a big boost to ‘microfoundations’ as a modeling strategy…”

  5. Mark Thoma: Economist’s View: Income Mobility: “The topic of the day seems to be the [Chetty et al.] new study on income mobility: [David Leonhardt:] Upward Mobility Has Not Declined; Jared Bernstein: Stable Income Mobility: Not a Muddle At All; Dean Baker: [Did We Need a Landmark Study to Tell Us Mobility Didn’t Decrease Between 1990 and 2007?]9http://www.cepr.net/index.php/blogs/beat-the-press/did-we-need-a-landmark-study-to-tell-us-mobility-didnt-decrease-for-people-entering-the-labor-market-between-1990-and-2007); Tyler Cowen: Upward mobility in the United States is not declining as many citizens think; Matthew Yglesias: What If Social Mobility Is Never High Anywhere?; Kevin Drum: Income Mobility in the US is Terrible, But at Least It’s Not Getting Worse; Heather Boushey: Here’s to wishing you the best of luck in the birth lottery—you’re going to need it…. My take is similar to Kevin Drum’s, who manages to separate the level of mobility (very low) to the rate of change (one study, the latest, says mobility is unchanged)…. [And Heather’s] response emphasizes the geographic variation–where you are born appears to matter quite a bit.”

Continue reading “Things to Read on the Evening of January 23, 2014”

Evening Must-Read: Mark Thoma: Mobility Roundup

Mark Thoma: Economist’s View: Income Mobility: “The topic of the day seems to be the [Chetty et al.] new study on income mobility:

And Mark comments:

My take is similar to Kevin Drum’s, who manages to separate the level of mobility (very low) to the rate of change (one study, the latest, says mobility is unchanged)…. [And Heather’s] response emphasizes the geographic variation–where you are born appears to matter quite a bit.

Evening Must-Read: Paul Krugman: Will University Economics Departments Help Us Understand Business Cycles?

Paul Krugman: Everything New Is Old Again:

There have been two big revolutions in macro…. The Keynesian revolution… tied to the Great Depression; then the new classical counterrevolution… loosely tied to stagflation in the 1970s…. Keynes offered a way to understand what was happening, and a solution…. Stagflation was predicted by Friedman and Phelps, using models that attempted to derive wage and price-setting behavior from rational choice… the effect… was to give a big boost to ‘microfoundations’ as a modeling strategy.

Continue reading “Evening Must-Read: Paul Krugman: Will University Economics Departments Help Us Understand Business Cycles?”

Evening Must-Read: Contractionary Fiscal Policy Is Contractionary

Menzie Chinn: Econbrowser: Euro and Non-Euro Countries and Fiscal Policy:

Contractionary fiscal policy is… contractionary. There has been some dispute over the robustness of the findin… over the proper time horizon…. Here is the entire sample of advanced countries… cumulative growth rates 2009-13 plotted against cumulative change in the cyclically-adjusted budget balances…. The more contractionary the policy stance, the slower the growth…. It’s clear that eurozone countries are a special case, where monetary policy is out of the control of the individual countries; a question is whether countries with their own monetary policy could actually experience an expansionary fiscal contraction…. For the non-euro area group, the regression coefficient is less negative, and is only significant at the 17% marginal significance level…. See this New Palgrave Encyclopedia of Economics chapter for an examination of why one would expect to see relatively large multipliers in the current economic conditions of ZLB and excess capacity.

Evening Must-Read: Justin Wolfers Explains the Latest Chetty et al. Piece on Lack of Mobility

Justin Wolfers: Twitter / JustinWolfers: Explaining the big new Chetty…: “Explaining the big new Chetty mobility study:

  1. No change in odds of moving higher or lower on the economic ladder than your parents.

  2. But higher income inequality today means that the rungs of the income ladder are now much further apart than in the past.

  3. Consequences of the “birth lottery” are larger now, because low mobility has bigger consequences.

  4. Bottom line of mobility study: Kids, more than ever, be careful to choose the right parents.

A Mathematical Response to Scott Winship’s Analysis of The Great Gatsby Curve

While we know today’s big inequality and mobility news is Raj Chetty, Emmanuel Saez, and others’ new paper on variance in mobility over time — which we’ll be discussing shortly — we wanted to take a moment to look at the math behind some analysis derived from some of the previous data they have collected  from their Equality of Opportunity Project on variance in mobility over geography.

The “Great Gatsby Curve,” a term coined by Princeton economist Alan Krueger based on the work of Ottawa economist Miles Corak, shows that across developed countries, higher economic inequality is associated with lower mobility. This curve has sparked a great deal of debate particularly because the United States stands apart among the developed nations for its high inequality and low mobility.

In a recent foray into this debate, Manhattan Institute sociologist Scott Winship and Heritage Foundation research assistant Donald Schneider use data from the Equality of Opportunity Project to look at the relationship between inequality and mobility across U.S. “commuting zones,” which are groups of counties that form a common labor market. (The Equality of Opportunity Project assessed economic mobility by looking at the 2011-12 incomes of people born in 1980-82 and their parents’ incomes from 1996-2000.) Winship and Schneider conclude that this new data indicate that mobility is actually largely unrelated to economic inequality and that the core reason for low economic mobility is single motherhood.

I’ve reproduced their findings, but I don’t come to the same conclusions.  Winship and Schneider don’t weight the data properly and ignore too much of the data. Thus, I do not conclude that they provide compelling arguments to ignore economic inequality when discussing economic mobility.

Winship and Schneider use several data points to make their argument.  After showing that the share of households led by single mothers is negatively associated with mobility (very interesting but a little off topic), they reproduce the Great Gatsby curve for U.S. commuting zones.  They compare the difference between the income of families in a commuting zone’s 75th percentile and 25th percentile—also known as the interquartile range—with a measure of economic mobility.

Figure 1 shows the relationship Winship and Schneider plot between the interquartile income range and the gap in expected economic mobility between the children from the richest and poorest families, as measured by the difference in their expected adult income.  The upward sloping line was calculated using a simple regression and indicates that areas with larger income gaps among parents in 1996-2000 have larger income gaps between their children in 2011-12 (Note that children’s incomes are measured in 2011-2012, when they are about 30, and their parental incomes are also measured around 1996-2000, when the ‘children’ are 15-20, as explained in the second paragraph of this paper).

Figure 1: Income Concentration vs. Difference in Relative Mobility

Figure 1

Then Winship and Schneider move on to look at the top 1%. Here’s where I think their analysis really does not hold up.  First let me be clear about what Winship and Schneider mean by “We-are-the-99%” inequality.  They are referring to the fraction of a region’s total income that went to someone with an income in the top 1% nationally. Of the 741 commuting zones in the dataset, 629 had data on the share of the population in the national top 1% so commuting zones were omitted from the analysis. Figure 2 below replicates their “We-are-the-99%” plot in blue.

Figure 2: Income Concentration vs. Relative Mobility

Figure 2

Winship and Schneider’s analysis equally weighs each commuting zone for both the “We-are-the-99%” inequality measure and the interquartile range. Under their formulation, the Eagle Butte, South Dakota and Los Angeles, California commuting zones are equally weighted.

Winship and Schneider smartly turn their focus to the largest 100 commuting zones because two outliers were drove their “We-are-the-99%” findings. However, this means that they ignore more than 85% of the data.

Further, excluding all but the largest 100 commuting zones does not remove the weighting problem because the size of the top 100 zones still varies considerably.  The ratio between the population of the largest and smallest zones of the largest 100 is about 28:1 compared to 13,741:1 for the smallest of the whole set.  The best way to avoid this problem is to use population weights in the regression instead of simply ignoring more than 85% of the data. Specifically, we used a weighted least squares regression as implemented in both R and Stata.

When we use the correct weights, we find a different answer.  Population-weighted regressions find that the concentration of income in the top 1% is associated with larger gaps between mobility of children from lower- and higher-income families. The orange line in Figure 2 is the population-weighted line of best fit.

Unfortunately, Winship and Schneider spend less time looking into several other measures of economic mobility in the Equality of Opportunity Project data, including measures of absolute mobility and a second measure of relative mobility. The absolute mobility measure is the expected economic outcome for children in families with below the median income. The second measure of relative mobility is the likelihood that someone raised in the bottom quintile makes it to the top quintile.  By focusing on one of the relative mobility measures, they miss the other, stronger relationships.

All of these regression results are in Table 1.  For the absolute mobility, a negative coefficient indicates a lower income for children born to low-income families.  For the first relative mobility measure, a positive coefficient indicates larger gaps in income. In the second relative mobility measure, a positive coefficient means that fewer children from low-income families will make it to the top. The bottom line is that in each of these regressions higher inequality means lower economic mobility.

Table 1: Population-Weighted Regressions for Two Inequality Measures and Three Mobility Measures

Intercept p-value Coefficient p-value Adjusted R^2
Absolute Mobility vs. LN(IQR) 197.24 <0.001 -14.16 <0.001 0.2199
Relative Mobility vs. LN(IQR) -61.98 <0.001 8.67 <0.001 0.0598
Alt. Relative Mobility vs. LN(IQR) 123.41 <0.001 -10.46 <0.001 0.1593
Absolute Mobility vs. LN(1%) 39.87 <0.001 -1.39 <0.001 0.0371
Relative Mobility vs. LN(1%) 33.49 <0.001 0.58 0.083 0.0032
Alt. Relative Mobility vs. LN(1%) 6.72 <0.001 -1.15 <0.001 0.0336

Before making broad proclamations, it is important to understand the limitations in the data and the regressions.  While the coefficients are strongly statistically significant, most of these regressions explain only a small portion of the underlying variation in mobility between regions.  On the one hand, it shouldn’t be terribly surprising that a measure of inequality focusing on the top 1% is not a strong predictor of mobility measures that focus on quartiles. But, the issue may be data limitations.  Specifically, the data are only a snapshot of inequality and it would be useful to test these inequality measures over many years to determine the implications of inequality on mobility across a person’s lifetime.  Likewise, the data contained only mobility information for children born in 1980-82 and it would also be useful to test these results for more than a single cohort.

Winship and Schneider extend their weighting mistakes to their analysis of the size of the middle class and economic mobility. Winship and Schneider plotted the relationship for only the largest 100 commuting zones and claimed that it proved the size of the middle class does not matter for mobility.

As with the analysis above, a weighted regression has an important impact on the results for the size of the middle class, and each of the three economic mobility measures are in Table 2.  In each case, the size of the middle class is statistically significant and explains much of the variation in mobility.

Table 2: Population-Weighted Regression for the Size of the Middle Class and Three Mobility Measures

Intercept p-value Coefficient p-value Adjusted R^2
Absolute Mobility vs. Middle 19.38 <0.001 44.90 <0.001 0.4723
Relative Mobility vs. Middle 50.12 <0.001 -33.55 <0.001 0.1893
Alt. Relative Mobility vs. Middle -7.68 <0.001 32.55 <0.001 0.3293

While analysis of multiple measures of inequality and multiple measures of mobility suggest that economic inequality is negatively associated with economic mobility, much more analysis needs to be done to fully understand these complex relationships.  In particular, the mechanisms that drive these relationships should be understood.  I hope that this dispels some of the faulty analysis and encourages more rigorous analysis of these data.

Carter Price is a Senior Mathematician at the Washington Center for Equitable Growth.

Morning Must-Read: Mark Schmitt and Jared Bernstein on Why Inequality Is a Problem

Jared Bernstein: Mark Schmitt on Inequality:

Mark Schmitt…[:]

…it’s not that [inequality is] anything less than “the defining challenge of our time”…. Rather, it’s too defining, too large…. too sweeping and cluttered to lead to useful solutions….

Also… it’s not the case that any level of economic inequality is problematic. Every economic system distributes…. When someone raises the issue as problematic these days, they’re really saying something about historically high levels… [and] the impact of these levels on something else…

Continue reading “Morning Must-Read: Mark Schmitt and Jared Bernstein on Why Inequality Is a Problem”

Here’s to wishing you the best of luck in the birth lottery—you’re going to need it

Economists are always proving things my Grandmother already knew. Today, we’re learning more about the fact that where you’re born—the “birth lottery”—matters for where you’ll end up in life.

A new paper by economists Raj Chetty and Nathaniel Hendren of Harvard University, Patrick Kline and Emmanuel Saez of the University of California at Berkeley, and Nicholas Turner of the Treasury Department’s Office of Tax Analysis finds that even as inequality has risen sharply in the United States in recent decades, the chances of moving up (or down) the ladder have stayed about the same.

This research poses a challenge to the Great Gatsby Curve. This is a relationship between inequality and mobility showing that countries with greater inequality have less economic mobility. To be clear, the Great Gatsby Curve shows that countries with more inequality have less mobility; the new Chetty, et al. paper doesn’t challenge this. What the paper does is add new evidence—using tax records for cohorts going back to 1971—on changes in economic mobility. The United States still has higher inequality and less economic mobility than most other developed nations.

Chetty and Saez are on the Equitable Growth Steering Committee, so perhaps I’m a little biased, but my main take-away from this paper is that it’s an important contribution to the growing pile of knowledge we have about economic mobility. Knowing more about how adult children fare economically, relative to their parents, is an important economic and social issue. The American Dream hinges on the idea of upward mobility; it is part of the idea of what our nation is. We have evidence that economic mobility is lower in the United States than in most other developed countries. And recent research by Chetty and his co-authors finds that where you’re born within the United States matters: there is a high degree of variation in the chances of moving up depending on where you live.

But, while the paper sheds light on an important issue, it doesn’t put me in a good mood. The US economy grew by 217 percent between 1971 and 2012. We’ve lived through an era where we were told that if we left the market alone, we’d all benefit. Yet, what we’re learning today is that the gaps between the rungs of the ladder are further apart and that our chances of moving on up aren’t any better.

This paper leads to a number of new research questions. And, the authors are doing their part to encourage people to seek answers by making their data public, as they have with earlier datasets. In this batch, they are releasing data on mobility in multiple cohorts for every Commuting Zone in the United States. To understand the economy, we need data and these scholars are giving us thousands of new data points (hint: for anyone considering our request for proposals, we’d love to see ideas making use of these data!).

In terms of specific questions I’m left with after reading the paper, I’ll start with the tantalizing cliffhanger. The authors don’t yet have much income data for children born after 1986. As an interim measure, they look at college attendance rates. College attendance is correlated with later earnings, so this makes sense. But, of course, we don’t know yet what that relationship will look like for students who just graduated, especially for those starting their careers in the Great Recession.

Second, if Chetty and his co-authors are correct, the variation in intergenerational mobility is much greater within the United States than across time. In the United States, it matters more where you were born than when you were born. So, what are some places doing right (and what are others doing wrong)? What’s so special about Northern California or Salt Lake City?

And, how does the shape of the income distribution interact with economic mobility and what does really mean for all of us? Chetty and his co-authors point out that the relationship between inequality and economic mobility may be affected by what the income distribution looks like. When we look at how inequality has played out within the United States (and across the world), the story is very much about the top sliver pulling further and further apart. This leads us to the question: how does the top 1 percent pulling away affect mobility? And, how does this intersect with the growing stock of wealth those at the top command?

Difficulties of Having Policy Negotiations Today: Outsourced to Kevin Drum and David Weigel

Kevin Drum and David Weigel muse on the difficulties of conducting negotiations about public policy in Washington when the policy ideas proposed by Republican/Conservative intellectuals and politicians have as their principal goal to break the government:

Kevin Drum: Note to GOP: Don’t Reveal Your Fiendish Plan to Destroy Obamacare Until the Last Reel: “One of the reasons that insurers aren’t too worried about the low signup rate for Obamacare is… they figure things will work out eventually, and in the meantime they’re protected… [by] very wonky stuff designed to smooth the transition…

[But]… some bright spark decided that if you called this an “Obamacare bailout”… Republicans could even get it repealed, which in turn would make life so hard for insurers that they’d drop out of Obamacare entirely! Bwa-ha-ha! But their plan isn’t going anywhere, and Dave Weigel thinks it’s partly because conservatives have acted too much like a stock villain from a James Bond movie….

Continue reading “Difficulties of Having Policy Negotiations Today: Outsourced to Kevin Drum and David Weigel”

Things to Read on the Afternoon of January 22, 2014

Must-Reads:

  1. Claudia Goldin: Close the Gender Pay Gap, Change the Way We Work: “The gap increases with age… wage differences are concentrated within occupations…. The earnings gap is most pronounced in occupations such as law that place a premium on the willingness and ability to work long hours, be in the office at specific times, and build face-to-face relationships with co-workers and clients…. Consider the case of women with master degrees in business administration. At 10 to 16 years into their careers, they are typically earning only 55 percent of what men do. Child bearing is a primary reason for the divergence…. The huge value that so many employers place on a standard work schedule affects more than the careers of women. Anyone who, for whatever reason, needs to take time off or work flexible hours gets penalized…. To be sure, some professions may never be able to offer much flexibility…. [But] many professions that once tied people to specific hours are finding ways to reduce the cost of flexibility…. Not everyone stands to gain in a world of greater job flexibility. Some of those willing to sacrifice their lives to work might no longer be able to reap outsize rewards. In the interests of a happier, wealthier and more equitable society, though, that would be a small price to pay.”

  2. Washington Post: TwitLonger — When you talk too much for Twitter: “We regret to announce that Ezra Klein, Melissa Bell and Dylan Matthews are leaving The Post for a new venture. All three were instrumental in two of The Post’s most successful digital initiatives, Wonkblog and Know More. We plan to continue building those brands and expanding their reach, and we’ll have some exciting announcements related to them in the coming days…”

  3. Josh Barro: We Need A New Supply Side Economics: “Demand stimulation remains the right goal today, but it’s not going to be the right goal forever…. We’re going to need a new supply side economics that encourages people to work, invest and innovate…. [This] doesn’t mean an agenda of small-bore and meddlesome initiatives designed to promote specific industries, particularly manufacturing, as often described by President Barack Obama…. Invest in smart infrastructure…. Reform means-tested entitlements…. Move the deregulatory agenda down to the state and local level…. Deregulate America’s most overrated industry: real estate…. Reform intellectual property–by weakening it…. Improve education, somehow…. Admit more high-skill immigrants…. Make taxes more progressive. This isn’t a supply-side reform; in fact, it is likely to discourage investment and economic growth at the margin. But it’s the most effective way to offset rising pre-tax income inequality, and a revenue source will be needed to pay for some of the above reform ideas…”

  4. Ryan Avent: Secular stagnation: The second best solution: “Larry Summers has revived discussion in the ‘secular stagnation’ hypothesis. Income has become concentrated in… groups… with low propensities to [spend]… generat[ing] excess saving…. [One solution] is to raise inflation expectations in order to reduce real… interest rates…. Mr Summers’ preferred course of action…. It is a rare rich country that doesn’t have a list of infrastructure needs that could justifiably be addressed in the best of times. Pulling those off the shelf and taking them on amid rock-bottom interest rates and weak demand is a no-brainer…. Mr Summers reckons that while fiscal policy is the first best means to address stagnation, using higher inflation to reduce real interest rates and boost private demand is a clear second best…. My sense is that Mr Summers reckons the inflation strategy is not… easy to deploy successfully…. I often return to higher inflation as a strategy because something like Mr Summers’ five-year programme of deficit-financed public investment looks politically unachievable to me. Higher inflation, by contrast, is something the technocratic Fed could deliver…. But… central banks don’t generally propel economies out of slumps like these without significant political pressure being applied…”

  5. Timothy Jost: All posts by Timothy Jost on Health Affairs Blog: The most recent: “On January 15, 2014, the Affordable Care Act won a very important legal victory in Halbig v. Sebelius. Judge Paul Friedman of the District Court for the District of Columbia held that the ACA unambiguously supports an IRS regulation allowing the agency to issue premium tax credits to individuals enrolled through federal, as well as state, exchanges…”

Continue reading “Things to Read on the Afternoon of January 22, 2014”