Afternoon Must-Read: Bob Litan: Two Relatively Painless Ways to Boost Growth

Bob Litan:
Two Relatively Painless Ways to Boost Growth:
“The first… greatly boost the numbers of permanent work visas…

…(citizenship would be a plus) for high-skilled immigrants…. The second idea stems from the landmark decision by a California state court in June 2014, Vergara v. State of California, which held that the teacher unions’ tenure system violated the equal protection clause of the state’s constitution…. Students who are penalized by an educational system stacked against them virtually from the time they enter school until they graduate (or drop out, as all too many will), represent a huge waste of human capital…





A Question for William Gale: The Fiscal Outlook

In the United States today:

  • Debt held by the public is at 72.1% of a year’s GDP.
    • Debt held by the non-Federal Reserve public is at 59.2% of a year’s GDP.
  • The nominal net interest bill is at 1.3% of a year’s GDP.
    • The real net interest bill is at -0.14% of a year’s GDP–yes, right now holders of government bonds are paying the government to keep their money safe.
  • A large carbon tax to deal with global warming is coming–maybe in this decade, maybe next decade.
  • A huge shift in health-care financing that will move an enormous chunk of business payroll costs into the income and the social-insurance tax base is coming with the implementation of the Cadillac Tax of the ACA.
  • The ACA has also embarked us on a large number of experiments in the reasonable hope that some of them will prove effective at improving the efficiency of our health-care financing system and so reducing public health-care costs.
  • According to CBO’s extended-baseline, our long-term fiscal gap over 2015-2039 is 1.2% of GDP.

And yet in this situation William Gale thinks that “a major priority should be to get our long-term fiscal house in order…”

Why?

Why would anyone seek today to relatively downweight virtually any other economic policy priority in order to focus on the deficit–especially when you bear in mind that our political system seems to have a very difficult time focusing on the deficit in a constructive way, and that over the past six years its focus on the deficit has been the major source of economic policy dysfunction?

What is the logic here?

William Gale:
Get the Fiscal House in Order:
“The current debt-GDP ratio of 74 percent is far higher…

…than at any time in U.S. history except for a brief period around World War II…. The higher debt load will burden the economy in the future. Reasonable projections… indicate that the debt ratio will rise… to about 82 percent by 2024, about 100 percent by 2033 and 200 percent by 2059…. Uncertainty cuts both ways; we might also find debt significantly higher. After all, the budget projections assume there will be no recessions, no wars, and no new programs….

Rising long-term debt reduces prospects for future economic growth…. Sustained increases in federal deficits and debt reduce net national saving… less improvement in the quality and quantity of physical capital and possibly in human capital…. There is no economic model that suggests that sustained deficits and debt, where the spending is not all invested, would be anything but growth-retarding…. A number of studies suggest significant effects. Illustrative calculations by Greg Mankiw and Douglas Elmendorf suggest that a national debt of 50 percent of GDP reduces net output by more than 3 percent…. IMF researchers… for each additional 10 percentage points in the debt/GDP ratio, growth in subsequent years falls by 0.15 percentage points…. Congressional Budget Office… increasing deficits by $2 trillion over the next 10 years… would decrease GDP by 7.5 percent over 25 years….

Putting the four pieces of the puzzle together–that is, sustained deficits and debt will prove harmful, the burden of debt reduction should be placed largely on high-income households because they will garner most of the benefits, higher tax burdens are the only real way to get the wealthy to finance a significant portion of closing the fiscal gap, and higher tax burdens do not significantly slow the economy in the long run–leads directly to the conclusion that the bulk of the solution should come from higher taxes in general, and higher taxes on high-income households in particular… limiting the value of tax expenditures… value-added taxes and carbon taxes…





Morning Must-Read: Nicholas Bagley: Am I Unreasonable?

Nicholas Bagley: Am I unreasonable?: “To prevail, it’s not enough for the King challengers…

…to show that it’s possible to read the ACA to eliminate tax credits from states that refused to set up their own exchanges. They must also demonstrate that the ACA does so unambiguously—and that the IRS’s contrary interpretation is therefore unreasonable. Under Chevron, if the ACA could be read in a couple of different ways, the courts owe deference to the IRS’s authoritative decision about how best to read it.

I confess that I do think Nick Bagley is being unreasonable. They do not have to demonstrate that their reading of the ACA doesn’t apply. All they have to do is induce five justices not to apply Chevron. They don’t even have to offer them a reason to overrule Chevron–just not to apply it in this particular instance. The justices are good at that.

The behavioral barriers to paying off debt

Paying off debt is no easy feat, even for the most disciplined among us. It requires careful planning, forward vision, and financial endurance over long periods of time. Sadly, mishandling debt is becoming an increasingly common reality for many Americans, who have experienced an explosion in household debt over the past three decades. Not surprisingly, low-income families have been hit the hardest, with a quarter of these households spending 40 percent of their take-home pay on debt.

Yet for those whose incomes barely cover basic household needs, how does one pay off debt? Michael Barr, a University of Michigan Law School professor (and former U.S. Assistant Treasury Secretary for Financial Institutions) is seeking to better understand the debt management strategies of low- and moderate-income earners. Barr received one of Equitable Growth’s inaugural grants to identify the behavioral barriers among these households to reducing debt. He plans to use that information to design policies and interventions that help households in similar straits to manage their debt more efficiently.

Barr believes that many of the existing consumer financial products and services do not take into account the conditions of low-income households.  The lives of the poor are unstable, frequently defined by inflexible schedules, low-paying jobs, and meager savings for an emergency. Attempts to reduce the debt loads of these borrowers are further impeded by the fact that people are, well, human. Classical economic theory is based on the premise that we are rational beings, but in reality it is almost impossible for the majority of us to make the most economically optimal decisions, day after day.

For many people, those occasional “irrational” financial lapses (grabbing take-out when you could cook at home, for example) are relatively harmless. But for those with low incomes, such decisions can be a major impediment to achieving financial security. And, as Barr points out, the financial services intended to make savings easier are usually underutilized or unavailable to the poor.

Instead, many of these families “juggle” their debts. They pay the minimum amount necessary to avoid collection agencies or utility shut offs, without making progress toward actually paying the debts off. Furthermore, a study by Laura Tach of Cornell University and Sara Sternberg Green of Harvard University finds that many families view the idea of needing help—especially in the form of government assistance—as shameful.

Instead, these borrowers try to manage their debt in private in order to project a self-sufficient social identity, sometimes cutting themselves off from helpful resources and making their financial woes worse. Tach and Green find that once they framed debt payments in terms of achieving this identity, or as a means to upward mobility, many families were inspired to pay off their debt at all costs, even forgoing basic necessities to do so.

More research needs to be done to understand the full interaction between financial services and how low- and moderate-income families think about and pay off their debt. Barr’s pursuit of making consumer services more sensitive to the nuances of human behavior can help improve the financial stability of low- and moderate-income families, and the economy as a whole.

Things to Read on the Morning of December 2, 2014

Must- and Shall-Reads:

 

  1. Juan Carlos Suárez Serrato and Owen Zidar:
    Who Benefits from State Corporate Tax Cuts? A Local Labor Markets Approach with Heterogeneous Firms:
    “This paper estimates the incidence of state corporate taxes on the welfare of workers, landowners, and firm owners using variation in state corporate tax rates and apportionment rules. We develop a spatial equilibrium model with imperfectly mobile firms and workers. Firm owners may earn profits and be inframarginal in their location choices due to differences in location-specific productivities. We use the reduced-form effects of tax changes to identify and estimate incidence as well as the structural parameters governing these impacts. In contrast to standard open economy models, firm owners bear roughly 40% of the incidence, while workers and landowners bear 30-35% and 25-30%, respectively”
  2. Chris Rock:
    It’s Not Black People Who Have Progressed. It’s White People:
    “When we talk about race relations… it’s all nonsense. There are no race relations. White people were crazy. Now they’re not as crazy. To say that black people have made progress would be to say they deserve what happened to them before…. To say Obama is progress is saying that he’s the first black person that is qualified to be president. That’s not black progress. That’s white progress. There’ve been black people qualified to be president for hundreds of years. If you saw Tina Turner and Ike having a lovely breakfast over there, would you say their relationship’s improved?… A smart person would go, ‘Oh, he stopped punching her in the face.’… Ike and Tina Turner’s relationship has nothing to do with Tina Turner. Nothing. It just doesn’t. The question is, you know, my kids are smart, educated, beautiful, polite children. There have been smart, educated, beautiful, polite black children for hundreds of years. The advantage that my children have is that my children are encountering the nicest white people that America has ever produced. Let’s hope America keeps producing nicer white people…”
  3. Hiroshi Nakaso:
    The Potential Impact of Large-Scale Monetary Accommodation:
    “The Bank of Japan introduced the QQE to achieve the price stability target of 2 percent at the earliest possible time, with a time horizon of about two years… to dispel a view that… prices would not rise… to raise inflation expectations through a strong and clear commitment to achieve the price stability target of 2 percent, and at the same time to exert downward pressure across the entire yield curve through massive purchases of government bonds. As a result, real interest rates will decline, thereby stimulating such private demand components as business fixed investment, private consumption, and housing investment. The upward pressure on prices will grow stronger as demand increases and the output gap narrows accordingly. Rises in actual inflation rates will be translated into higher expected rates of inflation and thus lower real interest rates. This will reinforce the virtuous cycle as the economy is provided with additional stimulus. Since its inception, the QQE has been producing the intended effects…. In recent months, however… the decline in demand following the consumption tax hike has been somewhat protracted… crude oil prices have declined substantially… slowing the CPI inflation rates… down to 1.0 percent in September…. The temporary weakness in demand associated with the consumption tax hike has already started to wane. Meanwhile, the decline in crude oil prices will have positive effects on economic activity and push up prices over the longer-run. Nevertheless… we decided to take preemptive actions to expand the QQE at the Monetary Policy Meeting held on October 31…. I would like to address a frequently cited remark that unconventional monetary stimulus could destabilize financial markets and the economy at large by encouraging ‘search for yield’ activities…. A rise in asset prices and a decline in volatility are intended effects of the QQE…. [But] we should be mindful of the risk that ‘search for yield’ activities enter into a self-fulfilling cycle…. If a rise in asset prices creates overly bullish expectations among non-financial entities such as the corporate and household sectors, it could trigger excessive risk-taking behavior in these sectors as well. Thus far, we have not observed signs of self-fulfilling, overheated price movements…”
  4. Paul Krugman:
    Famous Fake Prediction Failures:
    Dean Baker is annoyed, and rightly so, at claims like this from Robert Samuelson that Keynesians failed to predict the slow recovery. Dean and I were both tearing our hair out in early 2009, warning that the Obama stimulus was too small and too short-lived…. Samuelson is taking the fact that this business cycle didn’t look like previous cycles as evidence that we don’t understand macroeconomics, so we shouldn’t even try to help the economy. But I was predicting a protracted jobless recovery long before the recession was official, and explained carefully why. But then I also fairly often get comments along the lines of ‘If you’re so smart, how come you didn’t see the housing bubble’, when I not only did see it (although Dean saw it much earlier), but got a lot of flak for daring to raise questions about the Bush Boom. Well, I guess you can’t expect people to be aware of what I was saying, seeing as how I only write for an obscure publication nobody has heard of.”
  5. Nick Bunker:
    Thanksgiving weekend reading – Washington Center for Equitable Growth: “Secular stagnation: Greg Ip argues that the growing tide of elderly in wealthy countries explains a lot of secular stagnation [the economist]. The Economist also created a series of accompanying graphics [the economist]. Shane Ferro looks at the troubling demographic situation in Japan [business insider]. Hidden wealth of nations: Matthew Klein looks at London School of Economics professor Gabriel Zucman’s research on the offshoring of wealth and profits [ft alphaville part 1, part 2]. The roots of upward mobility: Richard Reeves looks at research that finds a link between inequality of non-cognitive skills and intergenerational mobility [brookings]. Derek Thompson poses a dilemma for Millennials: move to a city with affordable housing or a city with a good track record of upward mobility [the atlantic]. More work and less play than expected: Dylan Matthews tries to figure out why we don’t have 3-hours workdays as Keynes predicted [vox]. Timothy Taylor considers two approaches to encouraging work: tax incentives and social support [conversable economist] :: Free exchange: No country for young people | The Economist | “Secular stagnation” in graphics: Doom and gloom | The Economist | How a Limo Ride With Paul Krugman Changed the Course of Abenomics – Bloomberg | The costs of offshore tax avoidance, part 1 | FT Alphaville | The costs of offshore tax avoidance, part 2 | FT Alphaville | The “Great Gatsby Curve” for Character Skills and Mobility | Brookings Institution | Why It’s So Hard for Millennials to Find a Place to Live and Work – The Atlantic | Why 3-hour workdays haven’t happened yet – Vox | CONVERSABLE ECONOMIST: Encouraging Work: Tax Incentives or Social Support?
  6. Tim Duy:
    Yes, I Am Optimistic:
    “As long as people have babies, capital depreciates, technology evolves, and tastes and preferences change, there is a powerful underlying (and under-appreciated) impetus for growth that is almost certain to reveal itself in any reasonably well-managed economy. This ultimately is the reason that despite the seemingly persistent belief that the recessionary bogeyman is just around the corner, recessions are remarkably rare events…. Bottom Line: Perhaps, just perhaps, the US economic expansion has been consistently undersold, and continues to be undersold. It is worth considering that maybe it is time to just accept the good news without the desperate search for every dark cloud.”
  7. Zeynep Tufekci:
    How TED (Really) Works: How One Hairdresser Behind the Scenes, and Émile Durkheim, Says More About TED than All the Viral Videos:
    “Check this Slate ad for a journalist who will write about education policy on the high-traffic site: no need to be an expert in the topic, just an interest in the beat, and the ability to write really fast (part-time, of course while you juggle other, likely unrelated, jobs)…. There are, of course, advantages to acquiring breadth as well as depth, as one should, but it still remains true: to do something well, you need to specialize, over time, and most organizations run on the fuel that is people dedicated to taking care of their corner. These people are rarely the ones on stage, or highlighted as interesting people, or celebrated as glamorous. It’s the nurse who really understands preemie babies, the electrician who takes care of the aging air-conditioning in the building that nobody else knows how to fix, and the programmer that makes the creaky legacy scheduling database work…. It’s why you can walk onto a big stage without having looked at a mirror, because you know you can trust the person whose job it is to take care of this. And the opposite is the anxiety we feel in situations where institutions don’t function as well, and where one keeps having to acquire competencies just to take care of basic functions: most places on the planet. The inability to trust this division of labor is among the most tiring aspects of living in less developed countries…. And my talk? Oh, it was about whether digital technology is helping social movements scale up without building deep organizations, and hence hitting the big time without the capacity to weather the challenges. So, yeah. Sometimes, the real magic is in the details, the specialization, and a division of labor you can rely on.”

Should Be Aware of:

 

  1. Amanda Marcotte:
    Don’t blame liberals for Elizabeth Lauten, the Obama daughters scold, resigning:
    “Liberals don’t have any power to force [Elizabeth] Lauten to resign nor do they have any power to make her Republican boss ask for her resignation. If Rep. Fincher wanted all this to blow over, it really would have…. I suspect Lauten had to go [because] she let the mask slip. Right now, there is a Republican full frontal assault on abortion rights and contraception access–which Rep. Fincher is a big part of–and Republicans are very touchy about this assault being called a ‘war on women’. They insist that attacks on abortion rights are supposedly about helping women and that the attacks on contraception access are about ‘religious freedom’ and that sexism and hostility towards female sexuality has nothing to do with it. Having some congressional staffer reveal that she thinks that you’re being immodest if you show your knees in public blows their cover and shows that nope, it’s all about their hysterical attitudes about women and sexuality…”
  2. Ed Kilgore:
    Bad Memories Down South:
    “I’ve just spent nearly a week back home in exurban Atlanta, and I regret to report that the events in and in reaction to Ferguson have brought back (at least in some of the older white folks I talked with) nasty and openly racist attitudes I haven’t heard expressed in so unguarded a manner since the 1970s… the intensity of the hostility I heard towards ‘the blacks’ (an inhibition against free use of the n-word, at least in semi-public, seems to be the only post-civil-rights taboo left), who have the outrageous temerity to protest an obvious act of self-defense by a police officer…. There seems to be a complete lack of reflection on the fact that it’s the black kid who is dead and the cop who is alive and free. This skewed perception of the equities of the matter is what most reminds me of the very bad old days back home…. I don’t know if the good conservative Christian white people of Georgia will eventually hold rallies to honor Darren Wilson the way they did for William Calley, but it would not surprise me at this point.”
  3. Kevin Drum:
    The Scary Mystery of Angela Merkel Is….Still a Mystery | Mother Jones:
    “Take the eurozone crisis, for example. Over the past five years, Germany has seemed almost spitefully hellbent on destroying the European economy simply because Germans disapprove of the spendthrift southerners responsible for the mess—all the time self-righteously refusing to admit that they themselves played a role that was every bit as lucrative and self-serving in the whole debacle. Because of this, the European economy is now headed for its third recession since 2008. Does Merkel share this view of things? Or does she recognize what needs to be done but simply doesn’t have either the will or the courage to challenge German public opinion? That’s never clear. And yes, I guess I find that a little scary. This is why I don’t quite get the comparison Packer makes between Merkel and Obama…. Personality-wise, perhaps, Obama and Merkel are similar. ‘No drama’ could apply equally well to either of them. But politically? I don’t see it. Obama doesn’t strike me as someone with no vision who hews as close as possible to public opinion.”

Thinking About Austerity in Britain: Daily Focus

Simon Wren-Lewis: Destroying the State is No Accident:
“Why do I think [that Osborne’s] sharp reduction in the size of the state in the UK is no accident?…

There is no sound macroeconomic case for a rapid reduction in the share of debt to GDP at a time when interest rates are still at or near their lower bound and there are risks to the recovery. So, if the macroeconomic argument for deficit reduction is unsound, there has to be another motive…. [And] why on earth has Ed Balls come to accept the austerity case?… Just think if Clement Attlee’s government at the end of the second world war had decided that the first priority was to reduce the debts built up during the war….

The reason for this about turn is of course mediamacro…. When the entire media jumps on your leader because he forgot the bit of his speech where he mentions the deficit, as a politician you are bound to conclude that the battle has been lost…. And please don’t say politicians who bow to this media pressure ‘lack courage’–a politician’s job is to win elections. The cock-up argument could respond that somehow the government has got trapped by its own rhetoric. It used the deficit line as an obvious stick with which to beat the opposition, but it has somehow got out of control….

Seven times as many people want higher taxes and spending than want lower taxes and spending. People like their NHS, they want resources put into state education, and pensions are also popular…. While people are clear about their preferences for public goods, they are not experts on macroeconomics. So when they are told that the deficit has to be reduced… they think about their own budgets and it makes sense. They remember the Eurozone crisis which involved governments not being able to sell their debt. Media myths have to come from half-truths…. The neoliberal force is strong with this government, and I see no reason to believe that does not also apply to their Chancellor and his macroeconomic policy.

Back at the start of the 1990s those of us in the Rubin wing of the Democratic Party who made deficit reduction our job number one–and who were willing to accede to one dollar of spending cuts in return for each dollar of tax increases–did so for two reasons:

First, we did so because we saw the large deficits created by the Reagan-Bush 41 administrations as a very damaging to America. We saw them, I still believe correctly, robbing us of more than 0.5%/year of economic growth via the higher real interest rates and the dollar cycle-induced hollowing-out of America’s manufacturing communities of technical practice. America in 1992 thus looked to us to be 6% poorer than if the Reagan-Bush 41 administrations had followed the economic policies of an Eisenhower.

Second, we did so because we also thought we saw signs over 1990-1992 that US was reaching the edge of the limits of its debt capacity, and that a failure to demonstrate that the political system could put the debt back on the sustainable trajectory might turn us not into Argentina but into an economy in which the annual costs of demonstrating to the bottom market that we were not Argentina would become substantial. In view of the extraordinary demand for the debt of the US government and of the other sovereigns with the exorbitant privilege of printing reserve currencies out of thin air that we have seen over the past decade, that second now needs considerable rethinking–it was probably a mirage, a misreading of the causes of the high real interest rates of the late-1980s and early-1990s.

Be that as it may, the macroeconomic policies of the early Clinton Administration were still an astonishing success: a strong, high-investment recovery advancing in time and strengthening the dot-com boom that paid enormous dividends to the US and to the world economy as a whole even as it took $4 trillion away from investors in the bubble.

Now, of course, things are very different than they were at the start of the 1990s. There is no warrant anywhere in financial markets for any belief that Germany (the Euro), Britain, or the US is anywhere close to its debt capacity. At current low interest rates there is every reason for reserve currency-printing sovereigns with exorbitant privilege to borrow and spend at least until the interest rates and inflation rates are normalized, and substantial reason to continue such policies a little later in order to acquire a credible reputation that they will be similarly irresponsible what should the liquidity trap come again.

Yet Ed Balls is not making the technocratic macroeconomic argument for a higher government spending now. And he is not making the technocratic public-finance political-economy argument that the rightsizing of the public sector will require a larger share of GDP for government in the 21st century than we have seen in the 20th. Education, pensions, healthcare, research and development, infrastructure, defense, and information goods are none of them optimally provided by a lightly-regulated market. And all of these, save (we hope) defense, loom larger in the 21st century than they loomed in the 20th. Wherefore then the belief that shrinking the state is a good thing?

The Cato Institute’s Brink Lindsey Is Running an Economic Growth Conference This Week: The Honest Broker for the Week of November 21, 2014

RE: The Future of U.S. Economic Growth & Reviving Economic Growth: A Cato Online Forum

Some questions for the authors of the contributions that struck me as the most interesting…

Two Questions for Scott Sumner: First Question: Why has nominal GDP targeting not already swept the economics community? It really ought to have. Second Question: I believe in nominal GDP targeting–especially if coupled with some version of “social credit” at or near the zero lower bound. But a look back at the history of ideas about a proper “neutral” monetary policy–Newton’s fixed price of gold, Hayek’s fixed nominal GDP level, Fisher’s fixed price-level commodity basket, Friedman’s stable M2 growth rate, the NAIRU targeting of the 1970s, Bernanke’s inflation-targeting—leads immediately to the conclusion that anybody who claims to have uncovered the Philosopher’s Stone here is a madman. How can you reassure me that I (and you) are not mad?

Scott Sumner:
More Bang for the Buck: A Surprisingly Cost-Effective Way to Boost Growth:
“I would certainly not claim that monetary policy is the most important determinant…

…of the long-run growth rate in the economy…. But it does offer one of the cheapest ways of boosting growth. Unlike fiscal programs such as infrastructure, there is virtually no cost to improving monetary policy…. Elsewhere (2014) I’ve argued that a policy of nominal GDP targeting would smooth out the business cycle and undercut many of the arguments for counterproductive policies…. We need to convince other economists that nominal GDP targeting is the way to go. Once we do so, the Fed will follow the consensus.


One Question for Michael Strain: Back in the first Clinton administration, the EITC for childless workers was one of the things that dropped out of the 1993 budget given the decision that we had to hit our $500 billion five-year deficit reduction score and the defection of the oil patch Democratic senators over the BTU tax. Nobody since has wanted to put it back on the table. Why not?

Michael Strain:
Getting back to Work:
“Tt is a safe bet that one reason fewer men are working…

…is that real wages for male workers without a college degree have been stagnant or falling for decades. So my second policy suggestion is to expand the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) for childless workers, many of whom are low-income men. The EITC is a federal earnings subsidy: if you work, and if you earn less than a certain amount, then the government will supplement your earnings with a transfer payment. The EITC offers very little support for childless workers, with a maximum credit of only about five-hundred dollars. This amount should be significantly expanded, as both President Obama and Rep. Paul Ryan have suggested. Previous expansions of the EITC have lifted millions out of poverty, and are designed to incentivize nonparticipants to return to the workforce. When they do, everyone wins–the economy has more workers and can produce more goods and services, and the new participants can earn their own success in the labor market, leading flourishing lives that include the dignity only work can provide.


One Question for Jeff Miron: The Affordable Care Act took at $800 billion ten-year whack at Medicare cost growth, included every administrative and organizational reform David Cutler could think of that might increase incentives for efficient delivery of care, made it much easier for insurance companies to offer and for individuals to purchase high-deductible and high-copay plans, and–in the Cadillac Tax–started a process that Peter Orszag and Christina Romer dearly hope will produce a very substantial cutback in the tax preference for employer-sponsored health insurance. Yet you are not out there saying: we need to build on the cost-containment and efficiency-enhancing aspects of ObamaCare. Why not?

Jeff Miron:
Curtailing Subsidies for Health Insurance:
“The U.S. has two paths to avoid the fiscal crisis…

…implied by current health insurance subsidies. The bigger government approach is to impose more restrictive price and quantity controls in Medicare and Obamacare…. The smaller government approach is to scale back Medicare and Obamacare. The most aggressive ‘reform’ would eliminate any federal role in subsidizing health insurance, leaving such policies to the states. Since the federal tax burden would fall dramatically, states could more easily raise taxes to finance these programs…. A less aggressive ‘reform’ is higher deductibles and co-pays in Medicare and Obamacare…


One Question for Alan Viard: How much of the efficiency gains from moving to a consumption tax come from the fact that it is also a lump-sum tax on current wealthholders? It taxes not just the income from their capital, but the capital itself as it has spent. Is this low-hanging fruit because this is a credible way of taxing existing wealthholders once while promising never to do it again? And is this in fact a credible way to do this?

Alan Viard:
Move to a Progressive Consumption Tax:
“As mentioned above, consumption taxation…

…does not penalize saving. Replacing income taxation with consumption taxation would therefore be beneficial…. The greatest gains could be achieved by replacing the entire income tax system (the individual and corporate income taxes, the unearned income Medicare contribution, and the estate and gift tax) with a consumption tax. For distributional reasons, though, the consumption tax would need to be progressive, rather than a regressive tax like the VAT….Households would report their income on annual tax returns, but would then claim a full deduction for all saving and add back in any dissaving.

One Question for Ramesh Ponnuru: The entertainment industry likes copyrights. But the high-tech industry does not like patent trolls. I can understand–given the Democratic Party’s dependence for its elite fund-raising on Hollywood, the trial lawyers, the traditionally-Jewish investment banks, and Silicon Valley–why causes like copyright reform and tort reform have so little traction within the set of Democratic office-holders. But what, in your view, has gone wrong with patent reform? Why hasn’t patent reform low-hanging bipartisan fruit?


Ramesh Ponnuru:
Taxes, Patents, and Money:
“My top priority in reforming business taxation…

…would be to allow companies to write off the full cost of an investment in the year it incurred the expense, while scaling back the tax break for corporate interest payments…. Low-quality patents on software and business methods appear to have generated a lot of rent-seeking litigation…. The Fed [should] adopt–or be instructed by Congress to adopt–a target path for nominal spending…


One Question for Heather Boushey: As things are, our small-business owners are an exploited class in America today. Overoptimistic, they work long hours for highly variable and relatively low average incomes and in the process provide a lot of opportunities for employment to those they hire. Minimizing additional regulatory burdens on this class seems a good thing. Yet I am finding it hard to see how to craft a paid leave program in a way that does this. Might it not be better to focus on how to help people reenter employment when they return from leave?

Heather Boushey:
To Grow Our Economy, Start with Paid Leave: “First, our proposed paid leave program…

…like any social insurance program, should be available to all workers, including small business employees and the self-employed. Excluding a certain group from taking leave only exacerbates the gap between those who provide care and those who do not. Second, eligibility should be tied to lifetime work history rather than current employment or job tenure. A paid leave program should follow the model of other social insurance programs, such as Social Security Disability Insurance, which bases eligibility on employment history and payment into the system. Third, a national paid leave program should provide a reasonable amount of leave to all workers. Policymakers can follow the lead of the Family and Medical Leave Act, which provides 12 weeks of leave, or 60 workdays, per year. Fourth, paid leave salaries need to be generous enough so workers, especially low-wage workers, won’t jeopardize their economic security by taking leave. We can follow what has worked at the state level. Policymakers can set benefit levels at two-thirds of a worker’s weekly average wage as in New Jersey, and cap them up to a certain amount, as in California.


Two Questions for Stephen Teles: How much of this rent-seeking can be addressed at the federal level, and how much requires fifty–or a hundred–state-level think tanks willing to make the case for efficiency and enterprise? And why, in an era where unions get little political respect and have little ability to utilize the powerful protections provided by the NLRA, have those seeking a rent wedge via occupational licensing done so well?

Stephen Teles:
Restrain Regressive Rent-Seeking:
“We often talk about the last third of a century as an era of deregulation….

…But the most important market rigidities that have been eliminated have been those that protected those from the middle class on down. In fact, the great paradox of the last third of a century is that we have actually had an explosion of regulation in this ‘supposedly deregulatory’ era… regulation that has the effect of redistributing, sometimes dramatically, upward…. Intellectual property… occupational licensing… the financial sector…. A focus on rent-seeking allows us to look at the American inequality problem with a different lens….

The image of the U.S. as a free-market paradise is hard to square with the presence in the top income strata of people like car dealers (protected by regulations against the consolidation of car sales), doctors (protected by medical licensing and extensive educational requirements), lawyers (with a limited supply of lawyers and a government that produces outsized demand for their services), government contractors (including private prison managers, defense contractors, for-profit colleges and others whose almost exclusive dependence on government revenue raises question about whether they are ‘private’ in any meaningful sense), and property developers (who in many urban areas can exploit government-constrained ability to build—which drives up prices — and political connections to generate oversized profits). Add in finance, licensed occupations, and sectors with lots of intellectual property, and you’re looking at a sizeable chunk of the 1 percent….

Putting a dent in rent seeking… requires that someone be willing to subsidize ‘third party’ political activity, and for good or ill that must start with deep-pocketed donors willing to use their money to compensate for the imbalance of organization and attention that is the lifeblood of rents…. It may be impossible to organize a broad, deeply mobilized grassroots coalition against upward-redistributing rent seeking. But in most cases, equaling the manpower and resources of the rent-seekers isn’t necessary–just making sure that there is someone on the other side can make a big difference…


One Question for Ryan Avent: What are these local-area “institutional reforms” to overcome NIMBYism? In California, I know that every local elected official curses the Jarvis-Gann Proposition 13 as preventing them from recouping enough via property tax revenue to offset the costs of providing services to a new development, thus changing local governmental officials from reliable boosters for their town to grinches suspicious of every project. Are we looking for a federal government carrot to allocate funds county-by-county based on population growth? Or what?

Ryan Avent:
How Land-Use Restrictions Block Growth:
“infrastructure alone will not solve the problem…

…Instead, metropolitan areas may need institutional reforms that better balance the economic interests of the metropolitan area (and the country as a whole) with the interests and preferences of those living in neighborhoods that are likely to be affected by new development. When land-use decisions are made at a hyper-local level–giving local councilmembers or commissions extensive influence over which projects are approved, or focusing negotiation between residents and developers at the street level rather than the metropolitan level–the result will typically be far too little development. Those living immediately around a project enjoy some of its benefits but bear nearly all of its costs, in terms of disruption and congestion; they are therefore highly motivated to block projects and can succeed when local institutions enable them.


One Question for Morris Kleiner: I find that 15% licensing premium huge when I consider that it applies to a great many occupations in which licensing requirements are minimally burdensome–little more than what is called for in order to learn how to do the job. How is it that licensing requirements that do not look burdensome prima facie appear to be substantial burdens and restrictions on entry in fact?

Morris Kleiner:
Our Guild-Ridden Labor Market | Cato Institute:
“The number of persons in licensed professions in the U.S….

…has grown from around 5 percent in the early 1950s to almost 29 percent in 2009. More than 800 occupations are licensed in at least one state (Kleiner and Krueger, 2013). However, my research with Princeton economist Alan Krueger, former head of President Obama’s Council of Economic Advisers shows that licensing raises wages by about 15 percent even when controlling for human capital variables such as age, education, and other labor market characteristics. This is largely due to the ability of regulated professions working through state legislators and regulatory boards to limit the supply of practitioners and eventually drive up costs to consumers and some perception that licensing enhances the quality of the service.


One Question for Don Peck: I have always found the argument of Naomi Cahn and June Carbone’s Red Families, Blue Families convincing here. Four big changes have hit American families over the past two generations: effective fertility control, the post-baby boom reduction in desired family size, the end of economic patriarchy in the form of solid career ladders for blue-collar men, and the opening-up of workforce opportunities to women. In this context, those embedded in a cultural matrix that aggressively encourages women to take control of their fertility, postpone childbearing and marriage until their late 20s or longer, and look for an equal partner find a relatively good fit. Those embedded in an alternative cultural matrix find a much worse fit–a cultural matrix that puts forth an eighteen year-old unattached single mother as an abstinence spokesperson, writes about Sandra Fluke as “ex-crazed co-eds going broke buying birth control, student tells Pelosi hearing touting freebie mandate”, and loads economic expectations of earning power that cannot be met onto young not-well-educated men places people under immense stress. Isn’t the answer to your Gordian knot of issues going to be that we need to up value the “Blue State” culture that has emerged in our era of the pill, feminism, and globalization, and downvalue “Red State” culture?

Don Peck:
Shoring up the Middle Class:
“I’d like to address… the cultural, economic, and familial dysfunction…

…that is steadily climbing from the lowest socio-economic classes into the broad American middle class…. As the sociologist W. Brad Wilcox writes, ‘the family lives of today’s moderately educated Americans increasingly resemble those of high-school dropouts, too often burdened by financial stress, partner conflict, single parenting, and troubled children.’… Among moderately educated women, 44 percent of all births occurred outside marriage… families of high-school graduates coming to look like those of high-school dropouts, rather than those of college graduates… the percentage of 14-year-old girls living with both their mother and father; the percentage of adolescents wanting to attend college ‘very much’; the percentage of adolescents who say they’d be embarrassed if they got (or got someone) pregnant; the percentage of never-married young adults using birth control all the time. Wilcox is hardly alone in noticing this trend. It has been documented, exhaustively, by scholars across the ideological spectrum…


One Question for Donald Marron: As you know, cap-and-trade looks like a carbon tax coupled with a substantial redistribution of the present value of a substantial chunk of the future carbon tax revenues to current energy producers. In a world in which it is reasonable to expect the next two generations to see disruptive innovations in energy, this redistribution enriches those who hold current market share and imposes a tax on future more-nimble more-innovative entrants and competitors. From a political economy standpoint, therefore, cap-and-trade–the McCain 2008 environmental policy–ought to have been irrestible. Yet it was resisted, very strongly. Why?

Donald Marron:
Bigger, Cleaner, and More Efficient: A Carbon-Corporate Tax Swap | Cato Institute:
“The United States could reduce its contribution to global climate change…

…and increase domestic prosperity by taxing emissions of carbon dioxide and other greenhouse gases and using the resulting revenue to reduce corporate income taxes. Such a carbon-corporate tax swap would give us a bigger, cleaner economy and avoid any need for more costly efforts to reduce emissions…


A Question for Tyler Cowen: Haven’t we gotten foreign policy right since World War II, more or less? Haven’t we created a world in which everyone save for the oligarchs of Muscovy and the princes and princelings of China wishes that their country was more like ours, and hopes that their grandchildren will have the option to move here if they want? What could we have done better over the past fifty years–aside from a lamentable tendency to think that right-dictatorships are more likely to evolve into democracies than left-dictatorships, that our soldiers can train “third forces” that will stand up on battlefields, and that we can intervene to both make people, in Woodrow Wilson’s words, “elect good men” and to make those we imagine are democracy-minded strongmen actually hold fair and honest elections?

Tyler Cowen:
The Primacy of Foreign Policy:
“I’m not going to try to solve these conundrums…

…iI’ll simply put it this way: the single most important thing we can do to boost long-run American growth is to get foreign policy right. Very literally our lives, and the lives of many others, depend on it. And that means the economists aren’t nearly as important as they like to think they are.


2964 words

Pulling up the “job ladder”

Economic recessions are bad for everyone. Unemployment spikes, wage growth slows, investors suffer losses as stock and bond markets reel, and businesses fail. But economists have long seen a silver lining in economic downturns. Joseph Schumpeter famously wrote of “creative destruction,” where the destruction of job and firms help more efficient firms spring up, boosting long-run economic growth. Some economists also talk about the “cleansing effect” of recessions. Yet a new working paper released by National Bureau of Economic Research shows that this silver lining is quite thin, particularly when it comes to workers.

The authors of the paper, Yale University’s Lisa B. Kahn and the U.S. Census Bureau’s Erika McEntarfer, look at data linking employees to employers to better understand changes in the movement of workers during recessions and booms. The first trend they note is that employment at high- and low-paying firms expand and contract in different patterns. The expansion of high-paying firms is quite pro-cyclical, meaning they expand quickly as the overall economy does, and contract during recessions. Low-paying firms are less sensitive to the fluctuations of the overall economy. The result is that the average “quality” of employers, measured by how much they pay their workers, declines during recessions.

At the same time, Kahn and McEntarfer look at the movement of workers at the different types of firms. They find that pro-cyclical, high-paying firms are more likely to have workers leave the firm compared to low-paying firms. In fact, low-paying firms are less likely to have workers separate during recessions. This decline in separations is the reason why low-paying firms have relatively stronger employment growth during economic recessions. These firms aren’t hiring more workers, they are just retaining more of them. The authors find evidence that the decline in separations at low-paying firms is primarily driven by a decline in “voluntary separations,” better known as quitting a job.

So if low-paying firms don’t contract as much during recessions because workers are less likely to quit, then the idea that recessions improve the allocation of workers to companies seems unlikely. Unless we think all workers at low-paying firms at the beginning of a recession are ideally matched with their employers, then the downturn is holding back the advancement of workers.

Basically, the two authors find what economists call the “job ladder”— the ability of workers to move onto higher-paying companies —is pulled up during recessions.

Kahn and McEntarfer document that workers at low-paying firms are 20 percent less likely to advance to higher-paying firms during a recession than during an economic boom. And workers that get a job during a recession are likely to pay a wage penalty. These workers are more likely to get a job with a low-paying firm and, according to the authors’ calculations, a worker will be at a firm that pays about 3 percent less on average than if she had gotten a job during an economic boom.

Rather than cleanse the economy, recessions actually restrict workers from advancing to jobs that are better matches. And the loss isn’t just for the worker who makes less but for the overall economy as well. Workers who are better matched to the demands of their jobs will be more productive and therefore boost overall productivity. Kahn and McEntarfer’s paper is another reminder that the line between the short- and the long-run consequences of economic recessions can be quite blurry.

Afternoon Must-Read: Zeynep Tufkeci: How TED (Really) Works

Zeynep Tufekci:
How TED (Really) Works: How One Hairdresser Behind the Scenes, and Émile Durkheim, Says More About TED than All the Viral Videos:
“Check this Slate ad for a journalist…

…who will write about education policy on the high-traffic site: no need to be an expert in the topic, just an interest in the beat, and the ability to write really fast (part-time, of course while you juggle other, likely unrelated, jobs)…. There are, of course, advantages to acquiring breadth as well as depth, as one should, but it still remains true: to do something well, you need to specialize, over time, and most organizations run on the fuel that is people dedicated to taking care of their corner. These people are rarely the ones on stage, or highlighted as interesting people, or celebrated as glamorous. It’s the nurse who really understands preemie babies, the electrician who takes care of the aging air-conditioning in the building that nobody else knows how to fix, and the programmer that makes the creaky legacy scheduling database work….

It’s why you can walk onto a big stage without having looked at a mirror, because you know you can trust the person whose job it is to take care of this. And the opposite is the anxiety we feel in situations where institutions don’t function as well, and where one keeps having to acquire competencies just to take care of basic functions: most places on the planet. The inability to trust this division of labor is among the most tiring aspects of living in less developed countries…. And my talk? Oh, it was about whether digital technology is helping social movements scale up without building deep organizations, and hence hitting the big time without the capacity to weather the challenges. So, yeah. Sometimes, the real magic is in the details, the specialization, and a division of labor you can rely on.

This is, I think, one of the big reasons why nobody is willing to pay $400 million for a Slate: an organization that is willing to pay for contrarian snark but that does not value subject-matter expertise is not an organization likely to last. By contrast, http://vox.com is focused on having excellent writers and excellent subject matter expertise in the same package, and is likely to grow.

But yes: plugging your market interface into a finely-graded division of labor populated by true experts and building your own expert division of labor where you cannot plug into the market’s is the key to turning even the best entrepreneurial idea into something of enduring value. As far as the interfaces are concerned, it is both locating in the right place and ensuring you have the right conductivity. As far as the internals are concerned, it is sweating the small stuff–and being willing to pay for quality.

Lunchtime Must-Read: Juan Carlos Suárez Serrato and Owen Zidar: Who Benefits from State Corporate Tax Cuts? A Local Labor Markets Approach with Heterogeneous Firms

Juan Carlos Suárez Serrato and Owen Zidar:
Who Benefits from State Corporate Tax Cuts? A Local Labor Markets Approach with Heterogeneous Firms:
“This paper estimates the incidence of state corporate taxes…

…on the welfare of workers, landowners, and firm owners using variation in state corporate tax rates and apportionment rules. We develop a spatial equilibrium model with imperfectly mobile firms and workers. Firm owners may earn profits and be inframarginal in their location choices due to differences in location-specific productivities. We use the reduced-form effects of tax changes to identify and estimate incidence as well as the structural parameters governing these impacts. In contrast to standard open economy models, firm owners bear roughly 40% of the incidence, while workers and landowners bear 30-35% and 25-30%, respectively