Must-Read: Thomas Palley: The New Economics of Trade

Must-Read: A couple of decades ago Paul Krugman wrote a very nice little book about why one reason that exchange rates swung so much and yet industrial locations were so persistent was because of the huge costs to any really existing multinational of actually moving production from one continent to another. Now Thomas Palley points out that this is not nearly as true as it used to be for production (although not for design, marketing, etc.). So what are the implications for equitable growth?

Thomas Palley: The New Economics of Trade: “Jack Welch… talked of ideally having ‘every plant you own on a barge”… [to] float between countries to take advantage of lowest costs…

…be they due to under-valued exchange rates, low taxes, subsidies, or a surfeit of cheap labor. Globalization has made Welch’s barge a reality… made capital mobility rather than country comparative advantage the engine of trade…. The U.S. and European response to Welch’s barge has been competitiveness policy that advocates measures such as increased education spending to improve skills; lower corporate tax rates; and investment and R&D incentives. The thinking is increased competitiveness can make Europe and the US more attractive to businesses. Unfortunately, competitiveness policy is not up to the task of anchoring the barge, and it can even be counter-productive….

The emergence of barge-like corporations has reduced the scope for effective competitiveness policy… and created a wedge between corporate and national interests…. Addressing globalization’s challenges poses enormous analytical difficulties. Unfair competition must be prevented and companies re-anchored. But this must be done without losing the benefits of real trade based on comparative advantage or ending investment that fosters development. These economic challenges are compounded by political difficulties… elite policy thinking… funded and lobbied for by corporations…. Fifty years ago what was good for GM may really have been good for the US. With Jack Welch’s barge, that may no longer hold.

In Which I Agree in Part and Dissent in Part with Paul Romer’s Narrative of the Intellectual Collapse of Chicago-School Macro

Paul Romer has a long post that seems to me to get some elements of the story right, some elements of the story wrong, and to miss some elements of the story completely:

Paul Romer: What Went Wrong in Macro–Historical Details: “During my time at MIT, Robert Solow was harshly critical…

…of the new classical macro models pioneered by Robert Lucas, dismissive in a way that seemed to me to skirt uncomfortably close contempt. I recall hearing the same type of criticism from Frank Hahn…. If it sounded like contempt to me, others may have heard it the same way.

At this point, Romer should say what Solow’s and Hahn’s criticisms were ca. my freshman college year 1978-1979. The argument, as I remember it, went like this:

  1. Lucas dismisses models that said that ,for institutional, behavioral, psychological, and historical reasons outside the model, prices are slow to adjust as ad hoc: he says that the patterns of and reasons for price adjustment durations need to be built in the model.

  2. Lucas proposes models that say that, for no reason at all, prices are slow to adjust because people cannot open the newspaper to read the inflation report.

  3. Lucas’s models do not fit the data. The most that can be said of them is that if you stringently restrict the set of allowable tests you might be able to fail to reject them at the 0.05 level if you give them the initial high ground of the null hypothesis.

And, at this point, Romer ought to say that Solow’s and Hahn’s criticisms were (a) no more biting in their rhetoric than the criticisms that Stigler, Friedman, and company had been inflicting on their victims at Chicago for a generation, and (b) correct and accurate. He ought to say that Lucas, too, eventually said that his proposed mechanism–that “surprises” in the prices they were offered on the market led them to misperceive their real terms-of-trade–simply did not work theoretically. And Romer ought to say that the evidence that Lucas’s mechanism simply did not work had emerged even while Romer was still in graduate school:

Robert Lucas: Monetary Neutrality: “In the models in Lucas (1972) and (1973), trade takes place in competitive markets…

…though these markets are incomplete, so any real effects of monetary policy need to work through movements in prices. The tests de-scribed in the last paragraph do not use data on prices and so do not test this prediction. Other econometric work that did require money shocks to be transmitted through price movements was much less favorable. Estimates in Sargent (1976) and in Leiderman (1979) indicated that only small fractions of output variability can be accounted for by unexpected price movements. Though the evidence seems to show that monetary surprises have real effects, they do not seem to be transmitted through price surprises, as in Lucas (1972).

And it would be nice if Paul Romer also acknowledged that, in his Nobel lecture, Lucas finally admitted that the bad ad hoc sticky-price assumption was no less microfounded than Lucas’s good ad hoc people-cannot-open-the-newspaper-to-read-the-price-level assumption:

One such… described in Lucas (1972)… was based on suppliers’ imperfect information…. Some of… assum[ed] that some nominal prices are set in advance, as in Fischer (1977), Phelps and Taylor (1977), Taylor (1979), or Svensson (1986)…. All… offer rationalizations of a short-run monetary non-neutrality…. None of these models deduces the function f from assumptions on technology and preferences alone… [but also from] the specific assumptions one makes about the strategies available to the players, the timing of moves, how information is revealed, and so on. Moreover, these specifics are all, for the sake of tractability, highly unrealistic and stylized: We cannot choose among them on the basis of descriptive realism…

In short, Romer ought, at this point, to say, simply: Solow and Hahn were right. He does not. Instead, he says:

Solow also seemed to be motivated to attack harshly because he was concerned that the type of model Lucas was developing might undermine political support for active countercyclical policy. To his credit, there was a legitimate basis for this concern…. But… in retrospect, if the goal was to maintain support for active macro policy, the better course would have been to take seriously what the rebel group that was forming around Lucas was saying. This might have kept the rebels from cutting off contact with all outsiders…

As Matthew Shapiro has frequently pointed-out, the cutting-off of contact went only one way. Saltwater economists kept on reading, assigning their students, borrowing from, and reacting to New Classical models. Freshwater economists, however, by and large did not assign what became known as New Keynesian work to their students, in large part did not borrow from and react to it, and so we get situations like Robert Lucas in 2009 having absolutely no understanding of what Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996) had taught everyone who had kept up with the literature about fiscal policy.

Romer continues:

Once they cut off contact with the outside, these rebels developed a sub-culture that was more like what you’d expect to find among members of a platoon on the battlefield than among scientists parsing logic and weighing evidence. Loyalty and group cohesion took priority, so models that were illogical or inconsistent with the evidence went unchallenged. These values might have developed in any department, but they found support and encouragement at the University of Chicago, which was already committed to Stigler conviction instead of Feynman integrity. As a result, real business cycle models, which were introduced by Prescott and Kydland in 1979, attracted support among the rebels, even though these models did an even worse job of matching the empirical evidence than the model that Lucas first proposed…. assumed away the possibility that monetary policy and inflation could have any interaction with output and employment… decided that econometrics was getting in the way. Word came down from the top that they were abandoning the cutting-edge econometric work that Sargent had specialized in and using calibration in its place….

The alternative to derision would have been for skeptics to embrace and extend. This was what Stan Fischer and Rudi Dornbusch, who were supervising almost all of the Ph.D. students at MIT doing anything related to macro, were quietly doing at this time…. Fischer and Dornbusch trained a cohort of Ph.D. students at MIT who put the tools of modern macro to work and, as Krugman has observed, turned out to be unusually influential…

Perhaps Stan was doing so quietly. Rudi never did anything quietly. Rudi was constitutionally incapable of ever doing anything “quietly”. He was the kind of person who would dismiss a paper of Allan Meltzer’s in public as “Tobin, plus original errors”. In Rudi’s view, rational expectations was a superb modeling tool for many problems, a very useful tool that allowed for enormous amounts of simplification while not forcing your conclusions into an unwanted and unwarranted coneptual Prokrustean box for many other problems, and a bonkers stupid assumption in some others. And he made that very clear. In Rudi’s view, Lucas’s people-cannot-open-the-newspaper assumption was silly, but as long as it was innocuous you should use it because it would help you communicate with more people–yet whenever it turned out not to be innocuous, but to instead be making you say something stupid, you should, of course, drop it immediately.

Romer continues:

If Dornbusch and Fischer had set the tone for the response to Lucas and his followers things might have turned out differently…

But they did set the tone! As Romer writes immediately, in the next paragraph:

The rebels… won the battle for mindshare among the next generation of macroeconomists… could have taken credit for killing off the large multi-equation models…. Lucas could have been embraced as a leading contributor to the larger intellectual program launched by Paul Samuelson, the founder of the department [at MIT]… could… have healed the divide that had separated MIT and Chicago… [with] its roots in Stigler’s political agenda…

I think not. I think that the reason for cutting off of communication on the part of Lucas and company was that the MIT contingent refused to accept the policy implications that Lucas and Sargent had derived from their models with the particular ad hocness that they liked. Romer again:

In 1978, when I was hearing the harsh critique from Solow, it is hard to find evidence of a closed-minded intransigence among the people he was criticizing. That mindset did develop soon thereafter and it seems to me that the frustration that would encourage it was already evident. Lucas and Sargent also wrote [in “After Keynesian Macroeconomics”, published in 1979, written presumably in 1978]:

Criticism of equilibrium models is simply a reaction to these implications for policy. So wide is (or was) the consensus that the task of macroeconomics is the discovery of the particular monetary and fiscal policies which can eliminate fluctuations by reacting to private sector instability that the assertion that this task either should not, or cannot be performed is regarded as frivolous independently of whatever reasoning and evidence may support it…. To confuse… faith in the existence of efficacious, reactive monetary and fiscal policies with scientific evidence that such policies are known is clearly dangerous, and to use such faith as a criterion for judging the extent to which particular theories “fit the facts” is worse still…

Lucas and Sargent, writing back in 1978 and 1979, are already saying that the government “either should not or cannot” pursue policies that attempt to “eliminate fluctuations by reacting to private sector instability”. And ever since then it seems to me that for Lucas, at least, the most important factor in his judgment of whether a model is worth discussing is whether it leads to that “either should not or cannot” policy conclusion.

I came through this process some seven years behind Paul Romer. I have learned huge amounts from Robert Barro and Thomas Sargent, but I have never interacted with Robert Lucas. But I don’t think my different reading of this history is due to my relative youth here.

And what I do want to earn is why Milton Friedman and company weren’t able to bring the Chicago Boys back into some contact with reality…

Must-Read: Paul Romer: On George Stigler

Must-Read: Paul Romer sets out his theory of George Stigler. I think Paul is under-generous. Romer drifts toward the position that Stigler chose to do ideology rather than science–that it was important to reject rather than test Chamberlin’s theories because if they were true they would support policies Stigler disliked. I see Stigler as believing that he was doing science: that since we knew that the arc of the universe bends toward freedom, doctrines that if true would support policies that limited freedom could not be correct, and admitting such doctrines for testing would increase the likelihood of error:

Paul Romer: On George Stigler: “The Great Depression was a traumatic experience for both Solow and Stigler…

…They reacted very differently. For Solow, the human cost of mass unemployment was so high that to him, it seemed obvious that the government had to do something to bring unemployment down quickly in the wake of a recession. Stigler saw the many harmful and ineffective things that the government tried during the 1930s (including price floors and official support for cartels) and resolved that the guide to government policy must be ‘do no harm.’ Stigler wanted halt to progress in economic theory because he feared that it would lead to more theories like those of Keynes and Chamberlin (who provided the foundation for Dixit and Stiglitz). For him, there was apparently too much risk that such theories might lend political support for government policies that should not be tried.

Under his division of labor with Milton Friedman, Friedman took on Keynes and Stigler took on Chamberlin. Marshall, they agreed, was safe. They turned Chicago in the last bastion of opposition to the Samuelson [mathematical general-equilibrium] program and thereby prolonged for decades the confusion that Marshall had spawned. For Stigler, the logical implication of ‘do no harm’ was ‘do nothing at all,’ so what good could come from the Samuelson program anyway? Samuelson, like Lucas, must have found it infuriating to have his life’s work dismissed by someone who already knew all the policy answers…

http://paulromer.net/what-went-wrong-in-macro-historical-details/

I would also say that Friedman “took on” Keynes in only a small and limited way. The way I put it to my students, Friedman’s argument was:

  • Keynes has identified a real problem, but,
  • as long as the central bank can keep the economy away from the zero lower bound,
  • the problem can be solved by the central bank keeping the money stock stable,
  • because the money stock is a sufficient statistic for forecasting future aggregate demand.
  • Hence all of Keynes’s worries about and proposals for fiscal policy and a somewhat comprehensive socialization of investment are unnecessary and in fact harmful,
  • and Keynes’s belief that they were necessary was the result of his failure to recognize how contractionary monetary policy had been in the Great Depression.

However, at the zero lower bound on interest rates Friedman became a Keynesian:

Even more pertinent is a talk Viner delivered in Minneapolis of February 20, 1933, on “Balanced Deflation, Inflation, or More Depression”….

[I]t would have been sound policy on the part of the federal government deliberately to permit a deficit to accumulate during depression years, to be liquidated in prosperity years…. The outstanding though unintentional achievement of the Hoover Administration in counteracting the depression has in fact been its deficits of the last two years….

[…]

I will use the term ‘inflation’ to mean an inrease in the total amount of spendable funds…. It is often said that the federal government and the Federal Reserve system have practiced inflation during this depression and that no beneficial effects resulted from it. What in fact happened was that they made mild motions in the direction of inflation…. At no time… since the beginning of the depression has there been for so long as four months a net increase in the total volume of bank credit…. Assuming for the moment that a deliberate policy of inflation should be adopted, the simplest and least objectionable procedure would be for the federal government to increase its expenditures or decrease its taxes, and to finance the resultant excess of expenditures over tax revenues either by the issue of legal tender greenbacks or by borrowing from the banks…

Friedman was always at least as interested in fighting the Hayeks and the Schumpeters (and the Lucases) who argued that nothing should be done to fight depressions as he was in fighting Keynes…

Must-Read: Paul Romer: On George Stigler

Must-Read: Paul Romer: On George Stigler: “The Great Depression was a traumatic experience for both Solow and Stigler…

…They reacted very differently. For Solow, the human cost of mass unemployment was so high that to him, it seemed obvious that the government had to do something to bring unemployment down quickly in the wake of a recession. Stigler saw the many harmful and ineffective things that the government tried during the 1930s (including price floors and official support for cartels) and resolved that the guide to government policy must be ‘do no harm.’ Stigler wanted halt to progress in economic theory because he feared that it would lead to more theories like those of Keynes and Chamberlin (who provided the foundation for Dixit and Stiglitz). For him, there was apparently too much risk that such theories might lend political support for government policies that should not be tried.

Under his division of labor with Milton Friedman, Friedman took on Keynes and Stigler took on Chamberlin. Marshall, they agreed, was safe. They turned Chicago in the last bastion of opposition to the Samuelson [mathematical general-equilibrium] program and thereby prolonged for decades the confusion that Marshall had spawned. For Stigler, the logical implication of ‘do no harm’ was ‘do nothing at all,’ so what good could come from the Samuelson program anyway? Samuelson, like Lucas, must have found it infuriating to have his life’s work dismissed by someone who already knew all the policy answers…

Things to Read on the Morning of August 9, 2015

Must- and Should-Reads:

Might Like to Be Aware of:

Must-Read: Den Baker: Job Growth Remains Strong in July

Must-Read: It is interesting that these days even Dean Baker is calling 215,000 net jobs a strong-growth month. I would still require more than 300,000 a month for “strong”. 200,000-300,000 a month is “moderate”. 100,000-200,000 a month is “adequate” (if the economy were already near full employment. And less than 100,000 a month is “weak”…

Dean Baker: Job Growth Remains Strong in July: “The economy added 215,000 jobs in July, while the overall unemployment rate was unchanged at 5.3 percent…

…The unemployment rate for African Americans fell from 9.5 percent to 9.1 percent, the lowest level since February of 2008. The employment-to-population ratio (EPOP) remained unchanged at 59.3 percent for the population as a whole and 55.8 percent for African Americans. While the unemployment rate has been falling sharply in the last four years, the EPOP has moved much less, having risen by just 1.1 percentage points from its low point in 2011…. The EPOP for prime-age men (ages 25-54) is still down by almost three percentage points from its pre-recession level. This is almost certainly an indication of ongoing weakness in the labor market.

Must-Read: Vox Voxsplains Vox.com

Must-Read: Vox Voxsplains Vox.com: What http://www.vox.com has had to say about what it thinks it is doing:

On explainer journalism: Vox: Nine Questions About Vox: “The media is excellent at reporting the news and pretty good at adding commentary…

…What’s lacking is an organization genuinely dedicated to explaining the news. That is to say, our end goal isn’t telling you what just happened, or how we feel about what just happened, it’s making sure you understand what just happened. We’re going to deliver a lot of contextual information that traditional news stories aren’t designed to carry, and we’re hiring journalists who really know the topics they cover. There’s no way we’ll be able to help readers understand issues if we haven’t done the work to understand them ourselves…. This article is an example. It tries to identify the main questions you might have about Vox and answer them in a clear, logically structured way. At the beginning is the most obvious, most important thing people might want to know about Vox rather than the latest scoop. This article contains news–we’re announcing our name, Vox…. But the new information isn’t the point. The point is to leave you with a better understanding of what we’re trying to do with Vox.

On the persistent stock: Matthew Yglesias: Refreshing the Evergreen: “No one even seemed to notice that we were flooding the site with previously published content…

…Articles were enthusiastically shared by people who had shared them the first time around, too…. Which is great!… If we can use our archives as a way to deliver more great pieces to today’s audiences, then that’s a huge win…. Lots of important things are… longstanding patterns, structures, or systems…. We think well-executed evergreen journalism is often the very best kind of journalism there is. We want to be doing it regularly, and we also want to be doing it better than traditional formats have allowed…. We’ve asked our whole staff to do at least one refresh per week, and we’re looking forward to seeing how it goes…. Hopefully we’ll get a bit closer to building and surfacing the persistent news resource we’re working towards.

On iteration: Ezra Klein, Melissa Bell, and Matt Yglesias: Welcome to Vox: A Work in Progress: “Today marks phase two…. At the core of this phase are the Vox Cards…

…inspired by the highlighters and index cards that some of us used in school to remember important information. You’ll find them attached to articles, where they add crucial context; behind highlighted words, where they allow us to offer deeper explanations of key concepts; and in their stacks…. But we’re just starting to learn how to use them. We have been employees of Vox Media for less than 65 days…. We’re launching this fast for one simple reason: there is no better way to figure out the best way to do explanatory journalism on the web than to do explanatory journalism on the web. We have some exciting ideas about how to do a better job explaining the news. But right now, those ideas are untested…. And that’s the only test that matters…. The quicker we can launch, the quicker we can start learning–and start improving.

On aggregation: Ezra Klein: How Vox Aggregates: “[When] I started… everything I wrote… in the hopes that someone else…

…would take it and try to use it… with a link back… a positive-sum endeavor…. [At the] Washington Post… I helped to create Know More… a big ‘Know More’ button that would lead people back to the original source to, well, learn more…. While aggregation has always been a clear service to readers, it can be enormously frustrating to writers…. But aggregation, when done correctly, offers value to the original source…. If you ever feel Vox isn’t using your work in the way you’d want, email me at ezra@vox.com and let me know. Our intention is always to do things in a way that is positive-sum, and if you ever feel we’re failing that ideal, we want to know, and we’ll work with you to change it…

On the homepage: Melissa Bell: Vox’s New Homepage, Explained: “If the slots look unusually…

…they’re designed not for one headline, but for many…. We’re able to offer both our newest story on the topic, but also the stories leading up to today…. I have no idea if this is going to work. It’ll require a different type of curation and we need to build a robust taxonomy…. There’s a basic latest news display…. There are some new permanent doorways into content we know you like to find… favorite writers… latest videos…. The layout algorithmically generates each time and the system may run through up to 1,000 different options to find the best one. (For more on the technical background, we took inspiration from some of the great work happening at Flipboard.)… There’s been a lot of talk of late about whether or not homepages are dead. We’re certainly not seeing that at Vox…

On first-person voices: Eleanor Barkhorn: First Person: “We’ve decided to devote a section…

…to thoughtful, in-depth, provocative personal narratives… First Person…. Here are a few pieces… that exemplify the style and range of pieces…. I’m a black ex-cop, and this is the real truth about race and policing. 9 things I wish I’d known before I became a stay-at-home mom. The internet is full of men who hate feminism. Here’s what they’re like in person. 9 things I wish people understood about anxiety. Confessions of a congressman


Vox: How We Make Vox:

17 DAYS AGO: Is the media becoming a wire service?: Is the golden age of media innovation over before it’s even begun? http://www.vox.com/2015/7/22/9013911/is-the-media-becoming-a-wire-service

ABOUT 2 MONTHS AGO: First Person, Vox’s new section devoted to narrative essays, explained: What is Vox First Person? And how can I write for it? http://www.vox.com/2015/6/12/8767221/vox-first-person-explained

4 MONTHS AGO: How Vox aggregates: A look into how we aggregate, why we aggregate, and what we’re trying to achieve http://www.vox.com/2015/4/13/8405999/how-vox-aggregates

4 MONTHS AGO: Happy Voxiversary!: One year ago today, we started to put web content online all day, every day. Thank you for joining the ride http://www.vox.com/2015/4/7/8353755/happy-voxiversary

7 MONTHS AGO: Refreshing the evergreen: How and why we’re trying to find a better way to use our past work http://www.vox.com/2015/1/15/7546877/evergreen-experiment

7 MONTHS AGO: Thank you for a great 2014!: It was a busy year. We published over 7,000 articles, almost 100 videos, 30 editorial apps, 150 features, and built over 30 storytelling tools. Here are a few of my favorite http://www.vox.com/2015/1/1/7472345/new-years-resolutions/in/5328445

8 MONTHS AGO: Vox shirts are now available: Now you can have your very own Vox t-shirt or sweatshirt http://www.vox.com/2014/12/9/7353725/vox-shirts-are-now-available/in/5328445

11 MONTHS AGO: How we updated our teen birth rate feature: We want the story to the be best single resource for our readers to explore a complex subject http://www.vox.com/2014/9/22/6401753/birth-rate-feature-update/in/5328445

11 MONTHS AGO: Vox’s new homepage, explained: It’s shiny http://www.vox.com/2014/9/5/6109125/why-we-built-a-homepage/in/5328445

ABOUT 1 YEAR AGO: Explore Vox card stacks: We’re at 81 and counting http://www.vox.com/2014/6/10/5797370/explore-vox-card-stacks/in/5328445

ABOUT 1 YEAR AGO: The homepage is dead! We’re building one anyway: Long live the homepage http://www.vox.com/2014/6/9/5792136/the-homepage-is-dead-we-re-building-one-anyway/in/5328445

ABOUT 1 YEAR AGO: Building Vox 1.0 in nine weeks: Launch fast, tweak often http://www.vox.com/2014/6/6/5787326/building-vox-1-0-in-nine-weeks/in/5328445

OVER 1 YEAR AGO: Three weeks of Vox: Where are the comments? And other site conundrums http://www.vox.com/2014/4/28/5659728/three-weeks-of-vox-tell-us-what-you-think/in/5328445

OVER 1 YEAR AGO: Ezra Klein voxsplains Vox in New York magazine http://www.vox.com/2014/4/11/5604242/ezra-klein-talks-about-vox-to-new-york-magazine/in/5328445

OVER 1 YEAR AGO: Correcting and updating card stacks: Rather than mucking up the cards with lots of annotations, each stack should have an updates card at the end http://www.vox.com/2014/4/8/5596086/correcting-and-updating-cardstacks/in/5328445

OVER 1 YEAR AGO: How come the links in charts don’t work?: We had to choose between mobile-friendly charts and interactive charts, and we decided to prioritize mobile http://www.vox.com/2014/4/8/5593258/how-come-the-links-in-charts-dont-work/in/5328445

OVER 1 YEAR AGO: Welcome to Vox: a work in progress http://www.vox.com/2014/3/30/5555690/welcome-to-vox/in/5328445

OVER 1 YEAR AGO: Nine questions about Vox http://www.vox.com/2014/3/28/5559144/nine-questions-about-vox

Noted for Your Nighttime Procrastination for August 7, 2015

Must- and Should-Reads:

Plus:

Might Like to Be Aware of:

Weekend reading

This is a weekly post we publish on Fridays with links to articles that touch on economic inequality and growth. The first section is a round-up of what Equitable Growth has published this week and the second is work we’re highlighting from elsewhere. We won’t be the first to share these articles, but we hope by taking a look back at the whole week, we can put them in context.

Equitable Growth round-up

Wage growth still hasn’t picked up yet in the United States.

Some cities may be eager to raise their minimum wages, but will enforcement be a problem?

While its impacts won’t be as large as the housing bubble, it’s worth looking at subprime auto loans.

A new study looks at the distribution of wealth after taxes and finds the tax code is promoting inequality.

A new regulation disclosing CEO pay ratios might not affect policy, but it should give us some interesting new data.

Links from around the web

The matter of segregation by income and race and its resulting consequences are increasing in the public conversation thanks to new research, policy action by the Department of Housing and Urban Development and a Supreme Court case. Thomas Edsall asks “where should a poor family live?” [nyt]

Corporate short-termism has also entered the public debate thanks to a proposal from Hillary Clinton’s campaign. William Galston argues that while you might disagree with her policy response, short-termism is definitely a problem for the U.S. economy. [wsj]

When industries expand, we usually would hope that there will be economies of scale where companies can produce goods or services more cheaply as they get bigger. Unfortunately the historical evidence shows the exact opposite happening in the finance industry, according to Timothy Taylor. [conversable economist]

On average women earn less than men. But in certain industries that’s not true when workers are young; women actually make more than men, on average. But as Ylan Mui writes, that changes as workers age. [wonkblog]

After almost 7 years of zero interest rates and unconventional monetary policy, some economists and policy makers are concerned about the effectiveness of monetary policy. A U.K. politician’s proposal to have the Bank of England directly finance infrastructure investments is drawing ire and Matthew Klein isn’t sure why. [ft alphaville]

Friday figure

080315-wage-growth-slack

Figure from “Wage growth and the health of the U.S. labor market” by Nick Bunker