Must-Read: Simon Wren-Lewis: Economics, DSGE and Reality

Must-Read: Simon Wren-Lewis recounts his career history and how it has shaped his thought. I have enormous respect for him. But I still do not understand why it would be a good thing to require that models have all of:

  • a representative agent
  • an Euler equation governing consumption
  • Calvo pricing and the associated forward-looking Phillips Curve
  • TFP residuals as an explanatory variable

All of these are either rejected by the data–strongly–or cheat by taking one of your model’s fit errors and claiming that it is a well-understood driving factor:

Simon Wren-Lewis: Economics, DSGE and Reality:

Just before 1990… with colleagues I showed that entering the ERM at an overvalued exchange rate would lead to a UK recession…

A well respected Financial Times journalist responded that we had won the intellectual argument, but he was still going with his heart that we should enter at 2.95 DM/£. The Conservative government did likewise, and the recession of 1992 inevitably followed. This was the first public occasion where academic research that I had organised could have made a big difference to UK policy and people’s lives…. It was also the first occasion that I saw close up academics who had not done similar research but who had influence use that influence to support simplistic reasoning. It is difficult to understate the impact that had on me: being centrally involved in a policy debate, losing that debate for partly political reasons, and subsequently seeing your analysis vindicated but at the cost of people becoming unemployed….

I went to Strathclyde University… to build a new UK model…. The writing was on the wall for this kind of modelling in the UK, because it did not fit the ‘it has to be DSGE’ edict from the US. A third round of funding, which wanted to add more influences from the financial sector into the model using ideas based on work by Stiglitz and Greenwald, was rejected because our approach was ‘old fashioned’ i.e not DSGE. (The irony given events some 20 years later is immense.)… I had no problem moving with the tide…. Having to ensure everything was microfounded I think created more heat than light, but I learnt a great deal from this work which would prove invaluable over the last decade….

After the financial crisis… governments from around the world first went with what macroeconomic theory and evidence would prescribe, and then in 2010 dramatically went the opposite way. The latter event was undoubtedly the underlying motivation for me starting to write this blog…. I discovered not just that the Coalition government’s constant refrain was simply wrong, but also that the Labour opposition seemed uninterested in what I found….

You can see from all this why I have a love/hate relationship to microfoundations and DSGE…. More traditional forms of macromodelling also had virtues that were lost with DSGE…. [But] those who believe microfounded modelling is a dead end are wrong….

Austerity is not the first time good advice has been ignored at considerable cost. And for the few that sometimes tell me I should ‘stick with the economics’, you can see why given my experience I find that rather difficult to do. It is a bit like asking a chef to ignore how bad the service is in his restaurant, and just stick with the cooking.

Must-Read: Laura Tyson and Anu Madgavkar: The Great Income Stagnation

Must-Read: It’s time to work toward a better definition of “equitable growth” than the vague and implicit one that we have been working with so far. Elements needed are that prosperity should be (a) broad-based, (b) fair, and also (c) substantial. That means substantial economic growth, but it also means conforming to people’s reasonable expectations of how economic growth was going to be divided and a relatively low level of inequality:

Laura Tyson and Anu Madgavkar: The Great Income Stagnation:

MGI surveys in France, the United Kingdom, and the US have found…

…that people whose incomes are not growing, and who do not anticipate an improvement, tend to view trade and immigration much more negatively than those who are experiencing or foresee gains. The Brexit vote in the UK and bipartisan opposition to trade agreements in the US are clear signs of this. Recent debate about income inequality in the US and other developed countries has focused on the rapid surge in incomes for the few. But stagnating or falling incomes for the many add a different dimension to the debate – and demand different types of solutions that emphasize wage growth for the majority of the income distribution. With most households continuing to face stagnating or falling incomes – and with younger generations thus on track to be poorer than their parents – such solutions are urgently needed.

Must-Reads: September 19, 2016


Should Reads:

Must-Read: Arindrajit Dube and Ethan Kaplan: Does Outsourcing Reduce Wages in the Low-Wage Service Occupations? Evidence from Janitors and Guards

Arindrajit Dube and Ethan Kaplan (2010): Does Outsourcing Reduce Wages in the Low-Wage Service Occupations? Evidence from Janitors and Guards:

Outsourcing of labor services grew substantially during the 1980s and 1990s….

Two occupations… janitors and guards…. The outsourcing wage penalty ranged from 4% to 7% for janitors and from 8% to 24% for guards… not due to compensating differentials for higher benefits or lower hours, skill differences, or the types of industries that outsourced. Rather, outsourcing seems to have reduced labor market rents for workers, especially for those in the upper half of the occupational wage distribution. Industries with higher historical wage premia were more likely to outsource service work.

Must-Read: Joe Gagnon: Negative Interest Rates: A Useful But Limited Tool

Must-Read: There is a debate that may be semantic and may be substantive with respect to whether a higher inflation target is in some sense a “policy” or a “tool” or not. I find myself of more than two minds about this. But by not including it on his list of things he prefers to negative interest rates alongside QE, Joe Gagnon implicitly reaches the conclusion that monetary régime change is not on the menu:

Joe Gagnon: Negative Interest Rates: A Useful But Limited Tool:

The disadvantages of paper currency are not so large as to allow for unlimited negative interest rates….

The Geneva Report shows that for negative rates down to -0.75 percent, there is little evidence of any large-scale shift into paper currency. But, especially if rates are expected to stay negative for a long time, there may not be a lot of room to cut further before triggering such a shift, which would mark the true lower bound on interest rates. Overall, it appears that other policies, notably large-scale asset purchases or QE, offer greater opportunities for monetary stimulus if and when it is needed.

Must-Read: Roger Farmer (2014): Real Business Cycle Theory and the High School Olympics

Must-Read: I think that the subtle Roger Farmer is mostly right here, but gets one key crucial detail wrong. He states that there are “permanent long-run shifts in the equilibrium unemployment rate caused by changes in the animal spirits of participants in the asset markets”. I am not sure that that is correct. What I do think is correct is this: there are permanent long-run shifts in the employment-to-population ratio caused by changes in the animal spirits of participants in the asset markets. (There are also permanent long-run shifts in the employment-to-population ratio caused by demographic, sociological, and cultural factors.) By focusing on the unemployment rate–now back to 4.9%–Roger, I think, unnecessarily weakens his case:

Roger Farmer (2014): Real Business Cycle Theory and the High School Olympics:

[Prescott’s] argument was that business cycles… are caused by the substitution of labor effort of households between times of plenty and times of famine…

A recession, according to this theory, is… a ‘sudden attack of contagious laziness’…. Keynesians disagreed. They argued that whatever causes a recession, low employment persists because of ‘frictions’ that prevent wages and prices from adjusting to their correct levels. The Keynesian view was guided by Samuelson’s neoclassical synthesis which accepted the idea that business cycles are fluctuations around a unique classical steady state. By accepting the neo-classical synthesis, Keynesian economists had agreed to play by real business cycle rules… accepted that the economy is a self-stabilizing system…. [So] they hey filtered the data and set the bar at the high school level. [But] Keynesian economics is not about the wiggles. It is about permanent long-run shifts in the equilibrium unemployment rate caused by changes in the animal spirits of participants in the asset markets. By filtering the data, we remove [that] possibility… have given up the game before it starts by allowing the other side to shift the goal posts. We don’t have to play by Ed [Prescott]’s rules…. The data do not look kindly on either real business cycle models or on the new-Keynesian approach. It’s time to get serious about macroeconomic science and put back the Olympic bar…

Must-Read: Manu Saadia: The Enduring Lessons of “Star Trek”

Must-Read: The wise Manu Saadia makes the case for his belief that “The Next Generation” rather than “The Original Series” is the real Star Trek:

Manu Saadia: The Enduring Lessons of “Star Trek”:

There are two kinds of science fiction… us[ing] the trappings of the future to explore the present…

…and us[ing] the same sorts of artifice for the opposite purpose—to imagine foreign, even utopian, futures. The original “Star Trek” series was undoubtedly of the first kind. The present saturated it. For a show that purported to “boldly go where no man has gone before,” it was remarkably at home in the familiar, if turbulent, world of the nineteen-sixties…. “Balance of Terror,” for instance, meditated on the futility of the Cold War. “A Private Little War” was an unsubtle dig at America’s involvement in Vietnam. “Let That Be Your Last Battlefield” offered a clumsy dramatization of slavery and racial discrimination…. Tellingly, the original series was at its best when its cast engaged in good, old-fashioned time travel….

It is hard to overstate how much of a departure the “Star Trek” franchise’s eighties-and-nineties-straddling incarnation, “The Next Generation,” was…. [It] swung almost entirely toward the second, more cerebral form of science fiction. It had no anchor in the present, nor did it genuflect before America’s frontier myths. “The Next Generation” was wholesale utopia, a thought experiment on how humans would behave under terminally improved material circumstances. Civilization, and the future, had won….

In “The Neutral Zone,” a reverse-time-travel episode, cryogenically preserved twentieth-century humans awake on the Enterprise. One of them, a take-charge Wall Street tycoon, is particularly eager to reclaim his stock portfolio and his status as master of the universe. “People are no longer obsessed with the accumulation of things,” Picard tells him—and us, the audience—sternly. “We’ve eliminated hunger, want, the need for possessions. We’ve grown out of our infancy”…

Must-Read: Project Syndicate: Untruth or Consequences

Must-Read: Project Syndicate is introducing a new fortnightly feature: trying to themselves aggregate the best explicit and implicit dialogues about the most important aspects of the world situation that are currently taking place in its pages. We wish them all the best of luck:

Project Syndicate: Untruth and Consequences:

In every corner of the world, governments are failing…

…to recognize the full implications of their policies, and experts are too confused, or inappropriately influenced, to provide clear and credible guidance. The result is a mixture of hubris and cluelessness that is consuming countries’ entire political establishments.

Must-Read: Gary Burtless: This Pessimistic Conclusion Does Not Correspond with Other Indicators

Must-Read: People who say that America today is in aggregate poorer than it was in 2000–or in 2008-9–are almost surely wrong. Economic performance since 2000 has been depressing, but not depressing to that extraordinary a degree:

Census report of big jump in income is a little too good to be true Brookings Institution

Gary Burtless: This Pessimistic Conclusion Does Not Correspond with Other Indicators:

This pessimistic conclusion… does not correspond with other indicators…. Personal income statistics published by the Commerce Department… show healthier income gains in the 21st century compared with the… CPS survey…. GDP estimates [say] real U.S. money income per person increased almost 11 percent in the first six years of the current economic recovery…. The Census CPS… suggests that the income gain was less than one-third as large (3.3 percent versus 10.9 percent)…. The Census household survey suggests that virtually all the income improvement in the recovery occurred in 2015, the Commerce Department’s personal income statistics show sizeable income gains in four of the last five years. This gap between… the CPS survey and… the national accounts has persisted for more than a decade….

The Commerce Department’s income estimates in the national accounts are derived from income tax returns, earnings records maintained by the unemployment insurance system, and administrative records provided by government transfer agencies… are almost certainly more accurate in the aggregate than estimates based on household survey responses. Of course, the national accounts data by themselves provide us with no evidence about the prevalence of poverty, the distribution of income, or the trend in median income.  Only household survey data offer a guide to how income is distributed…. But if the household survey is giving us an inaccurate picture of the trend in average income, it is inevitably giving a distorted picture of the trend in income at many points in the income distribution…. The [CPS] survey findings are worth reporting on the front pages of the nation’s newspapers, [so] the data they rely on are worth checking against competing, and perhaps more reliable, sources of information.

Musings on “Just Deserts” and the Opening of Plato’s Republic

Bradford delong com Grasping Reality with the Invisible Hand

Musings on “Just Deserts” and the Opening of Plato’s Republic:

Greg Mankiw Defending the 1% proposes what he calls the “just deserts” theory of social justice:

What you have gained and hold by playing by the economic rules is yours: social justice consists in not cheating or injuring people, and not being cheated or injured in turn.

This is an old theory: we see it first in the western intellectual tradition nearly 2400 years ago, in the opening of the dialogue that is Plato’s Republic. It is advanced by Kephalos…

The other participants in Plato’s dialogue, led by Sokrates, conclude relatively quickly that Kephalos’s argument–taken up by his son Polymarkhos–is unphilosophical, and thus unworthy of consideration by those who want to gain a deep and true understanding of the subject. For the rest of the dialogue, Kephalos’s position–that justice consists of getting one’s just deserts: not injuring or cheating people, and not being injured or cheated–is abandoned. The live positions are, instead,

  1. That “justice” does not really exist: it is merely a rhetorical weapon with which the strong control the weak.

  2. That justice consists of the right arrangement of human society, because a rightly arranged human society is an instrumental virtue that produces many many benefits.

  3. That justice consists of the right arrangement of human society, a good and worthwhile thing both because of the other benefits it produces and a thing very much worth having in itself.

Ever since Plato, moral philosophers have followed his lead–or, rather, the lead of the characters in his dialogue–in this dismissal of “justice is neither cheating nor being cheated”. But, as Obama CEA Chair Jason Furman pointed out to me, that cannot be completely right. First, justice as what Mankiw calls “just deserts” has enormous psychological resonance for human beings. To the extent that moral philosophy exists to account for an help us understand the morality we human beings do have, dismissing a very large chunk of our moral intuitions as wrong simpliciter is not very helpful. Second, given that human beings have a strong tropism toward Kephalos’s “just deserts” position–that justice consists of not injuring or cheating people, and not being injured or cheated–anyone who tries to set out what a rightly arranged society is without taking account of this strong human psychological tropism will almost surely fail.

My tentative ideas on this are unfinished, and probably wrong.

But I would suggest that we might be thinking about the fact that humans are, at a very deep and basic level, gift-exchange animals. We create and reinforce our social bonds by establishing patterns of “owing” other people and by “being owed”. We want to enter into reciprocal gift-exchange relationships. We create and reinforce social bonds by giving each other presents. We like to give. We like to receive. We like neither to feel like cheaters nor to feel cheated. We like, instead, to feel embedded in networks of mutual reciprocal obligation. We don’t like being too much on the downside of the gift exchange: to have received much more than we have given in return makes us feel very small. We don’t like being too much on the upside of the gift exchange either: to give and give and give and never receive makes us feel like suckers.

We want to be neither cheaters nor saps. It is, psychologically, very hard for most of us to feel like we are being takers: that we are consuming more than we are contributing, and are in some way dependent on and recipients of the charity of others. It is also, psychologically, very hard for most of us to feel like we are being saps: that others are laughing at us as they toil not yet consume what we have produced.

And on top of this evopsych propensity to be gift-exchange animals–what Adam Smith called our “natural propensity to truck, barter, and exchange”–we have built our complex economic division of labor. We construct property and market exchange–what Adam Smith called our natural propensity “to truck, barter, and exchange” to set and regulate expectations of what the fair, non-cheater non-sap terms of gift-exchange over time are.

But we face a problem: How do we enter into a gift-exchange relationship with somebody we will never see again? And we have a solution: a cash-on-the-barrelhead exchange. We devise money as a substitute for the trust that in this transaction one is indeed in a gift-exchange relationship, rather than a sap being taken by a grifter.
And on top of this we have constructed a largely-peaceful global 7.4B-strong highly-productive societal division of labor, built on:

  • assigning things to owners—who thus have both the responsibility for stewardship and the incentive to be good stewards…
  • on very large-scale webs of win-win exchange…
  • mediated and regulated by market prices…

There are enormous benefits to arranging things this way. As soon as we enter into a gift-exchange relationship with someone or something we will see again–perhaps often–it will automatically shade over into the friend zone. This is just who we are. And as soon as we think about entering into a gift-exchange relationship with someone, we think better of them. Thus a large and extended division of labor mediated by the market version of gift-exchange is a ver powerful creator of social harmony. This is what the wise Albert Hirschman called the doux commerce thesis.

Now it is certainly true that economists do not talk about this once. For example, in Books I and II of his Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith definitely does write as if self-interest mediated by exchange is at the foundation of the social order. But Adam Smith the moral philosopher (as opposed to Adam Smith the proto-economist attempting to disrupt the 18th century discipline of “political oeconomy”) does not believe that. And it is not true. People as economists conceive them are not “Hobbesians” focusing on their narrow personal self-interest, but rather “Lockeians”: believers in live-and-let live, respecting others and their spheres of autonomy and eager to enter into reciprocal gift-exchange relationships—both one-offs mediated by cash alone and longer-run ones as well. In an economist’s imagination, people do not enter a butcher’s shop only when armed cap-a-pie and only with armed guards, fearing that the butcher will not sell him meat for money but will, rather, knock him unconscious, take his money, slaughter him, smoke him, and sell him as long pig. Rather, there is a presumed underlying order of property and ownership that is largely self-enforcing, that requires only a “night watchman” to keep it stable and secure.

This extended pattern of independence is a very valuable piece of our societal capital.

Thus, given these psychological and institutional facts-on-the-ground, in my view any rightly arranged society has to successfully do all of:

  1. setting up a framework for the production of stuff…
  2. setting up a framework for the distribution of stuff…
  3. creating a very dense reciprocal network of interdependencies to create and reinforce our belief that we are all one society…
  4. and doing so in such a way that:
    • people do not see themselves, are not seen as, and are not saps–people who are systematically and persistently taken advantage of by others in their societal and market gift-exchange relationships.
    • people do not see themselves, are not seen as, and are not moochers–people who systematically persistently take advantage of others in their societal and market gift-exchange relationships.

Achieving these results is complicated and difficult, for reasons related to [the water-diamonds paradox][]. But I am now far afield, and need to get back to my main topic…


Cf., also: