A Note on the Core PCE Inflation Phillips Curve: Thursday Focus/The Honest Broker for the Week of August 30, 2014

A Note on the Core PCE Inflation Phillips Curve

The Honest Broker for the Week of August 30, 2014

David Beckworth notes that in the Bernanke-Yellen era the FOMC gets uncomfortable and decides that it has to loosen policy and steps up its interventions when PCE inflation falls below 1.5%/year and gets uneasy and decides that it has to tighten policy when PCE inflation rises above 2%/year:

[This] reduced-form relationship… is highly suggestive and consistent with my claim… that… there is a 2% ceiling to an inflation target corridor…

Macro and Other Market Musings About the Fed Not Trying Hard Enough To Hit Its Inflation Target Macro and Other Market Musings About the Fed Not Trying Hard Enough To Hit Its Inflation Target

Now the FOMC’s preferred inflation measure–the core PCE deflator–is giving signs of crawling up toward above 2%/year again. Thus the FOMC Is no longer discussing whether to stop its programs of asset purchases and start raising interest rates, but rather when to do so.

Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html

Thus it is time to remind ourselves of just what the U.S. macroeconomic time series on the core PCE deflator has to tell us about the risks and resulting costs of an inflationary spiral should the FOMC retain or even increase its current degree of monetary accomodation for another two or three years or so. And when I look at the time series, I find myself once again driven to the conclusion that what the time series of inflation in th U.S. over the past half century is that the risks and resulting costs of such an inflaitionary spiral are quite low. I cannot see how to get any other conclusion out of the data.


Begin with the core PCE deflator inflation rate: Annual:

Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html

And monthly at an annual rate:

Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html

The first obvious lesson is that monthly numbers are very noisy estimates of what the underlying PCE core price trend is. The monthly PCE core inflation rates make up a negatively-autocorrelated band 2.5%-points wide around the underlying inflation state of the economy. The second is that, in spite of a great deal of angst about how the Federal Reserve is about to lose its inflation-fighting credibility and risks the imminent-deanchoring of inflation expectations, the time series shows only four run-ups of inflation:

  1. The late 1960s Vietnam War period.
  2. The 1973-5 Yom Kippur War oil-shock period.
  3. The 1979 Iranian Revolution oil-shock period.
  4. The post-1987 crash Greenspan inflation.

Of these, the fourth was deliberate: Alan Greenspan did not know how much of a negative shock to the real economy would follow in the wake of the October 1987 stock market crash, and he did not want to find out. The first was semi-deliberate: William McChesney Martin understood tht there were risks in acceding to Johnson-administration pressure and while Lyndon Johnson may not have know there were risks his economic advisors certainly did. The second and third saw Arthur Burns and G. William Miller unable to master but rather mastered by events. What, quantitatively, can these four episodes of inflationary breakout–and the symmetric Volcker deflation of the early 1980s and Greenspan opportunistic disinflation of the 1990s tell us about how far the unemployment rate would have to get below the NAIRU for how long to produce how large an inflationary breakout?

Start with the accelerationist Phillips Curve model: future inflation will be equal to “expected inflation” plus disturbance terms, one of which is the level of unemployment relative to the NAIRU–the non-inflation accelerating rate of unemployment–and what the rate of inflation has been over the past year Will in many cases be a reasonable proxy for “expected inflation”. Thus we plot the difference between the next month’s inflation and what inflation has been over the past year, and between the next year’s inflation and what inflation has been over the past year:

The time series shows significant negative autocorrelation at the monthly level, which is not surprising: it is what noise in the observed price level would produce in the inflation rate. The time series at the annual frequency crosses the y-axis enough to make it clear that there is little serial correlation at the annual inflation frequency.

Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html

The next step is to consider the simplest possible accelerationist Phillips curves: regressions of the one-year and one-month forward change in annual inflation on the unemployment rate:

Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html

First, the standard errors that R spits out are, of course, wrong. For the monthly left-hand-side variable, each monthly inflation residual is negatively autocorrelated with its temporal neighbors. Thus the standard errors that R reports are too large. For the annual left-hand-side variable, the residuals in the regression are a twelve-observation moving average of those negatively-autocorrelated monthly inflation residuals. Multiply the reported standard errors of the estimates by at least two when using these estimates. The annual-frequency left-hand-side variable shows more of a relationship, so henceforth focus on that case.

Second, what R spits out are:

  • A slope coefficient for the annual left-hand-side variable of -0.232: an unemployment rate 1%-point below the NAIRU will raise annual inflation next year by 0.232%-points.
  • A NAIRU estimate of 6.06%: if the unemployment rate is below that, inflation will tend to drift up; if the unemployment rate is above that, inflation will tend to drift down.

The natural next question to ask is: why is the slope coefficient so small? between 1966 and 1969 core PCE inflation rose from 1.2%/year to 4.6%/year–and with a slope coefficient of -0.232 the unemployment rate would have had to average 4.8%-points below the NAIRU for 1966 through 1968 in order to generate such an acceleration. Between 1973 and 1975 core PCE inflation jumped by 7%-points–requiring a 15%-point gap between the actual unemployment rate and the NAIRU to generate such a large move so fast. And 1979-19890 saw a 2.5%-point runup in a single year: a 10.8%-point one-year unemployment-rate impetus. Even the 1986-1989 jump from 3.3% to 4.6% in 2.5 years would require a 2.2%-point gap between the actual unemployment rate and the NAIRU in a period in which the unemployment rate averaged 6.2%. We did not see such large shifts in unemployment as would be needed to drive such runups (although we did see a prolonged period of high super-NAIRU unemployment in the 1980s of sufficient magnitude to drive the Volcker disinflation).

Perhaps the problem is omitted variables? Perhaps when the unemployment rate is low other factors omitted from the simplest regression that tend to retard inflation are present, and that the true coefficient on unemployment is much larger. This is certainly a possibility. The obvious variables to add to the regression are (a) measures of supply shocks, (b) some way to account for the fact that the NAIRU is not constant, and (c) richer inflation dynamics. For our purposes we want to leave (a) to one side: the low unemployment of the early 1970s and the high inflation of the first oil-shock period are a significant source of what coefficient the unemployment rate had. Indeed, Milton Friedman used to argue that the OPEC oil-price increases were not a cause of future inflation but a consequence of past easy money and inflation and should be omitted from the determinants of inflation precisely because their inclusion had the effect of reducing the coefficient on unemployment.

As far as (b), all we can say about the NAIRU is that it presumably evolves slowly over time. A polynomial in time thus suggests itself. For (c), the natural variables to add are lags of inflation. And th obvious strategy is to conduct a specification search: add a time trend and powers thereof and add lags of inflation and see what specifications produce a substantially increased unemployment coefficient without obvious overfitting of the time series. Proceeding in steps until we have a fourth-degree polynomial time trend and three annual lags of annual inflation produces an extraordinarily overfitted equation:

Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html

But none of the regressions up to and including the massively-overfitted one generate a coefficient on the unemployment rate even 1/3 greater than the simple one-independent-variable unemployment rate specification.

The weak dependence in econometic estimates of inflation on the unemployment rate means that inflation hawks rarely rely on econometric estimates of the price pressure produced by sub-NAIRU unemployment rates to support their fears of runaway inflationary spirals. The time series tells us that a central bank that pushes the unemployment rate a full percentage point below the NAIRU and keeps it there sees inflation higher by 0.23%-points after one year, by 0.46%-points after two years, and by 0.92%-points after four years. That is not a catastrophe.

Instead, the argument is made that allowing the unemployment rate to decline below the NAIRU by even a small amount is likely, unless immediate and strong steps are taken to cool the economy and raise unemployment, to cause a sudden loss of confidence in the central bank’s commitment to price stability and an immediate and substantial rise in inflation expectations that have suddenly become “de-anchored”. For example, consider Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank President Charles Plosser speaking in the FOMC in April 2008:

I remain concerned, however, about inflation and our calibration of the appropriate level of the fed funds rate consistent with our goals. Inflation readings have abated marginally since our last meeting; but as the Greenbook suggests, there is reason to believe that this is a temporary reprieve… year-over-year CPI inflation was 4 percent in March, and year-over-year PCE inflation was 3.4 percent—well above their 2007 levels…. Markets question our willingness to take actions consistent with sustained and credible price stability. Now, we have often alluded to the idea that near-term weakness will help mitigate some of the inflation pressures. However, I would just like to remind us that this critically depends on inflation expectations remaining well anchored…. I believe that the FOMC’s commitment to price stability remains credible at this time, but just barely…

However, identifying the upward breakouts of inflation not with oil or other supply shocks but with a sudden loss of credibility generating an expectational shift to a different equilibrium runs into a problem–at least if the goal is to caution against policies that might temporarily produce a too-low unemployment rate. The upside breakouts took place in a few isolated time periods when the unemployment rate was 6% or 5%. Most of the time when the unemployment rate was 6% or 5% or even 4% there was little if any upward acceleration in inflation. The most that can be said of this hawkish point of view, even viewing it through the most rose-colored glasses imaginable and reading it in the most favorable light, is that a super-NAIRU unemployment rate insulates against a breakdown of confidence in the central bank’s commitment to fighting inflation. But a sub-NAIRU unemployment rate does not reliably trigger a breakdown of such confidence, does not even make such a breakdown more likely than not, and–given the small effect of low-NAIRU unemployment price pressure on inflation–would not seem to be the natural place to look for risks to the central bank’s credibility.

Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html Dropbox 20140825 Core Inflation Phillips Curve 20140827 Core Inflation Phillips Curve html

In some ways, the basic message here is one that I first learned back in the mid-1990s from Douglas O. Staiger et al. They asked: “http://www.nber.org/books/rome97-1)”>How Precise Are Estimates of the Natural Rate of Unemployment?” They answered: not at all. Why not? Because the only way to possibly pin down the value of the NAIRU with any precision is through the effects of unemployment on inflation. Since the econometric time series tells us that the effects of unemployment on inflation are small, there is no way to precisely pin down the NAIRU. By the same coin, the costs in terms of a damaging suboptimal inflation rate of policies that produce deviations of unemployment from the NAIRU must also be small, because the effects of unemployment on the NAIRU are weak.

Inflation hawks thus face a benefit-cost question that they need to answer. The benefits for societal welfare of the Federal Reserve’s successfully fulfilling its dual mandate are very large. To successfully fulfill the employment part requires tiptoeing unemployment down to the NAIRU. The costs of making a mistake–of overdoing it–are, the computer tells us, small in terms of the amount of undesired and costly inflation produced. Does this not imply a Rikki-Tikki-Tavi “run and find out!” attitude toward monetary policy–that learning more about where the NAIRU is by engaging in policies that allow for information-revealing deviations of unemployment from the NAIRU and inflation from its target is also an important monetary policy goal?

I have asked this question a number of times. I haven’t gotten an answer…


Source: http://delong.typepad.com/20140827-core-inflation-phillips-curve.rmd

References

2 William T. Dickens (2007): A New Method for Estimating Time Variation in the NAIRU

1 Douglas O. Staiger et al. (1996): How Precise Are Estimates of the Natural Rate of Unemployment? in Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer, eds. (1996): Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 0-226-72484-0 http://www.nber.org/books/rome97-1)

3 Mark Watson (2014): Inflation Persistence, the NAIRU, and the Great Recession, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings

4 David Beckworth: About the Fed Not Trying Hard Enough To Hit Its Inflation Target)

2204 words

August 28, 2014

Connect with us!

Explore the Equitable Growth network of experts around the country and get answers to today's most pressing questions!

Get in Touch